mexico agriculture and rural development...

127
Report No. 51902-MX MEXICO Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review December 2009 Agriculture and Rural Development Unit Sustainable Development Department Latin America and the Caribbean Region The World Bank Document of the World Bank

Upload: phamnhi

Post on 27-Sep-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

Report No. 51902-MX

MEXICO

Agriculture and Rural Development

Public Expenditure Review

December 2009

Agriculture and Rural Development Unit

Sustainable Development Department

Latin America and the Caribbean Region

The World Bank

Document of the World Bank

Page 2: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

© The World Bank

Agriculture and Rural Development Unit

Latin America and the Caribbean Region

1818 H Street, NW

Washington, DC 20433

Telephone: 202-473-1000

Internet: www.wordlbank.org

All rights reserved

Cover design: Michelle Friedman, World Bank

Photos: The World Bank Photo Collection

The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect

the views of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the governments they represent. The

World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries,

colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any

judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the

endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.

Rights and Permissions:

The material in this publication is copyrighted. Copying and/or transmitting portions or all of this

work without permission may be a violation of applicable law. The International Bank for

Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and

will normally grant permission to reproduce portions of the work promptly.

All other queries on rights and licenses, including subsidiary rights, should be addressed to the

Office of the Publisher, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA, fax:

202-522-2422, email: [email protected].

Document of the World Bank Report No. 51902-MX

Page 3: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

i

Contents

Report Information ..................................................................................................... iii Preface ..........................................................................................................................v EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ....................................................................................... vii

1. Introduction ............................................................................................................1 Purpose of the Study .....................................................................................................1

Overview of The Mexican ARD Policy Context .........................................................3 Performance of the ARD Sector and of Rural Poverty ................................................7

2. Diagnostics of the Federal Rural Budget ...........................................................11 Mexico‘s Rural Development Budget: The Programa Especial Concurrente (PEC) .11 Classification of ARD Programs ................................................................................14

The PEC Structure ......................................................................................................18 Changes in the 2008 PEC ...........................................................................................24

Other Fiscal Costs Outside PEC .................................................................................26 Relative Size of ARD expenditures ............................................................................29

3. Efficiency Assessment ..........................................................................................32 Comparison with Latin American Countries ..............................................................32 Comparison with OECD Countries ............................................................................36

APE and Agricultural performance at the State Level ...............................................40 APE and the Performance of Different Crops Over Time .........................................46

4. Equity Assessment ...............................................................................................52 State and Municipal Level Equity Assessment ..........................................................52 Producer and Household Level Equity Assessment ...................................................59

5. M&E and Institutional Aspects of ARD Programs ..........................................66 Monitoring and Evaluation .........................................................................................66 Institutional Issues ......................................................................................................69

6. Options for Moving Forward ..............................................................................73 Key Features of the ARD Program in Mexico ...........................................................73 Policy Options for Reform .........................................................................................75 1) Improving the ARD Planning System ...................................................................75

2) Rationalizing the Overall System for Farmer Support ...........................................77 3) Improving the Support System for Small Producers through gradual

decentralization ..........................................................................................................84 4) Improving the M&E and Institutional Aspects of ARD Programs ........................86 5) Increasing the Positive Environmental Externalities of ARD Programs and

Supporting the National Climate Change Strategy ....................................................88

Appendix to Chapter 6: Technical Notes ...................................................................94

Technical Note 1: New Zealand‘s Successful Agriculture Policy Reform

Experience ..................................................................................................................94 Technical Note 2: INDAP: Technology Transfer Targeting Small Farmers in Chile ....

………………………………………………………………………………………96 Technical Note 3: Payments for Environmental Services in Natural Resource

Sectors ........................................................................................................................98

7. References ...........................................................................................................102

Page 4: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

ii

List of Boxes

Box 2-1: Dimensions in the Decentralization of Rural Development Programs in

Mexico .......................................................................................................................... 17 Box 2-2: Efficiency gains from switching from private to public goods ..................... 20 Box 2-3: The role of agricultural subsidies in Mexico‘s water crisis .......................... 27 Box 6-1: OECD Analysis on Inter-Institutional Horizontal Co-ordination ................. 76

Box 6-2: Challenges Facing the Rural Finance Sector in Mexico ............................... 79 Box 6-3: Proposal by Winters and Davis (2007) on PROCAMPO Reform ................ 80 Box 6-4: Proposal by Sumner and Balagtas (2007) on Ingreso Objetivo Reform ....... 82 Box 6-5: Applying a Territorial Approach to Rural Development in a Decentralization

Option ........................................................................................................................... 86 Box 6-6: Rural Proofing in the UK and Canada .......................................................... 87

Page 5: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

iii

Report Information

CURRENCY EQUIVALENTS

(Exchange rate effective as of 12/1/2009)

Currency Unit: Mexican Peso (MxP)

US$ 1= MxP 12.88

FISCAL YEAR

January 1 – December 31

Abbreviations and Acronyms

AOI Agricultural Orientation Index

APE Agricultural Public Expenditure

ARD Agriculture and Rural Development

ASERCA Apoyos y Servicios a la Comercialización Agraria

CABSA Program to Develop Environmental Services Markets for Carbon

Capture and Biodiversity and to Establish and Improve Agroforestry

Systems

CC Concentration Coefficient

CIDRS Comisión Intersectorial para el Desarrollo Sustentable

CLCs Cuenta por Liquidar Certificada

CONAFOR Comisión Nacional Forestal

CONAGUA Comisión Nacional de Agua

CONAPO Consejo Nacional de Población

CONEVAL Consejo Nacional de Evaluación

ENIGH Encuesta Nacional de Ingresos y Gastos de los Hogares

ENNVIH Encuesta Nacional sobre los Niveles de Vida de los Hogares

EU European Union

FAIS Fondo de Aportaciones para Infraestructura Social

FAO Food and Agriculture Organization

FAPPA Fondo para el Apoyo a Proyectos Productivos

FIRA Fideicomisos Instituidos en Relación con la Agricultura

FIRCO Fideicomiso de Riesgo Compartido

FISM Fondo para la Infraestructura Social Municipal

FONAES Fondo Nacional de Apoyos para las Empresas Sociales

GATT General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade

GDP Gross Domestic Product

GOM Government of Mexico

GSSE General Service Support Estimate

IDB Inter-American Development Bank

INEGI Instituto Nacional de Estadística y Geografía

LAC Latin America and Caribbean

LDRS Ley de Desarrollo Rural Sustentable

M&E Monitoring and Evaluation

Page 6: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

iv

MPS Market Price Support

NAFTA North American Free Trade Agreement

NRM Natural Resources Management

OECD Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development

PDR Programa de Desarrollo Rural

PEC Programa Especial Concurrente para el Desarrollo Rural

Sustentable

PER Public Expenditure Review

PES Payment for Environmental Services

PROCAMPO Programa de Apoyos Directos al Campo

PROGAN Programa de Estímulos a la Productividad Ganadera

PRONASOL Programa Nacional de Solidaridad

PSAB Pago por Servicios Ambientales del Bosque

PSAH Pago por Servicios Hidrológicos Ambientales

PSE Producer Support Estimate

RDE Rural Development Expenditure

SAGARPA Secretaria de Agricultura, Ganadería, Desarrollo Rural, Pesca y

Alimentación

SCT Secretaria de Comunicación y Transportes

SECON Secretaria de Economía

SEDESOL Secretaria de Desarrollo Social

SEMARNAT Secretaria de Medio Ambiente y Recursos Naturales

SFP Secretaria de Función Publica

SHCP Secretaria de Hacienda y Crédito Publico

SMA Salarios Mínimos Agropecuarios

SRA Secretaria de Reforma Agraria

TFP Total Factor Productivity

TSE Total Support Estimate

USA United States of America

Page 7: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

v

Preface

At the request of the Secretaria de Hacienda y Credito Publico (SHCP), the World Bank

has produced this ARD PER that analyzes Mexico‘s Rural Development federal budget,

known as the Programa Especial Concurrente (PEC). The analysis focuses on the

categorization of PEC, efficiency aspects using international comparison as well as state

level comparisons, and equity aspects at the state and household levels.

The core team for this report comprised John Nash (Lead Economist, LCSSD), Jose

Maria Caballero (FAO consultant), Christian Borja-Vega (Consultant), Jozef Draaisma

(Senior Country Economist) and Yurie Tanimichi Hoberg (Task Team Leader). Dianelva

Montas and Erika Salamanca (LCSAR) handled logistics in Washington DC, Alejandra

Gonzales and Rosa Maria Hernandez-Fernandez handled mission logistics in Mexico

City, Maria Claudia Pachon and Diana Cubas edited the Spanish translation and Michelle

Friedman assisted finalization and publication of the report.

The team benefitted from the detailed comments by Steven Webb (peer reviewer), Dina

Umali-Deininger (peer reviewer), Mona Sur (peer reviewer), Evelyne Rodriguez

(external peer reviewer), Ethel Sennhauser (Sector Manager, LCSAR), David Rosenblatt

(Sector Leader/Lead Economist, LCSPR), Gustavo Saltiel (Sector Leader), John Scott

(Professor, CIDE), Stefano Pagiola (Senior Environmental Economist, ENV) and Susana

Sanchez (Senior Financial Economist, AFTSN). Technical background papers for the

report were prepared by Luis Gomez Oliver (Consultant), John Scott

(Consultant/Professor, CIDE), and Alberto Valdes (Consultant). In addition, Stefano

Pagiola (Senior Environmental Economist, ENV), Ricardo Hernandez (Senior

Environmental Specialist, LCSEN), Robert Davis (Senior Forestry Specialist, LCSAR),

Gerardo Segura (Senior Rural Development Specialist, LCSAR), and Harideep Singh

(Senior Rural Development Specialist, LCSAR) also provided technical input into the

report. The team worked under the overall guidance of Mr. Carlos Treviño

(Subsecretario de Egresos, SHCP) and received technical guidance from SAGARPA

through Mr. José Luis López Díaz Barriga (Official Mayor).

Page 8: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

vi

Page 9: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

vii

MEXICO Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

===============================================================

1. Mexico‘s large ARD program represents a very significant fiscal effort by the

Government of Mexico (GOM) on behalf of the rural population. Average public

expenditure per capita is now similar in the urban and rural sectors, unlike that in

many Latin American countries, where there is still an ―urban bias‖ in the

allocation of public expenditure. The present day Agriculture and Rural

Development (ARD) program represents the outcome of the far-reaching reform

efforts which began in the late 1980s to modernize the sector and introduce a

more efficient, equitable and less distortionary policy environment.

2. Mexico‘s ARD policy reforms included many novel features signaling a clear

departure from past policies. They resulted in some international best practices

such as the success of the Oportunidades program in rural poverty reduction, the

decoupled design1 of PROCAMPO, and the strong global leadership of the GOM

in mainstreaming climate change in ARD issues. This report offers options and

alternatives for the GOM to move forward on further improving its ARD public

expenditure program.

3. There are four reasons why the study is timely. First, 2008 marked the end of the

North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) transition period and signaled

the full integration of the North America markets. Trade liberalization and

NAFTA were powerful influences on recent Mexican Agriculture and Rural

Development (ARD) policies, since NAFTA was conceived and negotiated in an

environment in which there was some fear that reduction of trade barriers would

create pressure on local producers, and in particular would cause a collapse in

domestic production of corn, a product deeply engrained in Mexican culture.

Thus, the end of the transition is an appropriate time to reflect on these policies.

Second, the current global food price crisis and the long-term prospect of high

prices for agricultural goods provides heightened social and political attention to

reassessing the main tenets of Mexican ARD policy and revisiting the main

programs.2 Third, the growing concern of the GOM for the sustainable use of

natural resources, in particular water resources, and for the impacts of climate

change calls for analysis of the budgetary implications of measures to improve

1 Decoupled payments are defined as those whose amount is not dependent on current production, input use

or prices, and thus is expected to have minimal impact on production decisions. 2 While commodity prices have fallen since their peaks early in 2008, they remain high relative to levels of

recent years, and in general this seems to be the most probable scenario for the future. Recent events are a

reminder that global commodity markets are -- and are likely to remain – volatile, underscoring the

importance of policies that help producers to increase their competitiveness under a variety of conditions

and allow them flexibility to respond to changing circumstances.

Page 10: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

viii

natural resources use and adjustment to climate change. This is particularly

important since recent forecasts show that Mexico will be disproportionately

affected by climate change, in particular by hurricanes, changes in temperature

and precipitation, and increased frequency and severity of floods and droughts.3

GOM adopted a National Climate Change Strategy in 2007 in recognition of this

important issue. A detailed analysis of ARD expenditures should help the GOM

and other interested parties in all three of these areas. Finally, the recent global

financial crisis highlights the importance of efficiency in public expenditure

programs as the role of the government is expanding in attempting to stave off a

recession.

Key Findings of the Report

1. Overall Strategy

4. Total rural expenditure (including universal social services) is estimated to

be MxP 382 billion, or a quarter of total public spending and 4 percent of

national GDP. This represents a very significant fiscal effort on behalf of the

rural population. Given the current share of the rural sector in the national

population (24 percent), average public expenditure per capita is now similar in

the urban and rural sectors. There is, hence, no ―urban bias‖ in the allocation of

public expenditures and subsidies.

5. The current structure of ARD expenditures in Mexico is largely the result of

past decisions to subsidize particular farming sectors, regions, crops, and

other aspects of farming. Most subsidies were introduced independently of

others because of circumstances at the time; and once introduced, the subsidies

have proved difficult to phase out. The resulting system is complex and poorly

oriented toward a clear long-term strategy or apparent socioeconomic rationale.

6. The Programa Especial Concurrente has not worked as a coordinating

mechanism of ARD programs as intended. The Sustainable Rural Development

Law of 2001 established a coordinating framework for ARD public expenditures

through the Comisión Intersectorial para el Desarrollo Sustentable (CIDRS),

headed by SAGARPA. CIDRS was expected to serve as a forum to coordinate

GOM‘s ARD activities. But a strategy has not been developed, and CIDRS has

not oriented or coordinated federal resource allocations to ARD programs. The

3 Third National Communication to the UNFCCC (November 2006). Increases in temperature: by 2020

projected temperature is expected to increase 0–2.5ºC in the winter (December–February) and 0.9–2.2ºC in

the summer (June–August). Reduction in precipitation: Rainfall is expected to decrease by up to 15 percent

in the central part of Mexico and by less than 5 percent near the Gulf of Mexico, mainly between January

and May; by 2020 projected precipitation fluctuations will be in the range of –7 to +12 percent (December–

February) and –8 to +12 percent (June–August). Increased frequency and intensity of extreme weather

events: the number of severe storms and the intensity of severe drought are also expected to increase; sea

water temperature is expected to increase 1–2ºC, leading to stronger and more intense tropical hurricanes

in the Caribbean Sea, the Gulf of Mexico, and the Pacific Ocean near Mexico, with a 6 percent expected

increase in wind intensity and a 16 percent expected increase in precipitation within 100 kilometers from

the center of a hurricane; cold fronts may become less frequent.

Page 11: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

ix

main instrument for CIDRS to coordinate ARD public expenses and activities is

the Programa Especial Concurrente (PEC). But PEC has never functioned as a

planning tool; rather it operates as an annual budget exercise for tabulating the

budget lines of all rural development programs together. PEC appears as an annex

of the annual federal budget.

7. Some current ARD programs are incompatible with the far-reaching and

ambitious climate change goals in Mexico’s 2007 National Climate Change

Strategy.4

Mexico is the only developing country to have submitted three

National Communications to the United Nations Framework Convention on

Climate Change (UNFCC), demonstrating a strong commitment and leadership

role in the international climate change agenda. However, certain major ARD

programs counteract these goals—for example, the electricity subsidy for farmers

to pump groundwater (tarifa 9), which has led to the overexploitation of many

aquifers in water-scarce regions, and the Ingreso Objetivo program, which

encourages farmers to produce low-value crops and even water-intensive crops

(fodder) using scarce water resources.

2. Rural vs. Agricultural vs. Social Objectives in the Budget

Productive public goods programs (such as infrastructure, research and

development, and the like) are underfunded. Two-thirds of productive

programs are private goods programs (subsidies to individuals and families,

cash transfers, and so on), and less than one third of spending in public goods

goes to productive programs.

While nearly all social programs are targeted to the poor (including small

farmers and vulnerable groups), very few agriculture programs are. More

than 95 percent of social program expenditures are targeted to the poor, but

only 8 percent of agricultural programs are.

In contrast to the importance of the rural non-farm sector, PEC reflects

an agro-centered view of rural development. Some 70 percent of spending

in productive programs is specifically for agricultural activities. Productive

programs not targeted to agriculture receive only part of the remaining 30

percent, since most of these programs support agricultural activities as well.

Agricultural programs are skewed toward private goods, while

nonagricultural rural programs emphasize public goods. More than 80

percent of agricultural programs support private goods, while less than 25

percent of nonagricultural programs do.

Certain programs, such as tarifa 9, have high environmental costs that

generate huge negative externalities. These externalities are expected to

4 The National Climate Change Strategy was formulated in 2007 and identifies opportunities to reduce

emissions on a voluntary basis as well as measures for national and local capacity for response and

adaptation. The strategy proposes concrete adaptation and mitigation measure for all sectors, including

agriculture, covering all the main aspects of climate change policy. Climate change strategies and action

plans have also been developed at the subnational level for Mexico City and the states of Veracruz and

Nuevo Leon (World Bank 2008b).

Page 12: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

x

become more serious as natural resources are increasingly exposed to climate

change.

3. Efficiency Assessment

The allocation of agricultural spending by states is correlated to the size

of their agricultural sectors; when normalized by the size of the sector, it

is not related to the growth of their agricultural sectors. That growth per

peso spent differs substantially across states suggests that reorienting

agricultural public expenditure to states where it has the highest impact would

increase the growth of the sector countrywide for a given level of public

spending.

Reallocating spending from private to public goods would allow for

further increase in efficiency in agricultural spending. Regression results

show that a 10 percent increase in agricultural public expenditure on private

goods as a percentage of the value of agricultural production is associated

with a 2.6 percent reduction in agricultural GDP growth. On the other hand,

spending on public agricultural goods shows a positive, although not

statistically significant, impact on agricultural GDP growth.5

4. Equity Assessment

ARD spending (which comprises agricultural spending and rural

development spending) is inequitable. Simulations show that the

distribution of ARD expenditures is flat for the poorest 70 percent of rural

households, which receive less than MxP 500 per capita per month in ARD

subsidies. However, the richest 10 percent receive on average more than MxP

3,000 per capita per month.

Taken alone, rural development spending is progressively distributed, with the poorest 20 percent of rural households receiving 33 percent of

benefits.

In contrast, agricultural spending is extremely regressive, with more than

half of spending concentrated in the richest decile.

Agricultural spending is so regressive that it cancels out about half the

redistributive impact of rural development spending. Rural development

programs decrease the Gini coefficient (reduce inequality) by about 14.2

percent, while agricultural spending increases the Gini coefficient (raises

inequality) by about 6.7 percent.

5 Using a 1985–2001 dataset on rural expenditure for LAC, Lopez and Galinato (2007) also show that

reducing the share of subsidies to private goods (or, equivalently, increasing the share of public goods) in

the government‘s budget has, ceteris paribus, a large and significant positive impact on rural per capita

income.

Page 13: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

xi

5. M&E and Institutional Aspects of ARD Programs

M&E of ARD programs has greatly improved recently, but important

challenges remain. These include carrying out evaluations not only of single

programs but also of the entire PEC, developing and integrating databases of

ARD program beneficiaries, conducting deeper program evaluations at longer

intervals instead of the current annual cycle, and systematically using

evaluation results for managerial and budgetary decision-making.

Implementation matters—and it is particularly complex in production-

oriented programs. How programs are implemented is almost as important

as how they are designed. Key aspects to take into consideration for

implementation include the three-year, no reelection electoral system of

municipal authorities, which hinders their involvement in medium- to long-

term endeavors like ARD; the year-based budgetary system in Mexico, which

does not favor the continuity of programs and views required by ARD and

does not offer security to beneficiaries regarding program stability;

administrative and budgetary norms that make it difficult to disburse program

funds and limit disbursement to several months of the year, thus placing big

pressure on those executing the program;6 the scarcity of recurrent funds for

program operation; and the poor economic compensation and weak morale for

bottom-level program operators, which is inconsistent with the importance of

their function.

Options for Moving Forward

8. To make well informed decisions, the GOM will need to weigh the tradeoffs of

policy options based on considerations such as cost, sequential importance,

technical difficulty, risks, and impact. While some options promise greater

benefits in the longer run, others could be targeted for quick action. Policy options

are reviewed in the following five areas:

1) Improving the ARD planning system.

2) Rationalizing the overall farmer support system.

3) Improving the support system for small producers through gradual

decentralization.

4) Improving the M&E and institutional aspects of ARD programs.

5) Increasing the positive environmental externalities of ARD programs and

supporting the national climate change strategy.

1) Improving the ARD Planning System

6 Many agricultural public expenditure programs are very sensitive to the timeliness with which resources

reach farmers, especially in areas where the rainy season is short. Operational and budgetary norms often

stand in the way of timelines, resulting in the late arrival of subsidies.

Page 14: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

xii

9. A more effective planning system for ARD spending could be put in place.

The guidelines for allocating budgetary resources and the authority and planning

capacity of the CIDRS would have to be strengthened for PEC to be effective. A

recent OECD review of rural development issues in Mexico (OECD 2007c)

highlights the challenge faced by Mexico where SAGARPA, a sectoral ministry

without sufficient authority over peer sectoral ministries is mandated to plan the

ARD expenditures as chair of CIDRS. The OECD proposal to move CIDRS from

SAGARPA to the President‘s office would better reflect the multisectoral

character of rural development, and strengthen the Commission‘s planning

capacity. Another option is to place CIDRS under SHCP because SHCP is primus

inter pares as a ministry, has a multisectoral mandate and view, and is responsible

for looking into the effectiveness and quality of public expenditure and preparing

the federal budget. In addition to strengthening CIDRS, a strong nucleus of

agricultural policy analysts, staffed with experts of recognized academic

excellence could be formed to operate autonomously under the SAGARPA.

10. The planning system for ARD spending should be based on a comprehensive

national ARD strategy. Without a comprehensive ARD strategy and planning

system for ARD expenditures it is difficult to achieve coherence among ARD

programs and their objectives. A comprehensive ARD strategy with consistent,

explicit, and selective objectives as well as quantifiable results and performance

indicators would be an important step toward better ARD policy. The strategy

could serve as a framework for individual programs, which would be assessed by

their contribution to its objectives. The strategy would also serve as a framework

for the M&E of individual programs. Along with the strategy, an ARD budgetary

planning system would be required to ensure consistency between the strategy

and budgetary allocations. PEC has led to substantial progress in this direction.

But so far PEC provides only the framework—not the content—of such a system.

2) Rationalizing the Overall System for Farmer Support

11. Federal public expenditures in productive programs should be reoriented in

three ways.

Gradually discontinuing market price support (MPS) to inputs and outputs, as

well as compensatory cash transfers.

Substantially increasing allocation to public goods such as irrigation

improvement and management; drainage and transport infrastructure; other

rural infrastructure (such as that provided by FAIS); research, extension, and

training; sanitary and phyto-sanitary services; market intelligence (including

collecting weather information through weather stations and agricultural

statistics); emergency programs; and other public goods.

Increasing support to small producers.

Page 15: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

xiii

12. Non-targeted production-oriented programs benefiting mostly commercial

farmers should be separated from productive and natural resource

management (NRM) programs targeting small producers, vulnerable groups,

and the poor which should be decentralized to the states. Resources for non-

targeted production-oriented programs could be maintained at the federal level,

but funds now spent by different ministries for targeted programs could be

pooled. The pooled funds could be distributed to state governments as block

grants according to an objective formula to allow state governments to create their

own programs that promote small producers. In addition, given the current

imbalance in favor of non-targeted programs, some resources could be moved

from non-targeted programs to the pooled fund. These decentralized funds could

also support programs that assist small producers in adapting to climate change

and increasing positive externalities in NRM programs.

13. Federal non-targeted programs that support on-farm and value chain

investments should be rationalized. These programs include PROGAN, Apoyos

a la Competitividad de las Ramas Productivas/Adquisición de Activos

Productivos, and the non-targeted programs of Alianza. One option is to merge

these types of program into a new non-targeted support program for on-farm and

agriculture value chains investments. Another is to maintain different programs

but redesign them and perhaps eliminating some to avoid duplications, sharpen

their objectives, and make them more effective and results oriented.

3) Improving the Support System for Small Producers through gradual

decentralization

14. Gradual decentralization to state governments of the mandate and resources

to support small producers would help address challenges. There are several

reasons for this:

Decentralization would facilitate a territorial approach for rural

development, which would help clustering investments.

The number, dispersion, and heterogeneity of small producers favor

responsibilities at the subnational level, where constraints and

opportunities can best be identified.

The subnational level is also more appropriate for attaining synergy

between productive programs and other investments and services (such as

NRM, infrastructure or education) favoring small producers.

Resources could be more rationally used at the subnational level if state

governments apply them according to state-level strategic plans for the

development of the small producers.

15. After the transition period, decentralization would imply transferring to

state governments, in addition to the present FAIS to finance small rural

infrastructure, block grants for the decentralized development of small rural

producers (in productive and NRM activities). This, in turn, implies (i) phasing

out corresponding federal ARD programs and allowing state governments to

Page 16: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

xiv

replace them with their own programs, so that they can exert strong ownership of

the rural development agenda for the development of small producers in their

states; (ii) pushing ahead with administrative federalization (federalización

administrativa) to transfer to state governments the assets, staff, and other

operational resources of federal ministries required for state governments to

properly operate the newly decentralized funds; and (iii) strengthening the

implementation capacity of state governments to be able to takeover these

responsibilities. Decentralization of funds to support small producers would

facilitate the use of a territorial approach to rural development.

4) Improving the M&E and Institutional Aspects of ARD Programs

16. Alternatives exist to enhance the M&E system of ARD expenditures. There

have been recent important advances in the M&E of rural programs. There are,

however, still remaining important areas for improvement. These include

carrying out evaluations not only of single programs but also of the entire PEC,

the development and integration of databases of the beneficiaries of ARD

programs, deeper program evaluations at longer intervals instead of the current

annual cycle, and systematic use of evaluation results for managerial and

budgetary decisions based on action agendas agreed upon by the evaluators, the

implementing agency, and a third party. Adherence to these agendas should be

monitored closely. As a logical follow on to the Ley de Desarrollo Rural

Sustentable, Mexico could also start a ―rural proofing‖ system to anticipate and

monitor national policies‘ impact on the rural sector. Canada and the United

Kingdom both found success with rural proofing systems (called ―rural lens‖ in

Canada).

17. Alternatives exist to improve program implementation. Implementation

challenges are complex and varied. Many are institutional limitations that take

time to resolve. Simplifying the number and type of programs would certainly

help respond to the implementation challenge, as would a comprehensive ARD

strategy. To help identify and address these issues, CONEVAL‘s process

evaluations could be widely used to maintain the focus on implementation

challenges. Issues that could be addressed include:

Revising the budgetary and administrative regulations under which ARD

programs are implemented to ensure that they provide sufficient flexibility

and do not unnecessarily impair or slow down implementation.

Paying due attention to the recurrent/operational cost needs of programs,

which are particularly large for production-oriented programs.

Improving dissemination of programs and the accountability of operators vis-

à-vis beneficiaries and using ―client satisfaction‖ criteria to assess

performance.

Improving the economic incentives and morale of program operators and

ensuring that incentives are well aligned with program objectives.

Page 17: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

xv

5) Increasing the Positive Environmental Externalities of ARD Programs and

Supporting the National Climate Change Strategy

18. Strategies for supporting agriculture and for dealing with climate change

need to be mutually reinforcing. For the past two decades over 80 percent of

economic losses from weather-related disasters occurred in the agriculture sector.

Agricultural policies and climate change policies thus need to be mutually

reinforcing by incorporating two principles. First, farmers need to respond to

localized changes in climate depending on their individual conditions and

constraints. Policies should expand their options rather than encourage them to

make choices that do not correspond well to individual circumstances. Second,

farmers should not be encouraged to ―maladapt‖ by overusing scarce resources or

increasing production in high-risk areas. Both principles have implications for

agricultural policies that are congruent with the National Climate Change

strategy.

19. Expanding payments for environmental services (PES) programs beyond

forestry could create positive synergies between agricultural production and

the environment. Specific investment programs to reduce emissions that are

identified by the National Climate Change Strategy and that could be scaled up

include programs to increase the use of biomass, e.g. through high-efficiency

wood burning stoves in rural communities and renewable energy sources for rural

areas as supported by the Fideicomiso de Riesgo Compartido (FIRCO), livestock

programs to rehabilitate degraded rangelands, and hydro-metrological hazard risk

management and water resources management. Scaling up these programs could

be accomplished either through national programs or through decentralized

programs. Such scaling up should be accompanied by appropriate monitoring

measures to ensure that the programs are responding to their environmental

objectives. In particular, there is considerable scope to replace distortionary

programs such as Ingreso Objetivo with targeted environmentally-friendly PES

programs, which would reduce distortions and provide income support to small

farmers while also providing valuable national and global externalities.

Summary Matrix of Options

20. In order to make well-informed going forward, the GOM will need to weigh the

trade-offs among the various criteria of policy options such as cost, cost,

sequential importance, technical difficulty, risks, and impact. The following table

summarizes the policy options presented in the study, based on some of these

criteria. The matrix will make clear that while there are options which promise

greater benefits in the longer run, there are also areas that the government could

target for quick action.

Page 18: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

xvi

Table: Summary Matrix of Policy Actions

Policy Options Implement

ation

Likely

Impact

Technical

Difficulty/

Risks

Fiscal Cost or

Savings

1. Improving the ARD Planning

(1) Prepare and approve a national

ARD strategy

Short High Medium Low Cost

(2) Reposition CIDRS within the

federal government to strengthen its

coordination capacity, and build an

effective ARD budgetary planning

system

Short

Medium

High

No Cost or Savings

(3) Create a nucleus of high-level

agriculture policy analysts under

SAGARPA umbrella.

Short

Medium

Low

Low Cost

2. Rationalizing the overall system for farmer support

(1) Increase expenditure allocation to

public goods: irrigation improvement

and management, drainage and

transport infrastructure; other rural

infrastructure (such as that provided

by FAIS); research, extension and

training; sanitary and phyto-sanitary

services; market intelligence;

emergency programs; and others

Short, Medium

and Long

High

Medium

High Cost

(2) Modify PROCAMPO Short Medium Medium No cost or saving

(3) Discontinue PROCAMPO Medium High High High Saving

(4) Modify Ingreso Objetivo Short Medium Medium No cost or saving

(5) Discontinue Ingreso Objetivo Medium High High High Saving

(6) Modify input support programs

(tarifa 9, agrodiesel, others)

Short Medium Medium No cost or saving

(7) Discontinue input support

programs with or without temporary

compensatory payments (tarifa 9,

agrodiesel, others)

Short

High

High

High Saving

(8) Rationalize federal non-targeted

programs oriented to support on-farm

and value chain investments (mainly

PROGAN, Apoyos a la

Competitividad de las Ramas

Productivas/Adquisición de Activos

Productivos, and the non-targeted

programs of Alianza).

Short, Medium

High

High

Low Cost/No Cost or

Savings

(9) Reduce the allocation to non-

targeted production oriented programs

to allow for an increase in expenditure

to support small producers (see 3 (1))*

Short, Medium

and Long

High

Low

Medium

Saving

(10) Increase support to the rural non-

farm sector

Short, Medium

and Long

High

High

Medium Cost

(11) Strengthen the rural finance

sector to increase service access

Short,

Medium, and

High

High

Medium Cost

Page 19: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

xvii

Long

3. Improving the support system to small producers

(1) Increase expenditure allocations to

support small producers*

Short, Medium

and Long

High

Low

Medium

Cost

(2) Pool resources from targeted

production/NRM oriented programs of

different federal entities, decentralize

those resources to state governments

according to an agreed distribution

formula and decentralization protocol,

and discontinue the corresponding

federal programs

Medium, Long

High

High

No Cost or Saving

(3) Accelerate the decentralization of

ARD federal offices (federalización

administrativa)

Short,

Medium, and

Long

Medium

High

Low Cost

(4) Agree with state governments on a

protocol containing guidelines for

decentralization of funds to support

small producers: (i) national

benchmarks, (ii) fund distribution

formula, (iii) M&E system, (iv)

implementation support system, and

(v) state government responsibilities

Short, Medium

Medium

Medium

No Cost or Saving

4. Improving the M&E and the implementation of programs

(1) Adjust budgetary and

administrative regulations of ARD

programs to ensure flexibility and

timely execution

Short

Medium

High

No Cost or Saving

(2) Increase recurrent cost allocations

for production oriented programs

Short, Medium

and Long

Medium

Medium

Medium Cost

(3) Improve the dissemination of ARD

programs

Short, Medium

and Long

Medium

Low

Low Cost

(4) Improve the accountability of

program operators at all levels and

introduce ―client satisfaction‖ criteria

to assess performance

Short, Medium

and Long

High

Medium

Low Cost

(5) Improve the economic and moral

incentives of medium and bottom level

program operators

Short, Medium

and Long

High

Medium

Medium Cost

(6) Carry out evaluations of the entire

PEC

Short, Medium

and Long Medium Low/Medium Low Cost

(7) Develop and integrate databases of

ARD program beneficiaries

Short, Medium

and Long Medium Medium Low Cost

(8) Carry out in-depth program

evaluations at less frequent intervals

Short, Medium

and Long Medium Low Low Cost

(9) Organize a system to agree on

and monitor action agendas

deriving from evaluation results

Short

Medium

Low

Low Cost

5. Increasing environmental externalities of ARD programs and supporting the national climate change

strategy

(1) Improve SAGARPA norms to

regulate slash and burn agriculture in

light of increasing forest fires

Short Medium Low No Cost or Saving

Page 20: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

xviii

(2) Increase research allocation to

research and technology transfer of

reducing emissions from agriculture

such as no-till technology, reducing

GHG gas from livestock, reforestation,

efficient use of inputs

Short, Medium

and Long

High Medium Medium Cost

(3) Revise regulations to incentivize

farmers to sell electricity generated by

biomass to the grid^

Medium Medium High Medium Saving

(4) Improve targeting of geographical

area and payment levels of payment for

environmental services programs, and

scaling up its operations

Short, Medium

and Long High Medium High Cost

(5) Replace distortionary support

programs with payments for

environmental services

Short, Medium

and Long High Medium No Cost or Saving

Implementation term: Short (< 2 years), generally associated with changes in laws or regulations; Medium (3–5

years), requiring some institutional changes; Long (> 5 years).

Effects term: Short (< 2 years); Moderate (3–5 years); Long (> 5 years).

Impact: High, medium, low (relative to other policy options proposed in these notes, not relative to other more

general reform options).

Technical difficulty/risks of undertaking the options suggested: High, moderate, low.

Fiscal cost to government: High (large public investment programs), moderate (some public program expenditure

required), low (little public expenditure). Fiscal saving: high, moderate, low.

Note: * = The suggested proposal is to shift resources from non-targeted production oriented programs to

targeted ones (eventually decentralized to state governments) to support small farmers. Thus, the net effect

should be budget neutral, i.e. the overall expenditure should not increase or decrease.

^ = The suggested proposal is expected to increase investments by farmers to generate biomass energy.

Although, this proposal per se is budget neutral, in the long-run this should result in fiscal cost saving since

as farmers begin to generate biomass energy, they would buy less subsidized electricity from the grid.

Page 21: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

1

1. INTRODUCTION

PURPOSE OF THE STUDY

1. This study examines agricultural and rural development (ARD) public

expenditures in Mexico. The study is based on federal public expenditures.7

Included in ARD spending are all the public programs considered as such by the

Secretaria de Hacienda y Crédito Publico (SHCP), i.e. compiled in the Programa

Especial Concurrente para el Desarrollo Rural Sustentable (PEC).8

For

completeness, some policies and programs benefiting the rural sector that do not

result in budgetary expenditures, but in forgone government income, namely tax

exemptions and discounts to farmers on electricity bills (tarifa 9) are also

considered. However, the study does not address trade policies, another important

government intervention that changes relative border and domestic prices.9

2. In recent years, a growing set of evaluations has become available for the

principal ARD programs in Mexico, and a number of broader evaluations of ARD

policies have been produced (OECD 2006a, 2007d, WB 2005a, 2005b, 2006a,

and 2008, Taylor et. al. 2007). The World Bank has also produced a number of

public expenditure reviews (PER) and sub-sector studies in Mexico: Guanajuato

state-level PER [2002], Veracruz state-level PER [2003], Mexico Country PER

[2004a], Infrastructure PER [2005c], Water PER [2007a], Access to Finance for

Farmers and Agricultural Enterprises [2004b], Mexico‘s Competitiveness:

Reaching its Potential [2006b], Policy Note on Sensitive Crops (Maize, Sugar and

Beans) [2007b]). The present assessment builds on this rich set of results. It aims

to provide a comprehensive appraisal of the overall ARD public spending strategy

implemented in Mexico, in terms of both the scope of the programs considered

and criteria of evaluation. Given the wide range and dispersion of ARD spending

in many, largely uncoordinated programs, as reported in the budgetary analysis,

this assessment focuses on the principal strategic programs and groupings of

programs, and their overall impact on ARD.

7 The study team made an effort to collect ARD expenditure data from state governments through a

questionnaire, but the number and quality of questionnaire returns did not allow the compilation of suitable

estimates of public expenditure in ARD from state governments‘ own budgets. Since ARD spending from

state governments‘ own budgets are known to be rather limited, it is unlikely that their omission affects the

main findings of this study. 8 The PEC does not necessarily include the budget of all activities pertaining to rural development, but this

classification will be used for this study since this is what the Government of Mexico has identified as the

federal budget for rural development. 9 For a review of distortions caused by public agricultural policy including trade policies, see World Bank

(2008c). Also, OECD (2006a) provides a general overview of both the trade and public expenditure

policies of Mexico.

Page 22: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

2

3. There are at least four reasons why the study is timely. First, year 2008 marked

the end of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) transition period

and the full integration of the North American markets. Trade liberalization and

the signing of NAFTA was a powerful influence in shaping recent Mexican ARD

policies, since NAFTA was conceived and negotiated in an environment in which

there was some fear that reduction of trade barriers NAFTA would create pressure

on local producers, and in particular would cause a collapse in domestic

production of corn, a product deeply engrained in Mexican culture. Thus, the end

of the transition period is an appropriate moment to reflect on these policies.

Second, the current global food price crisis and the long term prospect of a high

price scenario for agricultural goods provides heightened social and political

attention to reassessing some of the main tenets of current Mexican ARD policy

and revisit some of the main programs.10

Third, the growing concern of the

Government of Mexico (GOM) for the sustainable use of natural resources, in

particular water resources, and for the impacts of climate change calls for an

analysis of the possible budgetary implications of measures aimed at improving

natural resources use and adjusting to climate change. This is particularly

important since recent forecasts show that Mexico will be disproportionately

affected by climate change, in particular by hurricanes, changes in temperature

and precipitation, and increased frequency and severity of floods and droughts.11

GOM has adopted a National Climate Change Strategy in 2007 in recognition of

the importance of this issue. A detailed analysis/assessment of ARD expenditures

should help the GOM and other interested parties in all three of these areas.

Finally, the recent global financial crisis highlights the importance of efficiency

in public expenditure programs as the role of the government is expanding in

attempting to stave off a recession.

4. The study is structured in six parts as follows: The first part presents the Mexican

ARD context in terms of policy and performance. The second part dissects the

ARD public budget, classifying expenditure programs in various ways so as to

provide an overview of the scope and composition of ARD spending. The third

10

While commodity prices have fallen since their peaks early in 2008, they remain high relative to levels

of recent years, and in general this seems to be the most probable scenario for the future. Recent events are

a reminder that global commodity markets are -- and are likely to remain – volatile, underscoring the

importance of policies that help producers to increase their competitiveness under a variety of conditions

and allow them flexibility to respond to changing circumstances. 11

Third National Communication to the United Nations Framework for Climate Change (November, 2006).

Increases in temperature: by 2020 projected temperature is expected to increase in the winter (December-

February) between 0 and 2.5 C and in the summer (June – August) in the range of 0.9 and 2.2 C11

.

Reduction in precipitation: the rainfall is expected to decrease by up to 15% in the Central part and by

less than 5% in the area of the Gulf of Mexico, mainly between January and May; by 2020 projected

precipitation fluctuations will be in the range of -7 to +12% (December-February) and -8 to +12% (June-

August). Increased frequency and intensity of extreme weather events: the number of severe storms

and the intensity of periods of severe drought is also expected to increase; the sea water temperature is

expected to increase between 1 and 2 C leading to stronger and more intense tropical hurricanes in the

Caribbean Sea, the Gulf of Mexico and the Mexican portion of the Pacific Ocean, with an increase of 6% in

wind intensity and an expected increase in precipitation of 16% within a radius of 100km from the center of

the hurricane; the cold fronts may become less frequent.

Page 23: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

3

part analyses efficiency issues by means of international and state-level

comparisons of agriculture public expenditures (APE) and agriculture

performance indicators. The main focus of the assessment is on APE, but these

are evaluated within the broader context of rural development policies,

considering the degree of consistency and complementarity between the two sets

of policies.12

The fourth part investigates equity issues emerging from ARD

expenditures. Equity is evaluated at the level of geographic units (states and

municipalities) and of individuals and households. In addition to assessing the

equity impacts of the main rural programs, an effort is made to evaluate the

overall equity implications of the entire APE and of rural development

expenditure (RDE). The fifth part contains a brief analysis of the Monitoring and

Evaluation (M&E) system of ARD programs and of selected institutional aspects,

and highlights some issues. Finally, the sixth part offers reflections on possible

directions for moving forwards both for the overall evolution of ARD

expenditures and for some of the main programs.

5. The current structure of ARD expenditures in Mexico is largely the result of an

accumulation of past decisions of subsidizing particular farming sectors, regions,

crops or aspects of farming. Each subsidy program was largely decided

independently of others because of circumstances at the time; and once

introduced, subsidies have proved difficult to phase out. The resulting system is

complex and does not seem to respond to any clear long-term strategy or

socioeconomic rationale. Thus, the aim of the study is to assist in the assessment

of the current overall ARD expenditure structure. There is a rich discussion in

Mexico concerning how specific ARD programs could be reformed and

improved. Although the study enters that discussion in the final chapter on policy

options, its main contribution is in the analysis of the global structure of ARD

expenditures and their efficiency and equity, and in providing guiding principles

and specific suggestions for a comprehensive reassessment.

OVERVIEW OF THE MEXICAN ARD POLICY CONTEXT

6. The principal ARD policies currently implemented in Mexico originated in

the context of a broad, market-orientated reform effort to modernize the

agricultural sector in the late eighties and early and mid-nineties. This

included accession to the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) in

August 1986, constitutional reform of the land tenure system designed to liberate

agricultural land markets in 1992, progressive deregulation of state-trading in

agriculture products and inputs throughout the 1990s and the dismantling of the

12

The study distinguishes between three types of public expenditures affecting rural areas: agriculture and

rural development (ARD) expenditures; agriculture public expenditures (APE); and rural development

expenditures (RDE). APE refers to those programs that more directly affect agricultural production. RDE

are expenditures in rural programs that do not affect agricultural production or only in an indirect way.

ARD expenditure is the sum of both. Classification of programs is often difficult because of the gray area

between APE and RDE, particularly when the impact on agriculture is indirect, and because many

programs include expenditures of both types. The classification of the main programs is presented in the

text.

Page 24: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

4

government trading company, the Compañía Nacional de Subsistencias

Populares, and the opening up of agricultural commodity markets under NAFTA,

initiated in 1994, with a long transition period, culminating in the full liberation of

maize, beans, sugar and dairy products in 2008.13

7. These reforms aimed to introduce efficient and equitable ARD programs. The ―second agrarian reform‖ (Gordillo et al. 1999), as this ambitious reform

effort has been labeled, was accompanied by extensive changes in ARD policies,

seeking to introduce more efficient and equitable and less distortionary policy

instruments. The long-drawn ―first‖ agrarian reform was accompanied, from the

Cardenas administration in the 1940s until its formal ending by President Salinas

de Gortary in 1992, by two principal forms of agricultural support: input support

(irrigation, fertilizers, stockholding) and market price support (MPS). By design,

these support policies where both distortionary and inequitable, failing to reach

small farmers who were intended to be the principal beneficiaries of the agrarian

reform.

8. The three principal support programs. Farmers were partly compensated for

the gradual reduction of MPS through three principal support programs: (i) the

Programa de Apoyos a la Comercialización (hereafter Apoyos)14

, an output-based

subsidy program introduced in 1991, (ii) the Programa de Apoyos Directos al

Campo (hereafter PROCAMPO), a per hectare direct transfer program decoupled

from production and prices, introduced in 1994, and (iii) Alianza para el Campo

(hereafter Alianza), a family of investment support programs offering matching

grants and support services, introduced in 1996. The expectation was that these

programs would not only play a compensatory role in the face of growing external

competition but, in the case of PROCAMPO and Alianza, would also provide the

necessary support for farmers to modernize production and switch to higher value

crops in the context of the newly liberalized land and product markets.

9. The reform included many novel features signaling a clear departure from

past policies. In the context of previous support policies, the decoupled design of

PROCAMPO made this program revolutionary in terms of efficiency and equity.

By decoupling transfers from production and prices and setting entitlements

according to historical area, the program was not only expected to minimize

distortions in productive decisions, but also to directly transfer resources to

farmers, including subsistence ones, for the first time in Mexico‘s history. Not

13

The end of the transition period was not the traumatic event that had been feared 15 years earlier, for two

reasons. One was that throughout the implementation period, the government had allowed importation at

low or zero tariffs of larger quantities than had been required under the agreement. Over the 15 year period,

imports of corn (mostly yellow) had grown substantially, but somewhat surprisingly, so had domestic corn

production (mostly white). Thus, the formal elimination of the final tariffs did not much change the reality

on the ground. And secondly, the final phase occurred in an environment in which global commodity

prices – particularly corn -- were at historically high levels. This brought high profits for Mexican

producers, while provoking a food price crisis for consumers. 14

The Programa de Apoyos a la Comercialización and PROCAMPO are both managed by Apoyos y

Servicios a la Comercialización Agraria (ASERCA), an agency within SAGARPA. Apoyos includes a

number of sub-programs, the most important of which is Ingreso Objetivo.

Page 25: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

5

the whole reform package, however, shared such novelties. In particular, Ingreso

Objetivo, the main sub-program of Apoyos, is a MPS mechanism for basic crops

such as rice, corn, wheat, sorghum and others, and is essentially no different from

the policies of the pre-reform period.

10. The agriculture support programs were accompanied by rural development

and poverty reduction programs. The reform in agricultural support policies

was accompanied by another reform in rural development and anti-poverty

policies. The principal anti-poverty program introduced was the Programa de

Educación, Salud y Alimentación (Progresa, in 1997; renamed Oportunidades in

2001), offering direct cash transfers to poor rural households conditional on

human capital investment (attending basic education and using health services).15

Three other important targeted rural development programs were introduced in

this period: (i) the Fondo de Aportaciones para Infraestructura Social (FAIS, in

1996), a large decentralized fund for basic infrastructural investment replacing the

Programa Nacional de Solidaridad (PRONASOL) of the Salinas administration

(1988-1994), (ii) the Programa de Empleo Temporal (1995), a multi-agency, self-

targeted temporary employment program16

and (iii) the Programa de Desarrollo

Rural (PDR, in 1996), the principal Alianza program targeted to small producers.

11. The Rural Development Law of 2001 created a framework to coordinate

rural development activities and expenditures in Mexico. Reforms were also

accompanied by an important institutional innovation, the passing of an umbrella

law for rural development, the Ley de Desarrollo Rural Sustentable (2001). This

law introduced a new and comprehensive institutional architecture for agriculture

and rural development in Mexico. At the national level, it created a national

council for rural development with governmental and civil society participants,

and an inter-ministerial rural development committee, the Comisión Intersecre-

tarial para el Desarrollo Rural Sustentable (CIDRS), chaired by the Secretaria de

Agricultura, Ganadería, Desarrollo Rural, Pesca y Alimentación (SAGARPA),

with the participation of various federal government ministries. In addition, mixed

government-civil society committees were created at the state, district and

municipal levels, and also for the main agricultural product chains and the main

ancillary services, although their functions and authority is still irregular and often

limited. The rural development law also mandated the creation of a coordinating

framework for ARD expenditures, the Programa Especial Concurrente para el

Desarrollo Rural Sustentable (PEC). However, beyond offering a budgetary

classification scheme to organize ARD expenditures, PEC has not had much

impact on the allocation of ARD resources. Coordination of the numerous

15

In 2001 the program was extended to urban areas and upper-secondary education and renamed

Oportunidades. 16

Originally, Programa de Empleo Temporal (PET) included the participation of Secretaria de Desarrollo

Social (SEDESOL), Secretaria de Medio Ambiente y Recursos Naturales (SEMARNAT), Secretaria de

Comunicacion y Transportes (SCT), and SAGARPA, but the SAGARPA component has recently been

discontinued.

Page 26: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

6

Mexican ARD programs, executed by various ministries and agencies, remains a

challenge.

12. ARD spending has doubled since 2000 showing an increase in the most

distortionary programs. Since 2000, ARD spending has almost doubled in real

terms, reaching a federal ARD budget of MxP 204 billion for 2008 (see Figure 2-

1). This expansion took place in the context of the liberalization of most

agricultural products in 2003 and the liberalization of ―sensitive‖ products in

2008. The expansion of APE was in large part allocated to existing and new

distortionary instruments such as the agricultural diesel subsidy, which was

started in 2001, partly reversing rather than deepening the effect of the market-

oriented reforms.

13. Specifically, the use of the most distortionary instruments fell in the 1990s,

while the use of the least distortionary instruments rose, but this positive

trend was reversed in recent years. Overall, the reforms led to a sharp

reduction in the participation of the most distortionary instruments (MPS, output

and variable input payments) with the combined share of the latter two in APE

declining from 50 to 20 percent between 1990 and 1996 (see Figure 1-1).17

On

the other hand, the share of the least distortionary instruments (public goods and

payments based on historical entitlements) increased from 30 to 70 percent in the

course of the decade. Since 2000, however, these trends have been reversed, with

the more distortionary instruments gradually gaining ground and the least

distortionary losing it.

Figure 1-1: Least and Most Distortionary APE (% Total APE)

Least distortionary APE

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

Payments based on non-current A/An/R/I Public goods (GSSE)

17

The sharp fall in payments based on variable inputs in 1997-2000 may be due to inconsistencies in the

OECD data. The fall in 1997 corresponds to a drop in the electricity subsidy for groundwater pumping for

irrigation, while the sharp increase in 2001 corresponds to the introduction of large agricultural diesel

subsidies. The new output-based payments in 2001 correspond to the introduction of Ingreso Objetivo

(ASERCA), with large subsidies for grains and other crops in 2001.

Page 27: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

7

Most distortionary APE

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

Payment based on variable inputs Payments based on output

Note: ―Non-current A/An/R/I‖ refers to transfers linked to historical area planted/animal

numbers/receipts/income. For further details see OECD (2007a,b)

Source: OECD (2007) as cited in Scott (2008)

14. Some of the current ARD programs are incompatible with Mexico’s far-

reaching and ambitious climate change goals as represented in the National

Climate Change Strategy adopted in 2007.18

Mexico is the only developing

country to have submitted three National Communications to the United Nations

Framework Convention on Climate Change, demonstrating a strong commitment

and leadership role in the international climate change agenda. However, certain

major ARD programs counteract these goals, for example the electricity subsidy

for farmers to pump groundwater (tarifa 9), which has led to overexploitation in

many of the country‘s aquifers in water scarce regions, as well as the Ingreso

Objetivo program, which encourages farmers to produce low value crops using

scarce water resources and even crops that are water intensive, as is the case with

fodder.

PERFORMANCE OF THE ARD SECTOR AND OF RURAL POVERTY

15. Overall, agricultural growth has been weak but has shown signs of

acceleration since 2000. Between 1980 and 2007 agricultural GDP grew 1.6

percent a year on average, lagging behind total GDP growth of 2.7 percent (see

Figure 1-2). This trend is unsurprising, reflecting the expected contraction of the

share of the primary sector in a developing economy. The relative difference

between the two growth rates, however, has narrowed rather than widened in

18

The National Climate Change Strategy was formulated in 2007 and identifies opportunities for emissions

reductions on a voluntary basis, as well as measures for the development of necessary national and local

capacity for response and adaptation. The strategy proposes concrete adaptation and mitigation measure

for all sectors, including agriculture, covering all the main aspects of climate change policy. Climate

change strategies and action plans have also been developed at the sub-national level for Mexico City, the

states of Veracruz and Nuevo Leon (World Bank, 2008b).

Page 28: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

8

recent years, after 2000. In 2001 and 2003, the growth rate of agriculture GDP

was actually above that of total GDP (3.5 percent and 3.1 percent vs. -0.2 percent

and 1.3 percent, respectively). This, together with the stability of basic food prices

and Oportunidades transfers, is widely credited for the significant reduction in

rural poverty achieved during the recessionary 2000-2002 years (Székely and

Rascon, 2004) and the overall 2000-2006 period.

Figure 1-2: Average Annual Growth Rates of Total GDP and Agriculture GDP (%, 1980-2007)

1.6%

3.7%

3.2%

2.6%

4.0%

0.8%

2.6%

1.7%

2.0%

3.6%

0.0%

0.5%

1.0%

1.5%

2.0%

2.5%

3.0%

3.5%

4.0%

4.5%

1980-1989 1990-1993 1994-1999 2000-2004 2005-2007

GDP Agric. GDP

Source: INEGI as cited in Scott (2008)

16. The rural poverty rate has decreased but the rural share in total poverty

remains unchanged since 1992. The last decade has witnessed a significant and

sustained decline in rural poverty rates. The incidence of extreme poverty

(pobreza alimentaria) declined from 53 to 24 percent between 1996 and 2006

(Figure 1-3). Most of this decline is a recovery from the dramatic increase in

poverty following the 1995 crisis, since the 1992-2002 decade was fully lost in

terms of rural poverty reduction. More recently (2004-2006), the rate of decline

of rural poverty has decelerated. In 2006, more than half of the rural population

was moderately poor (pobreza patrimonial), and a quarter was extremely poor.

Rural areas still account for two thirds of the extreme poor in Mexico, just as they

did in 1992.

Figure 1-3: Rural Poverty Rates and Rural Share in Total Poverty (%, 1992-2006)

Page 29: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

9

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2005 2006

Po

ve

rty r

ate

s (

lin

e)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

Ru

ral

sh

are

in

po

ve

rty (

ba

r)

Rural share in total poverty (alimentaria) Extreme Poverty rate (alimentaria )

Poverty rate (patrimonial)

Source: CONEVAL as cited in Scott (2008)

17. To what extent does agriculture offer an opportunity for rural households to

escape poverty? The poverty reduction potential of agriculture is a major theme

of the Bank‘s World Development Report 2008 (World Bank, 2008a). This

potential seems to have been sharply diminished in Mexico over the last decade,

for independent (non-wage) farm incomes have collapsed from 28.7 to 9.1 percent

of rural household income between 1992 and 2004, while total farm income

contracted from close to 40 percent to just 17 percent (Figure 1-4). As shown in

Table 1-1, however, agriculture is proportionally much more important for the

poor, as a source of both independent income and wage labor employment.

Figure 1-4: Sources of Rural Household Income (%)

Page 30: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

10

8.6 4.6

0.1 4.22.0 4.11.6

3.7

22.8

36.3

15.5

18.5

9.0

8.228.7

9.1

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

1992 2004

Domestic inter-household transfers Oportunidades and Procampo transfers

International transfers Pensions

Non-Farm Wage Labor Indep. Non-Farm Activs.

Agricultural Wage Labor Independent Farming

Farm Income

Non Farm Income

Transfers

Source: Ruiz-Castillo (2005) as cited in Scott (2008). Total does not add up to

100% because smaller or unspecified income sources were excluded.

Table 1-1: Household Deciles Ordered by Per Capita Income (2006)

Agricultural activities by household (hh) deciles ordered by income per capita (2006)

hh with agricultural workers hh with independent farming income

hh

Deciles Households % Decile Households % Decile

Annual income

million MP MP/hh

1 3,222,510 60% 705,977 26.6% 2,705 3,831

2 1,492,371 32% 249,587 9.4% 1,830 7,331

3 946,424 24% 190,263 7.2% 1,253 6,586

4 625,353 15% 119,835 4.5% 1,038 8,664

5 578,002 13% 103,074 3.9% 1,853 17,977

6 340,805 9% 86,394 3.3% 982 11,362

7 390,019 9% 68,100 2.6% 977 14,349

8 233,630 7% 63,465 2.4% 917 14,456

9 144,672 5% 30,022 1.1% 878 29,249

10 152,976 4% 39,521 1.5% 3,521 89,093

Total 8,126,762 18% 1,656,238 6.2% 15,954 9,633

Source: Scott (2008) based on data in ENIGH (2006)

Page 31: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

11

2. DIAGNOSTICS OF THE FEDERAL RURAL

BUDGET

MEXICO’S RURAL DEVELOPMENT BUDGET: THE PROGRAMA ESPECIAL CONCURRENTE

(PEC)

18. PEC has not worked as a coordinating mechanism of ARD programs as

intended. The Sustainable Rural Development Law of 2001 established a

coordinating framework for ARD public expenditures through the Comisión

Intersectorial para el Desarrollo Sustentable (CIDRS), headed by SAGARPA.

The expectation was that CIDRS would develop a rural development strategy and

serve as a forum to coordinate GOM‘s ARD activities. A strategy, however, has

not been developed, and CIDRS has not yet actually managed to orient and

coordinate the allocation of federal resource to ARD programs. Thus, the PEC,

annually prepared by CIDRS, has, to date, not functioned as a planning tool; it

operates as an annual budget exercise where the budget lines of all rural

development programs are tabulated together. PEC appears as an Annex of the

annual federal budget.19

19. The PEC budget has been steadily increasing since its first compilation in

2001, almost doubling between 2001 and 2008. The only year in which it

declined was 2004. During 2001-2008, it has averaged an annual growth rate of

9.2 percent in constant prices (Figure 2-1).

Figure 2-1: PEC Budget 2001-2008 (2007 Constant MxP)

19

The federal budget has, since 1996, explicitly classified the rural development budget even before the

formulation of the PEC in 2001. Before 2001, the rural development budget was compiled under the

category ―gasto en desarrollo rural (rural development costs)‖in the budget decree. Since many

expenditure programs operate in rural and urban areas, a difficult task of SHCP when constructing PEC is

to estimate what part of these programs is spent in rural and urban areas. The criteria used for the

apportioning, which in some cases have been challenged by experts, should be made transparent and

disclosed jointly with PEC figures.

Page 32: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

12

0

20,000

40,000

60,000

80,000

100,000

120,000

140,000

160,000

180,000

200,000

Mx

P m

illi

on

in

20

07

va

lue

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

Year

Source: Centro de Estudios para el Desarrollo Rural Sustentable y la Soberanía Alimentaria as cited in

Oliver and Santillanes (2008).

20. PEC reflects GOM’s strong commitment to rural development. PEC

amounted to 12 percent of the federal budget in 2006 and included more than 60

programs with 85 subprograms and 94 components to be implemented by 13

different secretarías plus sub-national governments. The actual executed 2007

PEC budget was MxP 177 billion (Table 2-1). The largest programs in PEC are

PROCAMPO (executed by SAGARPA), Alianza para el Campo (SAGARPA),

Apoyos a la Comercializacion (SAGARPA) and Oportunidades (SEDESOL).

Approximately one third of the total PEC budget is executed by SAGARPA.

Table 2-1: Mexico’s Rural Development Budget (PEC) 2006-2008

Page 33: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

13

Allocation MxP million

Percent (%) Current prices Constant prices (2007)

2006 (a) 2007(b) 2008 (c) 2006 2007 2008 2006 2007 2008

Total PEC 152,934.31

152,934.31

176,794.3 204,000.0 160,944.6 176,794.3 198,598.4 100.00 100.00 100

Total by Ministries 125,882.21 144,637.2 171,900.3 134,187.2 146,262.0 167,348.6 82.31 82.57 84.26

Ramo 04.

Gobernación 298.5 300.00 400.0 310.1 300.0 389.4 0.20 0.17 0.20

Ramo 05. SRE 109.2

71.40 69.7 76.0 71.4 67.9 0.07 0.04 0.03

Ramo 06. SHCP 6,180.60

8,291.90 10,795.3 6,781.2 8,291.9 10,509.5 4.04

4.73 5.29

Ramo 08. SAGARPA 48,899.41

58,384.71 65,341.4 53,055.4 58,536.9 63,611.3 31.97 33.33 32.03

Ramo 09. SCT

2,634.0

2,857.80 7,545.7 2,602.3 2,857.8 7,345.9 1.72

1.63 3.70

Ramo 10. Economía 654.5

838.50 918.2 923.3 838.5 893.9 0.43 0.48 0.45

Ramo 11. SEP

24,594.9

23,161.75 24,694.9 25,695.1 23,686.8 24,041.0 16.08

13.22 12.11

Ramo 12. Salud 9,790.80

15,056.45 12,643.8 12,745.9 15,940.5 12,309.0 6.40

8.60 6.20

Ramo 14. STyPS 74.10

66.95 111.0 78.9 67.0 108.1 0.05 0.04 0.05

Ramo 15. Reforma

Agraria

4,342.0

4,772.30 5,435.4 4,618.4 4,779.8 5,291.5 2.84 2.72 2.66

Ramo 16.

SEMARNAT

10,930.4

16,525.10 17,519.2 9,379.0 14,289.8 17,055.3 7.15

9.43 8.59

Ramo 20. SEDESOL 17,372.30

14,233.85 26,290.7 17,892.2 16,525.1 25,594.6 11.36 8.13 12.89

Ramo 21. Turismo 1.5

76.50 135.0 1.7 76.5 131.4 0.00 0.04 0.07

Total by other

categories

27,052.10

30,532.50 32,099.7 26,757.4 30,532.3 31,249.7 17.69 17.43 15.74

Ramo 19.

Aportaciones a

Seguridad Social

5,151.90

5,512.90 6,300.0 5,070.0 5,512.7 6,133.2 3.37 3.15 3.09

Ramo 31. Tribunales

Agrarios

584.2

250.00 790.2 601.2 694.0 769.3 0.38 0.14 0.39

Ramo 33.

Aportaciones

Federales a Estados y

Municipios

21,316.0

694.00 24,758.5 21,086.2 24,075.6 24,102.9 13.94 0.40 12.14

Ramo 23. Previsiones

Salariales y Económic. 24,075.60 250.0 250.0 243.4 13.74 0.12

Source: Oliver and Santillanes (2008).

a. 2006: Executed Budget, data from Public Accounts, SHCP

b.2007: Budget incorporated in the Proceso Integral de Programación y Presupuesto (PIPP), SHCP.

c. 2008: Programmed budget as presented in the Presupuesto de Egresos de la Federación 2008.

21. Difficulty in coordinating the PEC budget is due to several factors. First of

all, there is the magnitude and sheer number of programs and agencies involved,

each with their own objectives, beneficiaries and rules.20

Secondly, it is difficult

for SAGARPA, a line ministry that chairs the CIDRS, to dictate to other line

ministries which ARD programs they should or should not have, and how they

should implement them. The situation would be different if CIDRS and the

annual PEC formulating exercise were under the mandate of Presidencia or the

SHCP. A third reason is the absence of a comprehensive national ARD strategy

with measurable objectives and outcomes and a clear indication of how different

programs would serve to achieve them. Partly because of this, many programs

that were initiated as temporary interventions responding to transitory situations

became permanent over time. Also, due to the absence of a national ARD

20

PEC programs are implemented by 13 out of the 18 federal ministries, as well as state governments for

decentralized programs, other entities of the federal government and the legislative branch of government.

In recent years PEC has included close to 100 different programs, although the consolidation of the 2008

PEC resulted in a reduction to 73 programs, 85 sub-programs and 94 components.

Page 34: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

14

strategy, the majority of programs are formulated to serve objectives and criteria

of the originating agency, or even of specific offices within those agencies. As a

result, the PEC budget encompasses numerous programs, sub-programs and

components with duplicating, or at times even contradicting activities, as well as

with noticeable gaps. The introduction of PEC as an accounting instrument was a

valuable step forward in bringing transparency to ARD budgetary allocations, and

is a first step towards coordination and consistency in ARD expenditures. PEC,

however, is not yet fulfilling its role as the mechanism to promote the efficient

allocation and use of public resources to promote ARD.

CLASSIFICATION OF ARD PROGRAMS

22. This section classifies the PEC budget (2006) into various categories: public-

private, social-productive, targeted to the poor-untargeted, etc., in order to better

understand the structure of Mexican ARD expenditures.21

The classification

exercise is complex and leaves room for subjective judgment, partly because the

categories themselves are not always clear-cut, and partly because many programs

have sub-programs and components falling under different categories.22

Programs have been disaggregated to the lowest level possible to enable proper

classification. Whenever available, data from SHCP accounts of the executed

budget were used. When these data were only available at the aggregate level,

additional information was used to allow for disaggregation.23

23. Public goods programs. Included here are programs typically provided by

governments in market economies, generally because they supply goods or

services whose consumption is neither excludable nor rivalrous.24

These

programs usually include investments like rural infrastructure (excluding on-farm

structures), and general social or productive services such as rural education and

health, telecommunications, information, training and research systems,

technology transfer to small producers, sanitary systems, natural resource

conservation and environmental programs, emergency programs, and operational

budgets of institutions. Table 2-2 presents the breakdown of these programs in

PEC.

21

The classification was conducted for 2006 since this was the latest year for which a completed executed

budget was available at the level of disaggregation necessary for the analysis. 22

Because of this, some programs appear under more than one category. The amounts appearing in the

different categories correspond to that spent in the sub-programs or components falling under the category.

This is the case, for instance, of Fondo para la Infraestructura Social Municipal (FISM), part of which is

classified as ―social‖ and part as ―indirectly productive‖, and of Alianza, partly classified as a ―public

goods‖ and partly as a ―private goods‖ program. 23

Additional sources include implementing agency data and external evaluation reports. 24

―Excludable‖ means that persons can be prevented from consuming the good or service, and therefore it is

feasible to charge for its consumption. ―Rivalrous‖ means that consumption of a good or service by one

person reduces the availability for another person to consume. Economic principles dictate that it is most

efficient for the public sector to provide goods and services that are neither excludable nor rivalrous;

therefore they are called ―public goods‖. Also include here are ―quasi-public goods‖ falling between public

and private goods, for which beneficiaries are only partially excludable from the consumption of the good

or service, and the cost of providing the good or service is less than proportional to the number of

consumers, hence are not fully rivalrous, e.g. education often has the characteristics of a quasi-public good.

Page 35: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

15

Table2-2: Major Public Goods Programs (categorized into social, productive, and indirectly productive) 2006

MxP

Million

Percent

(%)

PUBLIC GOODS PROGRAMS 79,120.68 100.00

A. Social Programs 40,186.94 50.79

1. Fondo para la Infraestructura Social Municipal (FISM) dentro del Ramo 33. Aportaciones

a estados y municipios 8,681.40 10.97

2. SPSS (Sistema de Protección Social en Salud) 8,653.10 10.94

3. Aportaciones federales dentro del Ramo 33. Aportaciones a estados y municipios 7,939.40 10.03

4. Programa IMSS-Oportunidades (sin Salud Indígena y Progresa) 5,151.90 6.51

5. Comisión Nacional de Desarrollo de los Pueblos Indígenas (CONADEPI) 4,790.70 6.05

6. Enciclomedia 1,801.60 2.28

7. Programas Alimentarios de DICONSA y LICONSA 1,593.00 2.01

8. Forestal (incluye Proárbol) 761.94 0.96

9. Áreas naturales protegidas 465.50 0.59

10. Programa de Atención a Jornaleros Agrícolas 137.90 0.17

11. Otros 210.50 0.27

B. Productive Programs 24,043.74 30.39

1 Programa de desarrollo de capacidades (SEP) 4,975.50 6.29

2. Fondo para la Infraestructura Social Municipal (FISM) dentro del Ramo 33. Aportaciones

a estados y municipios 4,695.20 5.93

3. Infraestructura hidroagrícola 3,297.10 4.17

4. Actividades recurrentes de apoyo productivo con presupuesto regular de SAGARPA* 2,943.10 3.72

5. Caminos rurales 1,823.20 2.30

6. Alianza para el Campo** 1,529.14 1.93

7. Forestal (incluye Proárbol) 913.50 1.15

8. Programa Normal de Sanidades 801.40 1.01

9. Sistema Financiero Rural 677.80 0.86

10. Microrregiones (incluye FONAES) 638.00 0.81

11. Otros 1,749.80 2.21

C. Programas de Fomento Productivo Indirecto (Indirectly Productive) 14,890.00 18.82

1. Gasto operativo (netamente administrativo) de la SAGARPA 4,485.80 5.67

2. Educación agropecuaria (SEP) 3,843.30 4.86

3. Instituciones de Educación Agropecuaria dependientes de SAGARPA 1,910.70 2.41

4. Conflictos y Conciliación Agraria 824.40 1.04

5. Gasto operativo de los Tribunales Agrarios 584.20 0.74

6. Procuraduría Agraria 583.70 0.74

7. Gasto operativo de la SRA 545.20 0.69

8. Programa de Certificación de Derechos Ejidales y Titulación de Solares (PROCEDE) 487.90 0.62

9. INEGI 363.50 0.46

10. Registro Agrario Nacional (RAN) 361.70 0.46

11. Otros 899.60 1.14

Source: Oliver and Santillanes (2008)

24. Private goods programs. Included here are programs that are usually provided

(or could be provided) by the private sector in market economies (mostly because

they supply goods or services whose consumption is excludable and rivalrous),

and also government programs that provide measurable subsidies to individuals or

Page 36: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

16

families usually under some targeting criteria.25

Included in this category are,

inter alia, subsidies to on-farm productive infrastructure and equipment, subsidies

to rural credit and agricultural insurance, input support, marketing support, and

compensatory cash transfers. It should not be assumed that government funding

of private goods is necessarily undesirable. There are private goods that are

productivity enhancing and may make sense for government to invest in them for

policy purposes, even if they consist of measurable subsidies to individuals or

families. This is for instance the case with Oportunidades, which enhances

human capital, and with many Alianza subsidies, which enhance the productive

potential of farms. Table 2-3 presents the breakdown of these programs.

Table 2-3: Major Private Goods Programs (categorized into public, private, and indirect private programs) 2006

MxP Million Percent (%)

PRIVATE GOODS PROGRAMS 73,812.70 100.00

A. Social Programs 29,726.00 40.27

1. Oportunidades (Educación – SEP) 13,941.50 46.90

2. Oportunidades (SEDESOL) 11,793.90 39.68

3. Programa de Vivienda Rural 2,207.50 7.43

4. Oportunidades (Salud – SSA) 1,108.60 3.73

5. Fondo para pago de adeudos a braceros rurales del 42 al 64 298.50 1.00

6. Adultos Mayores en Zonas Rurales 297.90 1.00

7. Apoyo para la repatriación de cadáveres a México 39.40 0.13

8. Asistencia jurídica urgente a mexicanos en EE.UU. y defensa de condenados a muerte 17.00 0.06

9. Migrantes en situación de probada indigencia 8.10 0.03

10. Otros 13.60 0.05

B. Productive Programs 43,825.90 59.37

1. PROCAMPO 15,024.50 34.28

2. Ingreso Objetivo (maíz, frijol, sorgo, algodón, arroz, trigo, soya…)/Apoyos directos al

productor por excedentes de comercialización 6,961.23 15.88

3. Alianza para el Campo 4,900.10 11.18

4. Programas Hidráulicos 3,807.40 8.69

5. Fondo de Compensación a Costos Energéticos Agrícolas 2,684.20 6.12

6. Fondo de Apoyo a la Competitividad de las Ramas Productivas 2,258.30 5.15

7. Programa Ganadero (PROGAN) 2,070.00 4.72

8. Programa de Empleo Temporal (SCT)* 791.90 1.81

9. FOMAGRO (FIRCO) 746.70 1.70

10. Forestal (incluye Proárbol) 635.16 1.45

11. AGROASEMEX (Fondos de Aseguramiento y de Microseguros) 520.00 1.19

12. Otros 3,426.41 7.82

C. Indirect Productive Programs 260.80 0.35

45. Obligaciones Jurídicas Ineludibles 260.80 0.35

Source: Oliver and Santillanes (2008).

25. Productive programs: These programs are targeted at directly improving the

productive capacity of agriculture or other rural economic activities. They

25

By including measurable subsidies to private individuals of families, this category includes cash transfer

programs such as PROCAMPO and Oportunidades, and to ―merit goods‖ programs (Musgrave, 1959) like

Vivienda Rural.

Page 37: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

17

include, inter alia, productive infrastructure, agricultural research and technology

transfer, sanitary systems, subsidies to rural credit and agricultural insurance,

improvements of productive resources, production subsides, marketing supports,

and marketing information. A different category labeled indirect productive

programs expenses captures those aimed at improving productive capacity but

with less direct impact on production as well as ministerial expenses to operate

the relevant programs. This category includes programs such as tertiary level

agricultural education, agricultural institutional programs, and land registry

programs, as well as ministerial operational budgets.

26. Social programs: These programs consist of expenditures aimed at improving the

general living conditions of the rural population and are not directly oriented at

expanding their productive capacity. Included here are, inter alia, the

improvement of social infrastructure, cash transfers not tied to current or

historical productive use, education, health and social welfare programs, and

consumption support programs. Naturally, social programs have an indirect

productive impact, but their primary aim is to improve the wellbeing of the

beneficiaries not their productive capacity.

27. Targeted and untargeted programs: Programs can further be categorized into

those that are targeted to the poor, small producers and vulnerable groups and

those that are not. Included in targeted programs are those oriented to the

indigenous populations, peasant women and casual workers, as well as other

programs aimed at improving the conditions of small producers or the rural poor

in which targeting is mandated in the operation rules, even if in practice a good

part of the expenditures does not actually reach the poor. Non-targeted

programs are those benefiting the rural population at large, not specifically aimed

at small producers, vulnerable groups or the poor.

28. Program decentralization: Another potential distinction is between centralized

and decentralized programs. This distinction, however, is difficult to establish in

practice because decentralization has several dimensions and the situation of

programs differs according to these dimensions (see Box 2-1). The design,

normative aspects and most or all funding of programs included in PEC come for

the federal level although there already is some level of decentralization in the so-

called ―decentralized‖ subprograms of Alianza.

Box 2-1: Dimensions in the Decentralization of Rural Development Programs in Mexico

The many rural sector programs that exist in Mexico operate under different institutional arrangements.

Some devolve decision-making power to sub-national governments to various extents, while others keep

most or all aspects under the control of central authorities. A simple centralization/ decentralization

dichotomy is insufficient to describe how rural programs work, for program processes move along several

dimensions, some under the control of central authorities, others under sub-national governments.

a) Funding source. Funding of rural programs may come from one, two or all three levels of government.

For most programs the federal level provides all or most of the resources. The programs, for instance, of

SRA (PROMUSAG and FAPPA) and SECON (FONAES) do not have as a rule, state or municipal

counterpart funding. When two government levels contribute, they are usually the federal and state

governments. This is the case with the Agriculture and Livestock sub-programs of Alianza or the

Page 38: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

18

PRODEFOR program of CONAFOR. A combination of federal and municipal funding, like in FIRCO‘s

Microcuencas program, does exist but is uncommon. In hardly any program do all three levels of

government contribute funds, with the exception of Alianza‘s Rural Development Program (PDR). Only in

the case of states‘ own programs, like the fertilizer program of the Secretaría de Desarrollo Rural in

Guerrero or the Núcleos de Desarrollo Comunitario program of the Secretaría de Desarrollo Humano in

Jalisco, does funding come exclusively from state sources. Rural Development programs financed entirely

by municipalities are rare.

b) Regulatory authority. Program operational rules serve to establish objectives and set forth key

implementation asepects, ranging from the eligibility criteria to the amount and type of benefits. Except for

states‘ own programs, these rules are issued by the federal government. All rural development programs

from federal ministries operate under centralized rules. When states and municipalities are involved in

program funding, additional criteria may be agreed between the government levels involved, formalized as

convenios and anexos técnicos, which usually include budgetary and programmatic provisions. Alianza´s

decentralized sub-programs are an example of this.

c) Allocation of funds to States. Most rural development programs operate on a demand basis, i.e.

producers apply for and compete for funding. In the case of centralized programs, competition may be at

the national level, in which case no allocation or indicative disbursement figure is given to the states. This

is for instance the case with CONAFOR‘s PRODEPLAN. In other cases, like in SEDESOL‘s

Oportunidaes Productivas and in FONAES, annual expenditure ceilings are established for each state, and

proposals compete at the state-level within those ceilings. Funds, however, are kept at the federal level. In

the case of decentralized programs, not only funds are allocated to the states, they are actually transferred to

fideicomisos located in the states where they are mixed with local funds.

d) Spending authority. Even when funds come from federal sources, prioritization and selection of

proposals may involve sub-national governments. The most centralized scenario is when the selection

process is carried out centrally by federal ministries. This can be done with the prior advice of a state-level

joint committee, like in the SRA‘s programs, or without it, like in the Integración Productiva, Agencias de

Desarrollo Local and Fondo de Financiamiento Social programs of SEDESOL‘s Oportunidades

Productivas. In other cases, like in FONAES, proposals under a certain amount are approved by the state

offices of the corresponding ministry. In more decentralized scenarios, joint state-federal committees may

conduct preliminary selection of proposals with the final decision being left to the federal level. A more

decentralized process is when, like in Alianza‘s decentralized programs or in CONAFOR‘s PRODEFOR

program, state-level joint committees or even municipal-level committees make the final decision. Total

decentralization of spending occurs when the use of resources is decided by sub-national authorities alone,

but this only happens with state‘s own programs.

e) Operational tasks. Rural development programs entail a number of operational tasks, such as promotion

and dissemination, reception and processing of applications, technical formulation of proposals, and

supervision of activities. Different government levels may take part in these tasks, which are usually

supported by private providers of services.

Source: World Bank 2006a

THE PEC STRUCTURE

29. ARD expenditures are equally divided between public and private goods.26

In 2006, 52 percent of PEC (MxP 79 billion) went to public goods programs and

26

Lopez and Galinato (2007) analyze the rural public expenditure of LAC countries for 1985-2001using a

FAO database which shows that 66 percent of Mexico‘s rural public expenditure is private, which is the

fourth highest in the region after Brazil (87 percent), Dominican Republic (80 percent), and Guatemala (69

percent). Contrarily, Honduras (9 percent) and Uruguay (19 percent) have the lowest shares. The

definition of rural expenditure used in this FAO study does not coincide with that of the PEC since

universal social services such as education and health are also included in the FAO‘s definition of rural

expenditure.

Page 39: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

19

the remaining 48 percent (MxP 73.8 billion) to private goods programs (Table 2-

4). The implementation of public programs was led by SAGARPA (17 percent),

followed by the Ministry of Education (14 percent), and the Ministry of Health

(11 percent, spent mainly in seguro popular). In addition, budget transfers from

the federal government to states and municipalities, used mainly for rural

infrastructure, amounted to 27 percent of public goods programs. Expenditure in

private goods concentrated in three ministries: SAGARPA (48 percent, mainly for

PROCAMPO, Apoyos, Alianza and PROGAN), SEDESOL (20 percent, for

Oportunidades and the rural housing program), and the Ministry of Education (19

percent, also for Oportunidades).

Table 2-4: ARD Public and Private Goods Programs by Government Agency (2006)

Allocation Total Public Goods Private Goods

MxP Million Percent (%) MxP Million Percent (%) MxP

Million Percent (%)

Total 152,933.38 100.00 79,120.68 100.00 73,812.70 100.00

04. Gobernación 298.50 0.20 0.00 0.00 298.50 0.40

05. Relaciones Exteriores 109.20 0.07 31.10 0.04 78.10 0.11

06. Hacienda y Crédito

Público 6,180.50 4.04 5,331.90 6.74 848.60 1.15

08. SAGARPA 48,898.69 31.97 13,538.94 17.11 35,359.75 47.90

09. SCT 2,634.00 1.72 1,842.10 2.33 791.90 1.07

10. Economía 654.39 0.43 39.10 0.05 615.29 0.83

11. Educación Pública 24,594.90 16.08 10,653.40 13.46 13,941.50 18.89

12. Salud 9,790.80 6.40 8,682.20 10.97 1,108.60 1.50

14. Trabajo y Previsión

Social 74.10 0.05 74.10 0.09 0.00 0.00

15. Reforma Agraria 4,342.00 2.84 3,034.50 3.84 1,307.50 1.77

16. SEMARNAT 10,930.40 7.15 6,385.94 8.07 4,544.46 6.16

19. Aportaciones a

Seguridad 5,151.90 3.37 5,151.90 6.51 0.00 0.00

20. Desarrollo Social 17,372.30 11.36 2,455.30 3.10 14,917.00 20.21

21. Turismo 1.50 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.50 0.00

31. Tribunales Agrarios 584.20 0.38 584.20 0.74 0.00 0.00

33. Aportaciones

Federales a Estados y

Municipios 21,316.00 13.94 21,316.00 26.94 0.00 0.00

Source: Oliver and Santillanes (2008) using data from SHCP

30. ARD expenditures are equally distributed between social and productive

programs. Thus, 46 percent of PEC (MxP 70 billion) went to social programs,

44 percent (MxP 68 billion) to productive programs, and 10 percent (MxP 15

billion) to indirectly productive programs 27

(see Table 2-5). Social programs

were mainly implemented by SEDESOL (Oportunidades, rural housing, and food

27

It should be noted that the even distribution of ARD expenditures between productive and social

programs is influenced by the classification of PROCAMPO as a productive program. PROCAMPO could

arguably be classified as a social program since its objective is to support farmers‘ incomes rather than to

boost production, and there is no conditionality on the use of the entitlement. If PROCAMPO were

classified as a social program, social programs would account for 55.5 percent of ARD expenditures,

productive programs for 34.6 percent and indirectly productive programs for 9.9 percent.

Page 40: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

20

programs), the Ministry of Education (Oportunidades and Enciclomedia), and the

Ministry of Health (social protection system and Oportunidades). These three

ministries accounted for nearly half (49 percent) of spending in rural social

programs. Almost three quarters of the expenditure in productive programs was

executed by SAGARPA (in particular PROCAMPO, Alianza, Apoyos, and

PROGAN), followed by SEMARNAT, mainly for irrigation infrastructure, and

the Ministry of Education for programs in agriculture technical training and plant

breeding training. Indirect productive programs comprised mainly tertiary

level agricultural education, and regular recurrent costs of agencies implementing

PEC programs. These costs come mainly from three ministries, SAGARPA, the

Ministry of Education and the Ministry of Land Reform, which were jointly

responsible for 91 percent of this spending category.

31. Production-oriented public goods programs are underfunded despite their

importance for ARD. Table shows that less than one third of spending in public

goods programs goes to directly production-oriented programs. The largest

spending in production-oriented programs of a public goods type was for

productive infrastructure (10.1 percent of public goods), training programs by the

Ministry of Education (6.3 percent), the productive part of FAIS, irrigation

infrastructure, and the public goods sub-programs of Alianza (5.7 percent). The

low level of spending by SAGARPA is noticeable given its mandate for the

development of the rural productive sector. SAGARPA allocates only 9.1 percent

of its total budget to production-oriented programs of a public goods type.

Considering the documented importance for production activities of the provision

of public goods28

, the fact that only 16 percent of PEC is for production-oriented

public goods programs signals overfunding of private goods, some of which could

potentially be reallocated to the funding of public goods (see Box 2-2).

Table 2-5: Cross-classification of Public/Private and Social/Productive ARD Programs, 2006

Total Cost Social Productive Indirect Productive

MxP

Million

Percent

(%)

MxP

Million

Percent

(%)

MxP

Million

Percent

(%)

MxP

Million Percent (%)

Total Cost 152,933.38 100.00 69,912.94 100.00 67,869.64 100.00 15,150.80 100.00

Public 79,120.68 51.74 40,186.94 57.48 24,043.74 35.43 14,890.00 98.28

Private 73,812.70 48.26 29,726.00 42.52 43,825.90 64.57 260.80 1.72

Source: Oliver and Santillanes (2008) using data from SHCP

Box 2-2: Efficiency gains from switching from private to public goods

Recent econometric work finds that in many countries in the LAC region it is crucial to shift rural public

expenditures from large subsidies going to specific groups of producers and towards the increased

provision of public goods1. As an illustration of the importance of the mix of spending between private and

public good, R. Lopez used the FAO LAC Regional Office database from several countries (1985-2001) to

classify expenditures. Public goods included technology generation and transfer, soil conservation, sanitary

and phytosanitary protection, communications and information services, rural infrastructure, and social

services (education and health). Private goods included commodity-specific or focalized items, marketing

assistance and promotion, subsidized credit, and irrigation.

28

For the importance the investment public goods see Lopez and Galinato (2007), World Bank (2005a),

World Bank (2008).

Page 41: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

21

The key message from the analysis is that while government expenditures do have a positive effect on

agricultural per capita income, the composition of those expenditures is important. The long-run effects on

per capita agricultural GDP of increasing the share of expenditures going to subsidies were large and

negative (and highly statistically significant.) A reallocation of 10% points of public expenditures from

subsidies to public goods would increase per capita agricultural income by about 2.3 % without increasing

total expenditures. On the poverty side, the analysis found no statistically significant direct effect of the

mix of expenditures on poverty, in part due to the poor state of rural poverty data. The main impact of the

mix of public expenditures on poverty is indirect, through the effect on per capita agricultural income.

Overall, the findings from the cross-country analysis of Lopez for Latin America are consistent with other

analyses for India and China, where spending on rural roads and agricultural research has been found to

have large poverty alleviation effects.

The allocation criteria for expenditures are not complex in theory – public goods should be a priority, and

coverage, targeting and the cost-effectiveness of transfers should enter any project evaluation. But

designing public spending is complicated in practice, because the policy maker would also need to have

empirical measures of the relevant ―elasticities‖ reflecting how agricultural growth and poverty reduction

responds to expenditures on various program categories. And from the national development perspective

one should have information on how national welfare responds to agricultural development. Policy design

is further complicated by the heterogeneity of farming conditions with respect to initial product mixes and

levels of productivity, access to infrastructure, soil fertility, and access to markets. This heterogeneity stems

in part from the natural resource base and geography, but also in part from the approach governments have

taken in the past to expenditures on public goods. Past investments in infrastructure and institutions, such

as telecommunications and transport, and the support network of finance, research and extension, will

determine the ability of small farmers to take advantage of opportunities in both domestic and international

markets. Finally, although the role of governments as the provider of public goods is well established, the

performance of governments is often disheartening. 1 The work by Ramon Lopez of the University of Maryland was pioneering in this area and first developed for the WB

regional report ―Beyond the City, The Rural Contribution to Development‖ in 2005, and later published as Lopez and

Galinato (2007).

Source: Valdes (2008b)

32. While the majority of social programs are targeted to the poor (including

small farmers and vulnerable groups), the majority of agriculture programs

are not targeted. Although the definition of poor differs significantly by each

program and has changed over time within programs, 96 percent of the

expenditure in social programs in PEC is targeted to the poor (Table 2-6), while

only 7.9 percent of the expenditure in agricultural programs is targeted (Table 2-

7). Because of leakages, part of the expenditure in some targeted programs may

not reach the poor. Oportunidades, which is the largest targeted program, is

particularly well targeted. Expenditures in other programs, particularly in those

involving infrastructure and area- or community-based targeting, are less well

targeted. On the other hand, part of the expenditure in non-targeted programs

favors the poor. This is, for instance, the case with PROCAMPO payments to

which small and very small farmers are eligible.

Table 2-6: Targeting of Social Programs

MxP

Million

Percent

(%)

SOCIAL PROGRAMS 69,912.94 100.00

A. Programs targeted at poor 66,865.00 95.64

21. Oportunidades (Educación – SEP) 13,941.50 19.94

Page 42: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

22

2. Oportunidades (SEDESOL) 11,793.90 16.87

3. Fondo para la Infraestructura Social Municipal dentro del Ramo

33. Aportaciones a estados y municipios 8,681.40 12.42

4. SPSS (Sistema de Protección Social en Salud) 8,653.10 12.38

5. Aportaciones federales dentro del Ramo 33. Aportaciones a

estados y municipios 7,939.40 11.36

6. Programa IMSS-Oportunidades (sin Salud Indíg. y Progresa) 5,151.90 7.37

7. Comisión Nacional de Desarrollo de los Pueblos Indígenas

(CONADEPI) 4,790.70 6.85

8. Programa de Vivienda Rural 2,207.50 3.16

9. Programas Alimentarios 1,593.00 2.28

10. Oportunidades 1,108.60 1.59

11. Otros 1,004.00 1.44

B. Programs not targeted at poor 3,047.94 4.36

1. Enciclomedia 1,801.60 2.58

2. Forestal (incluye Proárbol) 761.94 1.09

3. Áreas naturales protegidas 465.50 0.67

4. Telefonía Rural 18.90 0.03

Source: Oliver and Santillanes (2008) using data from SHCP

Table 2-7: Targeting of Agriculture Programs

MxP

Million

Percent

(%)

AGRICULTURAL PROGRAMS 47,559.97 100.00

A. Programs targeted at poor 3,760.34 7.91

1. Alianza para el Campo (componente de desarollo rural) 2,083.55 4.38

2. FOMAGRO (FIRCO) 746.70 1.57

3. PIASRE 462.90 0.97

4. Fondo de Tierras 248.50 0.52

5. Fondo Nacional de Apoyos para Empresas en Solidaridad (FONAES) 173.59 0.36

6. Microcuencas (FIRCO) 45.10 0.09

B. Programs not targeted at poor 43,799.63 92.09

8. PROCAMPO 15,024.50 31.59

1. Apoyos directos al productor por excedentes de comercialización (Ingreso Objetivo y otros) 6,961.23 14.64

2. Programas Hidráulicos 3,807.40 8.01

3. Infraestructura hidroagrícola 3,297.10 6.93

4. Alianza para el Campo 2,976.98 6.26

5. Actividades recurrentes de apoyo productivo dentro del presupuesto regular de SAGARPA 2,863.70 6.02

6. Fondo de Compensación a Costos Energéticos Agrícolas 2,684.20 5.64

7. Fondo de Apoyo a la Competitividad de las Ramas Productivas 2,258.30 4.75

8. Programa Ganadero (PROGAN) 2,070.00 4.35

9.- Programa Normal de Sanidades 801.40 1.69

10. AGROASEMEX (Fondos de Aseguramiento y de Microseguros) 520.00 1.09

11. Programa de atención a Contingencias Climatológicas FAPRACC 337.82 0.71

12. Fondo de Apoyo a las Organizaciones Sociales, Agropecuarias y Pesqueras (PROSAP) 197.00 0.41

Source: Oliver and Santillanes (2008) using data from SHCP

33. In contrast to the importance of the non-farm sector in the rural economy,

PEC reflects an agro-centered view of rural development. Some 70 percent of

spending in production-oriented programs of a public goods type is for

Page 43: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

23

agricultural activities and 30 percent for programs open to other rural productive

activities (Table 2-10). The main programs in the latter category as shown in

Table 2-9 are the skills development program of the Ministry of Education, which

supports the enhancement of different rural technical skills (25 percent of non-

agricultural programs), a part of FAIS, which supports productive infrastructure

(23 percent), rural roads (9 percent), and forestry and other environmental

programs (7 percent). The weight of the agriculture programs is probably

underestimated since a good part of the resources of many not agriculture-specific

programs is probably, in fact, used to support agricultural activities.

Table 2-8: Main Agricultural Programs (2006)

MxP

Million

Percent

(%)

AGRICULTURAL PROGRAMS 47,559.97 100.00

A. Public Goods 8,736.69 18.37

1. Infraestructura hidroagrícola (Comisión Nacional del Agua – SEMARNAT) 3,297.10 10.13

2. Actividades recurrentes de apoyo productivo dentro del presupuesto regular de SAGARPA

(organismos sanitarios, y de investigación, información y capacitación) 2,853.80 8.77

3. Alianza para el Campo 1,079.39 3.32

4. Programa Normal de Sanidades 801.40 2.46

5. Programa Integral de Agricultura Sostenible y Reconversión Productiva (PIASRE) 462.90 1.42

6. Fondo de Apoyo a las Organizaciones Sociales, Agropecuarias y Pesqueras (PROSAP) 197.00 0.61

7. Microcuencas (FIRCO) 45.10 0.14

B. Private Goods 38,823.28 81.63

1. PROCAMPO 15,024.50 38.70

2. Ingreso Objetivo (maíz, frijol, sorgo, algodón, arroz, trigo, soya…)/Apoyos directos al

productor por excedentes de comercialización 6,961.23 17.93

3. Alianza para el Campo 3,981.14 10.25

4. Programas Hidráulicos 3,807.40 9.81

5. Fondo de Compensación a Costos Energéticos Agrícolas 2,684.20 6.91

6. Fondo de Apoyo a la Competitividad de las Ramas Productivas 2,258.30 5.82

7. Programa Ganadero (PROGAN) 2,070.00 5.33

8. FOMAGRO (FIRCO) 746.70 1.92

9. AGROASEMEX (Fondos de Aseguramiento y de Microseguros) 520.00 1.34

10. Programa de atención a Contingencias Climatológicas FAPRACC 337.82 0.87

11. Fondo de Tierras 248.50 0.64

12. Fondo Nacional de Apoyos para Empresas en Solidaridad (FONAES) 173.59 0.45

13.Actividades recurrentes de apoyo productivo dentro del presupuesto regular de SAGARPA 9.90 0.03

Source: Oliver and Santillanes (2008) using data from SHCP

Table 2-9: Main Non-Agricultural (Productive) Specific Programs (2006)

MxP

Million

Percent

(%)

NON_AGRICULTURAL SPECIFIC PROGRAMS 20,309.67 100.00

A. Public Goods 15,307.05 75.37

1. Programa de desarrollo de capacidades (SEP) 4,975.50 24.50

2. Fondo para la Infraestructura Social Municipal dentro del Ramo 33. Aportaciones a

estados y municipios 4,695.20 23.12

3. Caminos rurales 1,823.20 8.98

4. Forestal (incluye Proárbol) 913.50 4.50

5. Sistema Financiero Rural dentro de las acciones de SAGARPA 677.80 3.34

Page 44: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

24

6. Microrregiones (incluye FONAES) 638.00 3.14

7. Alianza para el Campo (apoyo a acuacultura y pesca) 449.75 2.21

8. Otros de Medio Ambiente 448.10 2.21

9. Fomento y Organización Agraria 143.50 0.71

10. Financiera Rural 127.70 0.63

11. Otros 414.80 2.04

B. Private Goods 5,002.62 24.63

1. Alianza para el Campo (acuacultura y pesca) 918.96 4.52

2. Programa de Empleo Temporal (componente operado por la SCT) 791.90 3.90

3. Forestal (incluye Proárbol) 635.16 3.13

4. Programa de la Mujer en el Sector Agrario (PROMUSAG) 482.40 2.38

5. Programa de Opciones Productivas 400.60 1.97

6.- Dar Continuidad a los Apoyos al Sector Pesquero 314.20 1.55

7. Fondo Nacional de Apoyos para Empresas en Solidaridad (FONAES) 311.40 1.53

8. Fondo de Apoyo para Proyectos Productivos (FAPPA) 291.40 1.43

9. Financiera Rural 202.30 1.00

10. Programa de Empleo Temporal (componente operado por la SEDESOL) 196.40 0.97

11. Otros 457.90 2.25

Source: Oliver and Santillanes (2008) using data from SHCP

34. Agricultural programs are skewed towards private goods and non-

agricultural programs towards public goods. More than 80 percent of the

agricultural programs are private, while more than 75 percent of those non-

specifically oriented to agriculture are public (Table 2-10). Echoing the argument

with productive goods in general, the low level of public spending for agricultural

activities is noticeable given the evidence of its superior growth impact. As

indicated above, non- agriculture specific programs focus on the provision of

public goods such as skills training and rural infrastructure. Non-agriculture

specific programs other than the ones mentioned above have tended to be

somewhat ad-hoc pilot-type experiences reflecting the difficulty in designing non-

agricultural rural productive programs in the absence of a multi-sectorial national

rural development strategy.

Table 2-10: Productive programs cross-referenced with public/private and agriculture/non-agriculture (2006)

Total Cost Agricultural

Not specifically

agricultural

MxP

Million Percent (%) MxP Million

Percent

(%) MxP Million

Percent

(%)

Total 67,869.64 100.00 47,559.97 100.00 20,309.67 100.00

Public 24,043.74 35.43 8,736.69 18.37 15,307.05 75.37

Private 43,825.59 64.57 38,823.28 81.63 5,002.62 24.63

Source: Oliver and Santillanes (2008)

CHANGES IN THE 2008 PEC

35. An effort was made in 2007 to consolidate the 2008 PEC budget. In 2007, a

new, more compact functional classification scheme was introduced,

consolidating the wide multiplicity of PEC programs into nine broad groups and

Page 45: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

25

16 programs (see Table 2-11). Some simplification in the operational rules of

programs was also introduced in the 2008 budget. However, this reform did not

involve an actual integration or coordination of the original programs, which in

the 2008 PEC numbered 73, many of them containing multiple subprograms. The

principal group within the broader classification, Competitiveness, represents

almost 40 percent of PEC and includes productive programs as traditionally

defined (Alianza), the ASERCA compensatory programs, input subsidies, and

even targeted education spending (including Oportunidades).

Table 2-11: 2008 PEC Budget

PEC 2008

Total budget (million MxP) 204,000

Groups (Programs)

Competitiveness 39.4% Educación 13.3% Apoyos Directos al Campo 8.2% Adquisición de activos productivos 8.0% Atención a problemas estructurales 5.8% Soporte 1.8% Inducción y Desarrollo del Financiamiento al Medio Rural 1.6% Atención a Contingencias Climatológicas 0.4% Apoyo a la participación de actores para el desarrollo rural 0.4%

Infrastructure (Infraestructura en el medio rural) 20.6%

Social (Atención a la pobreza en el medio rural) 16.3%

Health (Atención a las condiciones de salud en el medio rural) 9.3%

Environmental (Uso sustentable de recursos naturales para la prod. Primaria) 6.5%

Administrative (Gasto administrativo) 4.9%

Financial (Financiamiento y aseguramiento al medio rural) 1.6%

Labor (Mejoramiento de condiciones laborales en el medio rural) 0.8%

Land Reform (Atención de aspectos agrarios) 0.6%

Source: Scott (2008)

36. The new structure of PEC reveals little spending in some critical areas like

finance, labor and land related programs. Together, the first two categories

(finance and labor) absorb just 2.4 percent of PEC, equivalent to half of

administrative spending. Only MxP 1.7 billion is allocated to rural employment

programs, which is less than 1 percent of the 2008 PEC. Land related programs

(known as programas agrarios in Mexico), which include, inter alia, access to

land, regularization of land rights, legal and other forms of support related to land

rights for ejidatarios and small farmers in general, and resolution of land

conflicts, absorb only 0.6 percent of PEC, in contrast to the importance of land

issues in Mexico. Social security/protection could probably be better identified as

a separate category but is included in the health and poverty programs. Until very

recently, it was practically non-existent in rural areas. This has changed

dramatically since the introduction and rapid growth of the Seguro Popular since

2004, and a minimum non-contributive universal rural pension started in 2007

(Adultos Mayores de 70 años y Más en Zonas Rurales). In 2008, following a

Page 46: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

26

large increase in the approved budget for the latter program (MxP 9.9 billion vs.

the originally proposed MxP 6.4 billion), these two programs account for

approximately 10 percent of PEC.

OTHER FISCAL COSTS OUTSIDE PEC

37. Although PEC captures the majority of public expenditure for rural

development except for universal social services (such as education and

health), there are policy measures implying fiscal costs that are not budget-

based and hence fall outside PEC but do contribute to the rural agenda. They

include tax exemptions, the Tarifa 9, which subsidies electricity tariffs to pump

groundwater, water tariff subsidies, agricultural credit subsidies, and subsidies to

crop insurance. The amounts of these implicit agricultural subsidies are

significant. Because of difficulties in quantifying the magnitude of each program,

only agricultural tax exemptions and Tarifa 9 are examined here.

38. The agricultural sector benefits from several tax exemptions totaling MxP

24.5 billion, which is approximately 5 percent of total tax exemptions and 8

percent of total income tax exemptions. There are 6 different exemption/incentive

categories for agriculture. The largest is the reduction in income tax, which totals

MxP 11.2 billion (Table 2-12). Other exemptions include deductions for

temporary farm worker subsistence (MxP 6.0 billion), for land dedicated to

agriculture (MxP 54 million), of income tax for individuals with up to 20 times

the agriculture minimum wage (salarios mínimos agropecuarios [SMA], MxP 4.8

billion), and for associations up to 40 times the agriculture minimum wage (MxP

2.4 billion).

Table 2-12: Tax exemptions and preferential treatment of the agricultural sector (2006)

MxP million % of National

GDP

Tax Exemption Total 24,547.6 0.27

1. 44.83% reduction in Income Tax (ISR)

11,203.8 0.12

2. Exoneration of 20 minimum agricultural wages (SMA) for

each associate or member (cap of 200 times the general

minimum wage of Mexico‘s Distrito Federal)

4,801.6 0.05

3. Deduction of 19% of revenue of self employed farmers to

cover casual work employment, animal feeding and incidental

expenses (no documentation required)

5,997.5 0.07

4.Exoneration of personal income tax (ISR) up to 40 minimum

agricultural wages (SMA)

2,382.8 0.03

5. Deduction of investments under the ―intermediate regime‖

107.9 0.00

6. Deduction for lands devoted to agricultural activities

(anticipated) 54.0 0.00

Source: Oliver and Santillanes (2008) using data from Presupuesto de Gastos Fiscales 2006

39. Agriculture uses 76 percent of available water resources in the country but

contributes only 1.9 percent of the water use fees and bulk water tariffs

Page 47: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

27

collected by the Comisión Nacional de Agua (CONAGUA). Despite the water

scarcity situation in many parts of the country, farmers pay only a portion of the

costs involved in delivering irrigation water. In addition, water charges, although

theoretically based on the volume of water used, are normally calculated per

hectare because of the lack of water measuring devices. The current water tariff

structure does not fully cover the operation and maintenance costs and

depreciation costs of irrigation infrastructure. Also, farmers pay a small fee when

their water use exceeds their concession (MxP 0.1 per cubic meter for excess

water use). This does not take into account the opportunity cost of water, which

would set the price at the marginal cost. Low water pricing and lack of

measurement encourage excessive water use and wasting, a situation that is far

from being unique to Mexico. In fact, in many countries, irrigation water costs

are highly subsidized, with farmers paying part only of the operation and

maintenance costs.29

Cost recovery for operation and maintenance of irrigation

systems is generally better in Mexico than in other developing countries.

40. The electricity subsidy is costly and promotes an unsustainable use of scarce

groundwater resources. The so-called Tarifa 9 is a subsidy on the tariff for

electricity use in agriculture, and is mainly used for pumping groundwater from

wells. The actual cost of generating and transmitting water in Mexico is

estimated to be MxP 1.44/kWh but farmers pay on average MxP 0.33/kWh, i.e.

only 23 percent of the actual cost.30

The subsidy implies that farmers pay on

average 29 percent of the electricity they consume, whereas industrial users pay

94 percent and urban domestic users 43 percent. The total cost of the electricity

subsidy for farmers was estimated to be MxP 8.0 billion in 2006.31

Underpricing

of water together with Tarifa 9 have strong environmental impacts, promoting the

overuse of Mexico‘s scarce water resources. The effects of Tarifa 9 are

particularly detrimental on groundwater resources, which also have serious

consequences for climate change adaptation strategies (see Box 2-3), also the

findings of World Bank (2008d) shows that it has very little positive impact on

poverty reduction since the majority of Tarifa 9 beneficiaries are well-off farmers

and poor farmers typically do not pump groundwater, instead they use water

wheels (norias) or surface water.32

Box 2-3: The role of agricultural subsidies in Mexico’s water crisis

Mexico now faces a ―water crisis‖ that includes the overexploitation of 102 of its 653 aquifers, accounting

for more than half of groundwater extraction in the country. The National Water Commission

(CONAGUA) estimates groundwater over-extraction at almost 40 percent of total groundwater use. The

value of the over-extracted groundwater in agricultural production alone is estimated at more than US$1.2

billion or 0.2 percent of GDP. The depletion of many aquifers leads to non-price and unregulated

rationing, distorting growth in Mexico‘s most dynamic economic regions.

29

World Bank (2007) 30

Muñoz Piña, Avila Forcada, et. al (2006). 31

Primer Informe de Gobierno del Presidente Calderon as cited in Gomez and Santillanes (2008). 32

Of the 105,000 recipients of the subsidy, 68,000 receive an annual subsidy of less than MxP 30,000,

while 33 users receive a subsidy of over MxP 500,000. This amounts to a Gini coefficient of 0.91 for the

distribution of the subsidy (World Bank, 2007a).

Page 48: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

28

The map below shows the locations of the 188 most important aquifers and their levels of exploitation.

Most of the extremely overexploited aquifers are in the central-northern regions of Mexico where water

scarcity is an issue and where the most active water-using economic sectors operate. The geographical

distribution of this resource implies scarcity where the economic activity is taking place.

The 188 Most Important Aquifers and their Levels of Exploitation

Source: INE (2006) using data from CNA, Water Statistics in Mexico, 2005 edition

Some apparent contradictions between the Constitution and national water laws and regulations further

complicate this sort of rationing, particularly in relation to disenfranchised populations. Although some

irrigation is shifting to water-saving technologies, the shift is limited, and the crop mix remains largely the

same because (i) water and electricity prices still give the false signal that water is abundant, and (ii)

irrigation infrastructure is insufficient to allow farmers to shift to specialty crops. Moreover, agricultural

producers benefit from low electricity tariffs for pumping (tarifa 9). Consequently, farmers have little

incentive to change current practices, which result in over-pumping of aquifers, lowering of the

groundwater tables, and in many cases the intrusion of salt water. In addition, the financial cost to society

of the approximately US$700 million per year electricity subsidy may represent only a fraction of the full

economic cost, since environmental degradation is not valued properly.

One such example of environmental degradation caused by the inappropriate use of groundwater is the

deterioration of semi-aquatic ecosystem wetlands. These ecosystems are considered among the world‘s

most important because they provide a unique habitat to a large number of species of flora and fauna. They

also support the migration cycles of aquatic birds, 12 species of which winter in Mexico‘s wetlands. For

this reason Mexico has supported the preservation of these habitats by incorporating 51 wetlands in the

Ramsar Convention. However, many of these sites are threatened by the lack of fresh water provided by

groundwater. Such is the case of the Xochimilco wetlands, as well as the Lerma and Aguascalientes

springs and many of central Mexico‘s major lakes (Chapala, Cuitzeo, and Pátzcuaro).

Source: Muñoz Piña, C., Avila Forcada, S. et. al., (2006) and Asad and Dinar (2006)

Page 49: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

29

RELATIVE SIZE OF ARD EXPENDITURES

41. The fiscal costs outside PEC quantified above amount to MxP 32.6 billion,

equivalent to 21.3 percent of PEC.33

Including these costs, total fiscal expenses

for ARD increase to MxP 185.5 billion (Table 2-13). Both tax exemptions and

the electricity subsidy can be classified as production-oriented, private goods type

subsidies, thus changing somewhat the balance among expenditure categories. By

including these fiscal expenses, the share of public goods fall from 51.7 to 42.6

percent of total ARD expenditures, while production-oriented expenses increase

from 44.4 to 54.1 percent (Table 2-5 and Table 2-13).

Table 2-13: Total Fiscal Expenses for ARD Including PEC and other Fiscal Costs in 2006

Total Cost Social Productive

Indirectly

Productive

MxP

Million

Percent

(%)

MxP

Million

Percent

(%)

MxP

Million

Percent

(%)

MxP

Million Percent (%)

Total 185,480.98 100.00 69,912.94 100.00 100,417.24 100.00 15,150.80 100.00

Public 79,120.68 42.65 40,186.94 57.48 24,043.74 23.94 14,890.00 98.28

Private 106,360.30 57.35 29,726.00 42.52 76,373.50 76.06 260.80 1.72

Source: Oliver and Santillanes (2008) using data from SHCP

42. Total rural expenditure (including universal social services) is estimated to

be MxP 382 billion, which represents a quarter of total public spending and 4

percent of national GDP. The estimate of ARD fiscal expenses in Table 2-13

does not include rural public spending on universal social services (general

education and health services, social security, and other general subsidies such as

the residential electricity subsidy). The rural share of these public expenditures

was estimated at 27.5 percent in World Bank (2004a). Adding these to the former

estimate of ARD expenditures implies that total rural spending is approximately

MxP 382 billion, representing a quarter of total public spending and 4 percent of

national GDP (Table 2-14).

43. This represents a very significant fiscal effort on behalf of the rural

population. Given the current share of the rural sector in the national population

(24 percent), it implies that average public expenditure per capita is now similar

in the urban and rural sectors, without an ―urban bias‖ in the allocation of public

expenditures and subsidies. In fact, when taking into account the contribution to

the fiscal revenue, there may even be a ―rural bias‖ in the expenditure. However,

there is evidence that the quality of public services is significantly lower in rural

areas.34

44. The magnitude of these expenditures is evident if measured in relation to the

weight of the ARD sector in the national economy. Agricultural GDP was 3.5

33

Since only two fiscal expenses were quantified (tax exemptions and tarifa 9), the actual total fiscal

expenses are expected to be higher. 34

See for instance World Bank (2004c) Chapter 3.A, and OECD (2007d) pages 132-33.

Page 50: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

30

percent of GDP in 2006, but rural GDP is considerably larger. Using ENIGH

data, the share of the rural sector in national GDP is estimated to be 11 percent .35

From the above, the total APE for 2006 (agricultural programs within the PEC

plus the agricultural tax exemption and tarifa 9) as estimated in this study (MxP

80,108 million), represents 43 percent of Agricultural GDP, while total ARD

expenditures (MxP 185,481 million, consisting of the entire PEC plus

agricultural tax exemptions and tarifa 9) and total rural expenditures (including

also universal social services, social security and residential electricity subsidies,

MxP 381,636 million) represent, respectively, 18 percent and 38 percent of rural

GDP (Table 2-14).

Table 2-14: Agricultural and Rural GDP and Public Expenditure

National Agriculture Rural (pop. 0-2,500)

Share

(%) Share (%)

Share

(%)

(1) Population (2006, million) 104 100.0%

6.0

(workers)

14%

(workers) 24.5 23.6%

(2) GDP (2006, MxP million) 9,175,564 100.0% 318,158 3.5% 1,007,807a 11.0%

(3) Public RURAL expenditure

(PEC+foregone ag. tax+tarifa

9 , MxP million) 185,481 100.0% 80,108 43.2% 185,481 100.0%

(4) Public expenditure ((3) +

other universal servicesb, MxP

million) 996,037 100.0% - - 381,636c 38.3%

(5) Expenditure/GDP [(3)/(2)] - 2.0% - 25.2% - 18.4%

(6) Expenditure (incl. universal

social services)/GDP [(4)/(2)] - 10.9% - - - 37.9%

Source: Rural population from CONAPO‘s population projection, Agriculture labor population from

ENOE (Encuesta Nacional de Ocupación y Empleo)

Note:

(a) Rural GDP estimated using ENIGH data on share of agricultural and non-agricultural income

(approximately 25/75) in rural households

(b) ―Other universal services‖ include universal social services (general health and educational services),

social security, and residential electric subsidy

(c) Rural share of universal social services estimated using 2006 spending figure and a share of 24.2% for

the rural sector (World Bank, 2004a)

35

To obtain an estimate of rural GDP, the relative share of agricultural/non-agricultural income in the rural

sector as observed in ENIGH (approx. 25/75) is used to estimate non-agricultural rural GDP.

Page 51: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

31

Page 52: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

32

3. EFFICIENCY ASSESSMENT

45. This section assess the relationship between Agricultural Public Expenditure

(APE) and agricultural production and productivity from three complementary

perspectives: (i) a comparative analysis of APE and agricultural GDP growth

rates using international data, (ii) an analysis of the correlation between APE and

production and productivity growth at the state level, and (iii) an analysis of the

evolution of agricultural support resources with growth rates for production,

cultivated land, and yields of different crops. The assessment is limited to

agriculture programs, i.e. to APE, and excludes non-agricultural rural

development programs, since there is no uniform international/state level dataset

that can be used to compare the budgets and performance of rural development

programs.

46. Two sets of data are used for the international comparisons, from the Food and

Agriculture Organization (FAO) and the Organization for Economic Co-operation

and Development (OECD). The FAO data is the GPAGRURAL database

produced by the FAO Regional Office for LAC.36

Although excellent for the

period covered (1987-2001), unfortunately it has not been updated since 2001.

The OECD data on APE is available as an annual exercise for its member

countries. The OECD monitoring effort is both more recent and allows more

detail in the breakdown of agriculture-related expenditures and supports. It also

allows for a comparison with developed countries.

COMPARISON WITH LATIN AMERICAN COUNTRIES

47. Mexico stands out in LAC as the one country spending more that the rest in

agriculture measured by a variety of indicators. Relative to total government

spending, Mexico spent 6 percent on agriculture in the 5-year average of 1997-

2001 (LAC average was 3.4 percent; Table3-1). This was the highest amount in

LAC. Relative to the size of the sector, Mexico also had the highest percentage,

23 percent against a LAC average of 11 percent (Figure 3-1). APE share in public

expenditure relative to the sector‘s share of GDP, captured in the Agricultural

Orientation Index (AOI), was again the highest: 1.6 compared to a LAC average

of 0.5, with Mexico clearly showing a bias in favor of agricultural spending

(Table 3-2).

36

FAO (2005b)

Page 53: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

33

Table 3-1: APE in LAC (1987-2001): 5 year average, % of total public spending

YEARS 1987-1991 1992-1996 1997-2001

Argentina 2 1.4 1

Bolivia 3.1 0.6 2.4

Brazil 5 3.5 3.6

Chile 2.2 2.4 2.6

Colombia n.a. 1 0.4

Costa Rica 22.4 10.1 4.3

Cuba n.a. n.a. n.a.

Ecuador 4.3 4.1 5.1

El Salvador 1.6 0.4 2.1

Guatemala 4.4 2.7 2.9

Honduras 2.3 1.6 2.8

Jamaica 2.9 1.2 0.7

Mexico 9 9.1 6

Nicaragua 5.5 12 9.3

Panama 4.3 2.9 4

Paraguay 5.1 4.3 4.3

Peru 2.1 3.2 2.6

Dominican Rep. 18.9 11 8.3

Uruguay 2 1.7 1.9

Venezuela 3.2 1.4 0.8

LAC 5.6 3.9 3.4

Source: FAO (2005b)37

as cited in Valdes (2008a).

Note: n.a. = non available

37

In the FAO study the source of public expenditures figures is the IMF Government Financial Statistics.

Page 54: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

34

Figure 3-1: APE relative to Agricultural GDP (%, 1992-2001)

14.7

10.6

0.0

5.0

10.0

15.0

20.0

25.0

30.0

35.0

Méx

ico

Panam

á

Brasi

l

Rep

. Dom

.

Nic

arag

uaLA

C

Uru

guay

Ecuad

or

Chi

le

Cos

ta R

ica

Bolivi

a

Perú

Jam

aica

Hon

duras

Venez

uela

Paragu

ay

Argent

ina

El Sal

vado

r

Gua

tem

ala

Col

ombia

%AGDP

1992-1996

1997-2001

Source: FAO (2005b) as cited in Valdes (2008a)

Table 3-2: Agriculture Orientation Index (AOI): Agriculture expenditure share relative to

agriculture’s share of GDP

YEARS 1985-1990 1995-2001

Mexico 7.1 1.6

Venezuela 1.7 1.2

Dominican Rep. 1.1 0.7

Brazil 1.5 0.7

LAC 111.2.2.2 0.55.5

Nicaragua n.a. 0.5

Panama 1.6 0.5

Costa Rica 3.5 0.5

Ecuador 1.4 0.5

Chile 0.2 0.3

Peru 0.2 0.3

Uruguay 0.5 0.3

Argentina 0.7 0.2

Paraguay 0.2 0.2

Honduras 0.2 0.2

El Salvador 0.2 0.2

Bolivia 0.2 0.1

Guatemala 0.1 0.1

Page 55: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

35

Jamaica 0.4 0.1

Colombia n.a. n.a.

Cuba n.a. n.a. Source: Valdes (2008a). Based FAO (2005b). GDP and Agriculture GDP from the World Development

Indicators, and from Government Finance Statistic Database (IMF).

48. Comparatively, the impact of Mexico APE on agricultural growth seems

small. Figure 3-2 shows annual growth rates of agriculture jointly with the ratio

of public agricultural spending relative to agricultural GDP. In 1997- 2001,

Mexico spent on agriculture an amount equivalent to 23 percent of agricultural

GDP while attaining a sectoral growth rate of less than 2 percent. In this figure,

well performing countries are located to the left and above the fitted line. Mexico

is the country furthest away below the line.

Figure 3-2: Agricultural growth rate in LAC in relation to APE (as a percentage of agricultural

GDP), Average (1997-2001)

Panama

Colombia

Venezuela

Argentina

El Salvador

Honduras

Bolivia

Guatemala

Chile

Peru

Paraguay

LACMexico

Brazil

Costa Rica Ecuador

Dominican Rep.

Nicaragua

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

5.0

6.0

7.0

0.0 5.0 10.0 15.0 20.0 25.0

% of AGDP

AGDP Growth Rates

(%)

Source: Valdes (2008a) using FAO (2005b). Agricultural GDP growth rates are based on World

Development Indicators Database.

49. Similarly, the impact of APE on Total Factor Productivity (TFP) is also low. Figure 3-3 compares growth rates in agricultural GDP and TFP over 1981-2001

with average APE/AGDP expenditure rates for 1985-2001, ordering countries by

the latter. The figure suggests, if anything, a negative correlation between the

countries‘ APE and the growth of AGDP and TFP. With the exception of Costa

Rica, the six highest spenders (above 15% of agricultural GDP), show the lowest

agricultural GDP growth rates over the period. On the other hand, the high growth

Page 56: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

36

economies in both GDP and TFP are concentrated in the lower and middle end of

the APE distribution.

Figure 3-3: Average yearly agricultural GDP and TFP growth rates and distribution of APE/AGDP

(%, 1981/5-2001)

-1.0%

0.0%

1.0%

2.0%

3.0%

4.0%

5.0%

Mexic

o

Nica

ragu

a

Uru

guay

Dom

inica

n Republic

Cost

a Rica

Pan

ama

Bra

zil

Chile

Venezu

ela

Jam

aica

Guat

emal

a

Hondura

s

Peru

Ecu

ador

Boliv

ia

Arg

entina

Par

aguay

Colo

mbia

GD

P, T

FP g

row

th

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

AP

E/G

DP

(%

)

GDP 1981-2001 TFP 1981-2001 APE/GDP 1985-2001

Source: APE and Agricultural GDP from FAO (2005b); Agricultural TFP growth rates from

Avila and Evenson (2004).

COMPARISON WITH OECD COUNTRIES

50. Total government support to the agricultural sector has followed cyclical

trends. The total transfers to the sector, measured by OECD‘s Total Support

Estimate (TSE) is defined as the sum of transfers to producers from taxpayers and

consumers, net of budget revenues (the import receipts associated with MPS

programs). The TSE of Mexico has followed a broadly cyclical pattern: it

declined in the second half of the 80s (following the 1983 crisis and 1986 trade

liberalization through GATT), increased significantly between 1989 and 1994

(reaching its highest historical level in real terms in 1993), collapsed in 1995

following the ―tequila crisis‖, expanded between 1996 and 2002, fell in 2002-

2004, and started to grow again after 2004. Also, the use of the most distortionary

producer support instruments declined in the 1990s but resurfaced again since

2000.

51. Mexican support to the sector is slightly lower than the OECD average and

similar to USA levels. Figure 3-4 shows average TSE for the period of 2003-05

for OCED members and selected MICs, as percentage of national GDP. Mexico‘s

TSE is 0.90 percent of national GDP, compared to an OECD average of 1.2

Page 57: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

37

percent and a USA average of 0.86. However, the level is significantly higher

compared to countries such as Brazil, Chile, and New Zealand. The allocation of

Producer Support Estimate (PSE) and GSSE in Figure 3-5 shows that compared to

OECD average, Mexico has a higher allocation for budget support to farmers

(Mexico 59 percent and OECD average 38 percent in 2006), but a lower

allocation for MPS (Mexico 30 percent and OECD average 40 percent in 2006)

and GSSE (Mexico 11 percent and OECD average 23 percent in 2006). Mexican

PSE levels are slightly lower than OECD average levels, similar to USA levels

and much higher than Brazil, Chile, and New Zealand (see Figure 3-6).

Figure 3-4: Total Support Estimate (TSE) for Select Countries (as % of national GDP; 2003-05 average)

0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5

Australia

New Zealand

Chile

Brazil

Canada

United States

Mexico

OECD

European Union

Japan

Russian Federation

China

Turkey

Source: OECD, PSE/CSE Database, 2007 and OECD Factbook 2008: Economic, Environmental and Social Statistics

Note: EU15 for 2003 and EU25 for 2004-2005. Chile Estimates based on Agricultural Policy Note, OECD. 2008

Figure 3-5: Mexico and OECD’s PSE and GSSE (%, 1990/97-2006)

Page 58: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

38

Mexico (1997-2006)

GSSE

MPS

Budget

Support to

Farmers

0.00%

20.00%

40.00%

60.00%

80.00%

100.00%

1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

PSE

GSSE

OECD (1990-2007)

GSSE

MPS

Budget

Support to

Farmers

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

p

GSSE

PSE

Source: OECD, PSE/CSE Database 2007

Figure 3-6: Producer Support Estimate (PSE) (% of agricultural GDP; 2003-05 average)

Page 59: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

39

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

New

Zea

land

Austra

lia

Brazil

Chi

le

Mex

ico

Uni

ted

State

s

Rus

sian

Fed

erat

ion

Can

ada

Turke

y

OEC

DEU

1

Japa

n

Source: OECD, PSE/CSE Database, 2007 and OECD Factbook 2008: Economic, Environmental and Social

Statistics. Chile Estimates are based on Agricultural Policy Note, OECD. 2008

Note: 1/EU15 for 2003 and EU25 for 2004-2005

52. Expenditure in public goods, earlier identified as being underfunded in

Mexico, is higher for marketing and promotion activities and lower for

infrastructure and research and development compared to some OECD and

MIC countries.38

For all the countries included in Table 3-3, infrastructure and

research and development are two categories of common significance. In the case

of Mexico, however, spending on marketing and promotion is the highest

category (although far less than in the United States), and spending on

infrastructure and research and development is relatively low, particularly

compared to New Zealand and also to Brazil and Chile. Knutson (2007) also

points out that Mexico would need to spend an additional MxP 1.1 billion a year

in Sanitary and phyto-sanitary inspection systems if it were to match the US

system.39

38

Brazil and Chile is included as part of OECD‘s regular monitoring and evaluation effort of agricultural

policies for a few non-member countries. 39

As a benchmark, Knutson (2007) indicates that in the US, US$0.01 is spent on sanitary and phyto-

sanitary system per dollar of crops and livestock sales. Applying this benchmark figure to the Mexican sale

of crops and livestocks in 2006 (MxP 303 billion or US$25.3 billion), the cost to the Mexican government

of a US equivalent SPS system would be MxP 2.8 billion. This compares with the 2006 Mexican sanitary

and phyto-sanitary budget of approximately MxP 1.7 billion.

Page 60: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

40

Table 3-3: Composition of General Service Support Estimate in Selected Countries (%, Average 2004-2005)

Source: Valdes (2008a) estimates based on OECD PSE/CSE database, 2005/2007.

Note: Brazil is only for 2004. Chilean agricultural schools are almost without exception privately run by

not-for-profit organizations, the budgets of which are not counted here.

APE AND AGRICULTURAL PERFORMANCE AT THE STATE LEVEL

53. The allocation of APE by states is correlated to the size of their agricultural

sectors. Figure 3-7 shows that the distribution of APE and agricultural GDP are closely

correlated, in fact, the correlation coefficient is 0.70, although some states (Tamaulipas,

Zacatecas, Tlaxcala, Sinaloa, etc.) receive disproportionately higher shares in relation to

their contribution to agricultural GDP, while others (Morelos, Baja California Sur,

Aguascalientes etc.) receive disproportionately lower shares. Figure 3-8 shows a map

highlighting the APE received by states relative to their agricultural GDP. It shows that

the states receiving higher proportions of APE are those in the northern and southern

parts of the country, whereas the majority of the central states receive less.

ITEMS Mexico Brazil Chile United

States

European

Union

New

Zealand Switzerland

Research and

Development 16.2 30.7 23.0 5.9 16.4 40.3 18.1

Agricultural

Schools 21.5 13.7 1.1 0.0 7.8 8.6 3.7

Inspection Services 16.5 3.7 9.3 2.6 6.0 32.3 2.4

Infrastructure 13.8 44.5 55.2 14.0 42.4 18.4 18.1

Marketing and

Promotion 31.2 0.4 11.0 70.5 19.5 0.0 11.2

Public Stockholding 0.0 6.9 0.0 0.4 7.3 0.0 8.6

Miscellaneous 0.7 0.0 0.8 6.6 0.6 0.2 37.9

Total % 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0

Page 61: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

41

Figure 3-7: State Shares in National Agricultural GDP and APE (2005-2006) (%; States ordered

from left to right by descending level of state APE received in 2006)

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

14%

Sinal

oa

Tamau

lipas

Chihuahua

Jalis

co

Sonora

Veracr

uz

Zaca

teca

s

Chiapas

Guanaj

uato

Mich

oacán

Durango

Oaxac

a

Puebla

Méxic

o

San Lu

is Poto

Guerrero

Baja C

alifo

rnia

Hidal

go

Coahuila

Tabas

co

Nuevo Le

ón

Nayar

it

Campech

e

Yucatá

n

Tlaxc

ala

Queréta

ro

More

los

Colima

Aguas

calie

ntes

Baja C

alifo

rnia

Sur

Quinta

na Roo

Distrit

o Federa

l

APE AGDP

Source: Scott (2008)

Figure 3-8: Map of Mexico Indicating the Share APE/Agricultural GDP (2006)

Note: Dark blue states = APE is more than 16 % of agricultural GDP (12 states)

Medium blue states = APE is between 15 % and 11.1 % of agricultural GDP (11 states)

Light blue states = APE is less than 11 % of agricultural GDP (9 states)

Page 62: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

42

54. States receiving larger amounts of APE generally contribute proportionally

more to national agricultural growth. This is shown in Figure 3-9 where the

contribution of states to the growth of national agricultural GDP in the period

1994-2006 is plotted.40

States on the left hand side of the figure, which receive

more APE than those on the right hand side, tend to have higher contributions to

national agriculture GDP growth rate. Regression results show that a 10 percent

increase of APE spent in a state is associated with a 0.2 percent higher state

contribution to national agricultural growth.41

Figure 3-9: Average Contribution of the States to the Growth Rates of National Agriculture (Million

MxP 1993 prices) [States ordered from left to right by descending level of state APE received in 2006]

-50.00

0.00

50.00

100.00

150.00

200.00

Sin

alo

a

Tam

aulip

as

Jalis

co

Chih

uahua

Zacate

cas

Sonora

Guanaju

ato

Chia

pas

Vera

cru

z

Mic

hoacán

Dura

ngo

Puebla

Oaxaca

Méxic

o

San L

uis

Poto

Hid

alg

o

Guerr

ero

Baja

Calif

orn

ia

Coahuila

Nuevo L

eón

Nayarit

Tabasco

Cam

peche

Tla

xcala

Yucatá

n

Queré

taro

More

los

Aguascalie

nte

s

Colim

a

Quin

tana R

oo

Baja

Calif

orn

ia S

ur

Dis

trito F

edera

l

mil

lio

n M

XP

(1993 p

rices)

Source: Authors‘ calculations based on National Account figures

55. Examining APE efficiency using state level data: Efficiency of APE can be

examined by looking upon APE as an investment which improves productive

technology. Thus, a higher level of normalized APE (APE/ Agricultural GDP) in

year t would be associated with a higher growth rate of Agricultural GDP in years

t+1, t+2, etc. Looking at it this way, in order to maximize agricultural growth,

APE should be distributed among the states so as to equalize the marginal effect

of APE on growth rates. If we find that rates of growth are low in states where

normalized APE (APE/AgGDP) is high, this suggests that there are potential

gains from reallocating APE from these states to states where the converse is true.

40

This contribution is calculated by multiplying the average annual agricultural GDP of the state in 1994-

2006 by the state‘s average annual agricultural growth rate in that period. 41

The correlation is less than perfect with a correlation coefficient of 0.55. The correlation is significant at

the 1% level (p value = 0.001).

Page 63: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

43

56. The allocation of public expenditure to the states is not related to the growth

of their agriculture. The relation between the level of normalized APE received

and the rate of growth of agriculture is shown in Figure 3-10, which exhibits no

correlation between the two variables.42

Under the assumption that the share of

allocations to the states has remained reasonably stable over the period, the

conclusion that follows is that the federal government has tended to allocate more

public expenditure to states with large agricultural sectors but not to those

growing faster. The association between APE and the contribution to national

agricultural growth is explained, therefore, by the effect of size in the allocation

of APE as shown previously in Figure 3-9, not by the fine-tuning of allocations

according to the growth potential of the states, as observed by historical growth

rates.

Figure 3-10: Average Annual Growth Rate of State Agricultural GDP (%, 1994-2006) [States

ordered from left to right by descending level of normalized state APE received in 2006]

-0.50

0.00

0.50

1.00

1.50

2.00

2.50

3.00

3.50

4.00

4.50

Sin

alo

a

Tam

aulip

as

Jalis

co

Chih

uahua

Zacate

cas

Sonora

Guanaju

ato

Chia

pas

Vera

cru

z

Mic

hoacán

Dura

ngo

Puebla

Oaxaca

Méxic

o

San L

uis

Poto

Hid

alg

o

Guerr

ero

Baja

Calif

orn

ia

Coahuila

Nuevo L

eón

Nayarit

Tabasco

Cam

peche

Tla

xcala

Yucatá

n

Queré

taro

More

los

Aguascalie

nte

s

Colim

a

Quin

tana R

oo

Baja

Calif

orn

ia S

ur

Dis

trito F

edera

l

Sta

te a

gri

cu

ltu

ral

gro

wth

rate

(avera

ge o

f 1994-2

006,

%)

Source: Authors‘ calculations based on National Account figures

57. There is scope for raising the efficiency by re-orienting APE to states which

exhibit higher impact of spending. Given that the growth rate in agriculture

tends to be higher in states with smaller agricultural sectors, the marginal benefit

of APE is higher in those states compared to states with large agricultural sectors,

whose growth rates are lower. As a result, small agricultural states have a much

higher investment efficiency (or ―bang for buck‖)43

of APE than large agricultural

states, which receive a disproportionately higher share of APE. For example,

42

Correlation coefficient is -0.22, which shows little correlation between the two variables (normalized

state APE and state agricultural growth rate). Thus, correlation is statistically insignificant (p value = 0.21). 43

This is calculated by multiplying the average agricultural GDP of the state in 1994-2006 by the state‘s

agricultural growth rate in that period, divided by APE in 2006 of that state.

Page 64: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

44

Morelos, which received one of the least APE as a share of its agricultural GDP,

shows MxP 21 of agricultural GDP for every peso of APE that was allocated to

the state, whereas Tamaulipas which received the second most APE as a share of

its agricultural GDP shows only MxP 0.4 of agricultural GDP for every peso of

APE allocated to the state (see Figure 3-11). This would suggest the existence of

potential efficiency gain in re-allocating APE in favor of those states which

exhibit a higher growth per peso of spending.

Figure 3-11: Investment efficiency of APE (“Bang for Buck”) [states ordered from left to right by

descending level of APE/agricultural GDP]

-5.00

0.00

5.00

10.00

15.00

20.00

25.00

Sin

alo

a

Tam

aulip

as

Jalis

co

Chih

uahua

Zacate

cas

Sonora

Guanaju

ato

Chia

pas

Vera

cru

z

Mic

hoacán

Dura

ngo

Puebla

Oaxaca

Méxic

o

San L

uis

Poto

Hid

alg

o

Guerr

ero

Baja

Calif

orn

ia

Coahuila

Nuevo L

eón

Nayarit

Tabasco

Cam

peche

Tla

xcala

Yucatá

n

Queré

taro

More

los

Aguascalie

nte

s

Colim

a

Quin

tana R

oo

Baja

Calif

orn

ia S

ur

Dis

trito F

edera

lMxP

of

AP

E p

er

Ag

. G

DP

sp

en

t

Source: Authors‘ calculations based on National Account figures

58. Labor and land productivity also appear to be uncorrelated with APE (see

Figure 3-12). The four states with the highest APE/AGDP rates (Tamaulipas,

Tlaxcala, Zacatecas and Campeche) present the lowest land productivities among

all states except Yucatan. On the other hand, productivity growth is roughly U-

shaped: it is positive for some of the states with largest shares of APE, negative

for most states in the middle and again positive for the states with the smallest

APE shares.

Page 65: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

45

Figure 3-12: Average Value of Production per Worker and Hectare (thousand MxP 2004, 2000-2004,

and Percentage Change in Labor and Land Productivity (%, 2000-2004):

[states ordered from left to right by descending level of APE/agricultural GDP]

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

Tamau

lipas

Tlaxc

ala

Zaca

teca

s

Campech

e

Sinal

oa

Quinta

na Roo

Chiapas

Sonora

Chihuahua

Baja C

alifo

rnia

Tabas

co

Guanaj

uato

Hidal

go

Colima

Oaxac

a

Nayar

it

Guerrero

Méxic

o

Puebla

San Lu

is Poto

Yucatá

n

Durango

Queréta

ro

Veracr

uz

Jalis

co

Coahuila

Nuevo Le

ón

Mich

oacán

Aguas

calie

ntes

Baja C

alifo

rnia

Sur

Distrit

o Federa

l

More

los

Val

ue

of

pro

du

ctio

n/w

ork

er

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

Val

ue

of

pro

du

ctio

n/h

ect

are

Value of production/hectare Value of production/worker

Percentage change in labor and land productivity: 2000-2004

-80%

-60%

-40%

-20%

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

Tamau

lipas

Tlaxc

ala

Zaca

teca

s

Campech

e

Sinal

oa

Quinta

na Roo

Chiapas

Sonora

Chihuahua

Baja C

alifo

rnia

Tabas

co

Guanaj

uato

Hidal

go

Colima

Oaxac

a

Nayar

it

Guerrero

Méxic

o

Puebla

San Lu

is Poto

Yucatá

n

Durango

Queréta

ro

Veracr

uz

Jalis

co

Coahuila

Nuevo Le

ón

Mich

oacán

Aguas

calie

ntes

Baja C

alifo

rnia

Sur

Distrit

o Federa

l

More

los

VP

/wo

rke

r(h

ctr)

Change in VP/hctr Change in VP/worker

Source: Scott (2008)

Page 66: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

46

59. There is a negative correlation between spending in private agricultural

goods and state level agricultural GDP growth. Regression results in Table 3-4

show that, controlling for the levels of mechanization, fertilization and

expenditures in public goods, a 10 percent increase in APE on private goods as a

percentage of the value of agricultural production is associated with a 2.6 percent

reduction in Agricultural GDP growth.44

This result may seem counterintuitive,

but can be explained by several factors. First, and most importantly, APE and

infrastructural investments have been concentrated historically in the largest and

most developed agricultural states, where additional growth potential may thus be

lower. Secondly, the size and concentration of federal APE may have a crowding

out effect on private and state government investments in the largest beneficiary

states. Finally, the results are consistent with a low productive impact of APE

programs at the farm level. On the other hand, spending on public agricultural

goods shows a positive but not statistically significant impact on agricultural GDP

growth.45

Table 3-4: Effect of APE on Log Average Annual Agricultural GDP growth: 2000-2006

APE Private Goods (% value agr

prod) -0.261

[0.014]*

APE Public Goods 1.113

[0.316]

Mechanization (% of cultivated

land) 0.052

[0.006]**

Fertilization (% of cultivated land) -0.042

[0.031]*

R-squared 0.712

Robust p values in brackets

* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

APE AND THE PERFORMANCE OF DIFFERENT CROPS OVER TIME

60. MPS and output-based ASERCA payments have targeted mostly traditional

crops, and not fruits and vegetables. Figure 3-13 to Figure 3-15 compare the

evolution of agricultural support resources with growth rates for production,

cultivated land, and land productivity of grains, vegetables and fruits over the

period 1980-2004. Both MPS and output-linked ASERCA payments have

targeted mostly traditional crops, particularly maize and other grains, as well as

raw sugar and some animal products like milk and poultry meat (Figure 3-13).

44

This result is in accordance with results by Lopez and Galianato (2007) showing that, ceteris paribus,

reducing the share of subsidies to private goods (or, equivalently, increasing the share of public goods) in

the government‘s budget has a large and significant positive impact on rural per capita income. 45

Lopez and Galinato (2007) also show using a 1985-2001 dataset on rural expenditure for LAC that

reducing the share of subsidies to private goods (or, equivalently, increasing the share of public goods) in

the government‘s budget has, ceteris paribus, a large and significant positive impact on rural per capita

income.

Page 67: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

47

Fruits and vegetables, on the other hand, have not received significant support,

but have benefited from the liberalization of agricultural markets.

Figure 3-13: Support Based on Specific Commodity Production: MPS and ASERCA (grains) (MxP

Million, 1980 - 2004)

-20,000

-10,000

0

10,000

20,000

30,000

40,000

1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

Grains MPS Grains ASERCA

-60,000

-50,000

-40,000

-30,000

-20,000

-10,000

0

10,000

20,000

30,000

40,000

50,000

19

86

19

87

19

88

19

89

19

90

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

Diary Meat Sugar Other

Source: OECD (2007) as cited in Scott (2008).

Page 68: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

48

61. Corresponding to the surge in the support for grains, the production of

grains expanded after 2000 while the growth of vegetables and fruits

declined. As one would expect, after the liberalization reforms a significant

increase is observed in the production of fruits and vegetables, but not of grains.

This growth was associated with an expansion in cultivated land in the case of

vegetables, and an increase in the productivity of land in the case of fruits. By

contrast, after 2000, the growth of vegetable production slows down, and in the

case of fruits declines, while grains grow at an average 7.5 percent annually,

entirely through growing land productivity (Figure 3-14 and Figure 3-15). Note

that the 1988-1994 and 2000-2004 periods present similar trends in the relative

behavior of grain vs. fruits and vegetable production and cultivated land, in favor

of the former. This coincides with the surge of MPS and output-based support for

grains, as well as the expansion of variable input-based support, which is also

mostly linked to the latter.

62. The data reviewed thus suggests a conflict between the market liberalization

process initiated in the early 1990s and culminating in 2008, and agricultural

support policies. Far from being resolved, this conflict has been revived in the

present decade, with the gradual shift back towards more distortionary support

policies. Subsidies have been biased towards traditional crops (grains) rather than

supporting comparative advantage crops like fruits and vegetables. Especially in

light of favorable conditions brought about by the current high commodity prices

for precisely these traditional crops, subsidizing these crops does not make sense

from an efficiency point of view. The findings of an analysis of Mexico‘s

agricultural policies including trade policies in World Bank (2008c) quantify this

anti-export bias. The study shows that producers of several import competing

crops such as certain grains and dairy benefit from huge income transfers (with a

positive nominal rate of assistance of 19.5 percent for the period 2000-04), while

producers of exportables such as fruits and vegetables are taxed (with a negative

nominal rate of assistance of 12.5 percent).46

46

The Nominal Rate of Assistance (NRA) is defined as the percentage by which government policies raise

gross returns to producers above what they would be without government‘s intervention (or lower them if

the NRA is less than zero). This concept is similar to the OECD‘s Total Support Estimate (TSE) but there

are several methodological differences between the two (World Bank, (2008c)). The overall NRA for

importables is positive over the period 2000-04 indicating government support to these crops, but with a

large degree of variation in the level of assistance to specific products. Some major importables showed

almost zero or even negative NRAs (barley, maize, sorghum, soybeans, beans and eggs), while products

such as wheat, rice, milk, sugarcane and chicken meat showed high NRAs (40-80 percent). On the other

hand, NRAs for exportables are negative over the same period except for beef, indicating that exportables

have generally been taxed. The tax was especially high on coffee and tomatoes, exceeding 40 percent in

some years.

Page 69: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

49

Figure 3-14: Index of Production, Cultivated Land, and Land Productivity in Grains, Vegetables and

Fruits (Base year is 1980= 1, 1980-2004)

Production

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.51

98

1

19

81

19

82

19

83

19

84

19

85

19

86

19

87

19

88

19

89

19

90

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

Grains Vegetables Fruits

Cultivated Land

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

19

80

19

81

19

82

19

83

19

84

19

85

19

86

19

87

19

88

19

89

19

90

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

Grains Vegetables Fruits

Page 70: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

50

Productivity (Ton/ha)

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

19

80

19

81

19

82

19

83

19

84

19

85

19

86

19

87

19

88

19

89

19

90

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

Grains Vegetables Fruits

Source: SIAP, SAGARPA as cited in Scott (2008)

Figure 3-15: Average Annual Growth Rates in Production, Cultivated Land, and Land Productivity

in Grains, Vegetables and Fruits (%, 1980-2004)

4.08%

2.26%

7.55%

0.16%

7.50%

2.19%

-0.50%

10.56%

-1.22%-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

1988-1994 1994-2000 2000-2004

Production

Grains Vegetables Fruits

Page 71: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

51

0.84%

-0.15%

-0.95%

-2.35%

6.12%

-2.36%

-4.55%

3.11%

-2.44%

-6%

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

1988-1994 1994-2000 2000-2004

Cultivated land

Grains Vegetables Fruits

3.24%

2.41%

8.50%

2.51%

1.38%

4.55%

4.05%

7.45%

1.22%

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

8%

9%

1988-1994 1994-2000 2000-2004

Land Productivity

Grains Vegetables Fruits Source: SIAP, SAGARPA as cited in Scott (2008).

Page 72: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

52

4. EQUITY ASSESSMENT

63. The equity of ARD expenditures is evaluated at the level of geographic units as

well as that of individual producers and households. The geographic analysis is at

the state level and also at the municipal level for programs for which there is

information. The distribution of APE is analyzed ordering states by their extreme

rural poverty rates (pobreza alimentaria), using the official CONEVAL measures

for 2005.47

STATE AND MUNICIPAL LEVEL EQUITY ASSESSMENT

64. The distribution by states of APE is highly correlated with Agricultural GDP

but not with extreme poverty. Figure 4-1 shows the cumulative distribution of

ARD expenditures and the cumulative state shares of extreme poverty,

Agricultural GDP and Oportunidades payments. There is a high degree of

correlation between the distribution of APE and Agricultural GDP, but not

between APE and extreme poverty. This is in contrast to the distribution of

Oportunidades, which shows a high correlation with the distribution of extreme

rural poverty. For example, the poorest six states are home to about 55 percent of

the extreme poor, and receive about 48 percent of total benefits from

Oportunidades but only 7 percent of total APE.

47

This measure is highly correlated with the multivariate Consejo Nacional de Poblacion (CONAPO)

marginality index, and is used here in preference over the latter because it represents the current official

poverty measure at the state level. Given the correlation, the results are not sensitive to the choice of

measure.

Page 73: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

53

Figure 4-1: Extreme Poverty, Agricultural GDP and ARD Expenditures (%, 2005-6)

[States ordered from left to right by rural poverty rate]

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

Chiapas

Oaxaca

Puebla

Tabas

co

Campech

e

Guanaj

uato

Quinta

na Roo

Méxic

o

Zaca

teca

s

Sinalo

a

Chihuah

ua

Sonora

Coahuila

Nuevo Le

ón

Colima

Distrit

o Federa

l

Po

vert

y ra

te

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Cu

mm

ula

tive

sh

are

s

Rural poverty rate Cummulative poverty sharesCummulative Agric. GDP shares Cummulative APE sharesCummulative Oportunidades shares

Source: Scott (2008), CONEVAL for rural poverty rates, INEGI for Agricultural GDP, and Oliver and

Santillanes for APE and Oportunidades expenditure

65. The distribution of APE per rural capita for the principal programs is

concentrated in the upper half of the poverty-ordered state distribution, with

the highest benefits allocated to the large agricultural states of Tamaulipas,

Sinaloa, Chihuahua, and Sonora. These four states are among the principal per

capita beneficiaries of PROCAMPO reflecting their agricultural land assets. But

their disproportionate participation in APE is explained by the extreme

concentration of Apoyos, diesel and the electricity subsidies (tarifa 9). At the

other extreme, the poorest states receive support mostly from PROCAMPO and

Alianza, obtaining barely a tenth of the per capita support benefiting the former

states (see Figure 4-2).

Page 74: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

54

Figure 4-2: Principal APE Programs (MxP, 2006) [states ordered from left to right by extreme

poverty rate]

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

Chiapas

Guerrero

Oaxaca

San Lu

is Poto

Puebla

Veracr

uz

Tabas

co

Mich

oacán

Campech

e

Durango

Guanaj

uato

Hidal

go

Quinta

na Roo

Yucatá

n

Méxic

o

Nayar

it

Zaca

teca

s

Tamau

lipas

Sinalo

a

Queréta

ro

Chihuah

ua

Jalis

co

Sonora

Tlaxc

ala

Coahuila

Aguas

calie

ntes

Nuevo Le

ón

More

los

Colima

Baja C

alifo

rnia

Sur

Baja C

alifo

rnia

An

ual

sp

en

din

g p

er

rura

l cap

ita

(MxP

)

PROCAMPO (tradicional) PROGAN Apoyos a la comercialización Diesel Alianza para el Campo

Source: Oliver and Santillanes (2008) as cited in Scott (2008)

66. State-wise, Alianza is better distributed than PROCAMPO, which in turn is

better distributed than Apoyos. Considering individual programs, Alianza is the

most progressively distributed at the state level, with 28 percent of transfers going

to the poorest five states, followed by PROCAMPO, with 22 percent. The

distribution of Apoyos is highly regressive, with the three poorest states receiving

just 7 percent (see Figure 4-3).

Page 75: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

55

Figure 4-3: Distribution of the Three Main Agricultural Programs (%; 2002, 2006).

[States ordered from left to right by extreme poverty rate]

Procampo

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

Chiapas

Guerrero

Oaxaca

San Lu

is Poto

Puebla

Veracr

uz

Tabasco

Mich

oacán

Campech

e

Durango

Guanajuato

Hidalg

o

Quinta

na Roo

Yucatá

n

Méxic

o

Nayarit

Zaca

teca

s

Tamaulip

as

Sinalo

a

Queréta

ro

Chihuahua

Jalis

co

Sonora

Tlaxc

ala

Coahuila

Aguasc

aliente

s

Nuevo Le

ón

More

los

Colima

Baja C

aliforn

ia Su

r

Baja C

aliforn

ia

Dis

trib

uti

on

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Cu

mm

ula

tive

dis

trib

uti

on

Distr. 2002 Distr. 2006 Cummul. Distr. 2002 Cummul. Distr. 2006 Cummulative rural poverty shares 2006

Apoyos

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

45%

Chiapas

Guerrero

Oaxaca

San Lu

is Poto

Puebla

Veracr

uz

Tabasco

Mich

oacán

Campech

e

Durango

Guanajuato

Hidalg

o

Quinta

na Roo

Yucatá

n

Méxic

o

Nayarit

Zaca

teca

s

Tamaulip

as

Sinalo

a

Queréta

ro

Chihuahua

Jalis

co

Sonora

Tlaxc

ala

Coahuila

Aguasc

aliente

s

Nuevo Le

ón

More

los

Colima

Baja C

aliforn

ia Su

r

Baja C

aliforn

ia

Dis

trib

uti

on

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Cu

mm

ula

tive

dis

trib

uti

on

Distr. 2002 Distr. 2006 Cummul. Distr. 2002 Cummul. Distr. 2006 Cummulative rural poverty shares 2006

Page 76: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

56

Alianza

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

8%

Chiapas

Guerrero

Oaxaca

San Lu

is Poto

Puebla

Veracr

uz

Tabasco

Mich

oacán

Campech

e

Durango

Guanajuato

Hidalg

o

Quinta

na Roo

Yucatá

n

Méxic

o

Nayarit

Zaca

teca

s

Tamaulip

as

Sinalo

a

Queréta

ro

Chihuahua

Jalis

co

Sonora

Tlaxc

ala

Coahuila

Aguasc

aliente

s

Nuevo Le

ón

More

los

Colima

Baja C

aliforn

ia Su

r

Baja C

aliforn

ia

Dis

trib

uti

on

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Cu

mm

ula

tive

dis

trib

uti

on

Distr. 2002 Distr. 2006 Cummul. Distr. 2002 Cummul. Distr. 2006 Cummulative rural poverty shares 2006

Source: Scott (2008), calculated based on Oliver and Santillanes (2008) and World Bank (2004a)

67. State-wise expenditures on both public and private goods are regressively

distributed. Interestingly, expenditures in public goods are more regressively

distributed than those in private goods, with per capita benefits rising in the upper

half of the state distribution (Figure 4-4). Expenditures in private goods are

concentrated in the large agricultural states, Tamaulipas, Sinaloa, Chihuahua, and

Sonora, reflecting the concentration of Apoyos, diesel and the electricity subsidies

(tarifa 9).

Page 77: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

57

Figure 4-4: Per Capita Expenditure in Public and Private Goods in APE (MxP, 2006) [States ordered

from left to right by extreme poverty rate]

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

Ch

iap

as

Gu

erre

ro

Oax

aca

San

Lu

is P

oto

Pu

ebla

Ver

acru

z

Tab

asco

Mic

ho

acán

Cam

pec

he

Du

ran

go

Gu

anaj

uat

o

Hid

algo

Qu

inta

na

Ro

o

Yuca

tán

Méx

ico

Nay

arit

Zaca

teca

s

Tam

aulip

as

Sin

alo

a

Qu

erét

aro

Ch

ihu

ahu

a

Jalis

co

Son

ora

Tlax

cala

Co

ahu

ila

Agu

asca

lien

tes

Nu

evo

Leó

n

Mo

relo

s

Co

lima

Baj

a C

alif

orn

ia S

ur

Baj

a C

alif

orn

ia

Pri

vate

(M

xP,b

ars)

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

Pu

blic

(M

xP,l

ine

)

Private goods Public goods

Source: Scott (2008). Based on data by Oliver and Santillanes (2008)

68. Results at the municipal level for PROCAMPO and Ingreso Objetivo confirm

the regressive geographical distribution of APE. It is possible to analyze the

distribution at the municipal level using administrative data for two main

programs, PROCAMPO and Ingreso Objetivo, ordering municipalities by their

extreme rural poverty rates. Both programs are regressively distributed, but

Ingreso Objetivo extremely so, with high per capita payments for a small fraction

of municipalities, and no payments for most of the rest. In comparison,

PROCAMPO benefits are densely distributed throughout. Figure 4-5 shows that

the poorest 70 percent of municipalities receive 40 percent of PROCAMPO

transfers, but less than 6 percent of Ingreso Objetivo, and in the latter case these

resources are concentrated in a few municipalities so that the great majority of the

poorest half of municipalities (and all those in the poorest third) receive no

transfers from Ingreso Objetivo.

Page 78: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

58

Figure 4-5: Average per Rural Capita of PROCAMPO and Ingreso Objetivo Transfers by

Municipalities (MxP, 2005-6) [ordered from left to right by extreme rural poverty rate]

Procampo

0

2000

4000

6000

8000

10000

12000

14000

16000

Municipalities

Pe

r ru

ral c

apit

a e

xpe

nd

itu

re (

MxP

)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Cu

mm

ula

tive

dis

trib

uti

on

Procampo Pesos/cap Procampo Cumm.distr. Procampo Cummulative rural poverty distr.

Ingreso Objetivo

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

3500

4000

4500

Municipalities

Pe

r ru

ral c

apit

a e

xpe

nd

itu

re (

MxP

)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Cu

mm

ula

tive

dis

trib

uti

on

Pesos/cap Cumm.distr. Cummulative rural poverty distr.

Source: ASERCA administrative data bases; CONEVAL municipal poverty measures.

Page 79: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

59

PRODUCER AND HOUSEHOLD LEVEL EQUITY ASSESSMENT

69. The availability of household and producer data bases reporting both agricultural

support programs and a relevant measure of household/producer wellbeing or

wealth to allow distributive analysis is limited. Three kinds of data sources are

used, which are complementary but not strictly comparable: (i) general household

surveys including ARD transfers (ENIGH 2004, 2006; ENNVIH 2002), (ii)

evaluation surveys for specific programs (Alianza, Oportunidades), and (iii)

administrative data of the programs (PROCAMPO, Ingreso Objetivo).48

The

distribution of benefits is analyzed using two types of ordering corresponding to

the different data sources. In the case of administrative data, producers are

ordered by land holdings, which is the only measure of wealth/welfare reported in

these data. In the case of the national household surveys, benefits received are

analyzed by population deciles ordered by (current) income per capita.

Household and producer data allow coverage of the principal ARD programs,

including the principal agricultural support programs, and rural social programs

like Oportunidades and the Programa de Empleo Temporal, as well as a number

of other smaller rural development programs. Using the distribution of irrigated

land as a proxy for the distribution of hydrological, hydro-agricultural and tarifa 9

electricity subsidies, the agricultural support programs covered in this incidence

analysis represent 75 percent of APE.

70. There is a high degree of regressivity for the major agricultural programs. To compare the principal APE programs, Figure 4-6 presents concentration

curves derived from the administrative data for PROCAMPO, Ingreso Objetivo,

and Alianza PDR.49

For comparative purposes, the distribution of rainfed and

irrigated land is also shown. There is an extreme concentration of benefits for all

programs. The poorest producer decile (in terms of land) receives a tenth of a

percentage point of Ingreso Objetivo and similarly insignificant fractions of the

other programs. At the other end of the distribution, the richest producer decile

receives the following shares of transfers: (i) 45 percent of PROCAMPO,(ii) 55

percent of the Alianza PDR,50

, (iii) 60 percent of energy and hydrological

subsidies (proxied by irrigated land), and (iv) 80 percent of Ingreso Objetivo.

48

General household surveys have the important advantage of being nationally representative and including

high-quality data on income and other measures of household well-being, but their sample size is not

designed to capture specific transfer programs accurately, especially when these have limited coverage or

concentrate a large share of their benefits in a relatively small proportion of producers. The other two

sources are of course designed to capture the program beneficiaries and transfers accurately, but are not

nationally representative and generally contain limited or no income household data. The analysis obtained

from the three sources must therefore be interpreted carefully, and in a complementary way. 49

The curve for Alianza PDR is derived from Word Bank 2006a. 50

The PDR is aimed at low-income groups through explicit targeting criteria. However, the Alianza

evaluation data reveals a failure to comply with these criteria. The program‘s rules require that at least 70%

of its resources be allocated to Very High or High marginality localities (as defined by CONAPO‘s

marginality index), but in 2004 only 32% of the expenditures associated with PDR were spent in these

localities – less than 2% in Very High marginality localities.

Page 80: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

60

Figure 4-6: Concentration Curves of Major Agricultural Programs and Land (%)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% 100%

Procampo Ingreso Objetivo Alianza-Desarrollo Rural

Irrigated Land Rainfed Land

Source: Scott (2008) using ASERCA administrative data, FAO (2005) and World Bank (2006).

71. PROCAMPO stands in contrast to Oportunidades. In Figure 4-7 the

distribution of PROCAMPO and Oportunidades resources is compared using

ENIGH data.51

The contrast between Oportunidades and PROCAMPO is evident

from their concentration curves in the income space. Although both programs are

more progressive than the income distribution, Oportunidades is highly

progressive (pro-poor) while PROCAMPO is regressive.

51

The distribution of PROCAMPO benefits differs substantially according to whether ENIGH data or the

administrative program data of ASERCA are used, the latter resulting in a substantially more regressive

distribution than the former. This is because, as most household surveys, ENIGH does not capture well

household incomes at the top of the distribution. In view of this, we report in some sections two sets of

results for PROCAMPO, one using ENIGH data and the other using ASERCA data.

Page 81: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

61

Figure 4-7: Comparison of PROCAMPO and Oportunidades Transfers by Rural Population Deciles

(%, 2006) [ordered from left to right by pre-transfer income per capita]

Rural distribution

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

0.0% 10.0% 20.0% 30.0% 40.0% 50.0% 60.0% 70.0% 80.0% 90.0% 100.0%

Oportunidades Procampo Income

Source: Scott (2008), calculations are based on data by ENIGH 2006

72. ARD expenditures are an inefficient redistributive instrument while APE is

not only inefficient but actually contributes to increasing income inequality.

To assess the global impact of ARD expenditures on rural income inequality, the

APE programs are contrasted with nine social and rural development programs

reported in ENIGH 2006 and in a special ―Social Module‖ commissioned by

SEDESOL with ENIGH 2004. Concentration Coefficients (CC) are used to

measure equity.52

As shown in Figure 4-8, the CC of ARD expenditures is

regressive in absolute terms (CC = 0.24), but still progressive relative to the

distribution of pre-transfer income (CC = 0.35). APE is more regressive (CC =

0.58) than the distribution of pre-transfer income (CC = 0.35), thus actually

contributing to increasing income inequality. By contrast, rural development

expenditure (RDE) is progressive (pro-poor) in absolute terms (CC = -0.2.6), with

the notable exception of the two productive SEDESOL programs: Opciones

Productivas (CC = 0.12) and Crédito a la Palabra (CC = 0.45).

52

The Concentration Coefficient (CC) is a generalized form of the Gini coefficient that shows the

concentration of a particular income source x (in this case payment from ARD programs) when recipients

are ranked by an index y (in this case pre-transfer income). The CC ranges from -1 when all transfers are

received by the poorest households, through 0 when all households receive the same amount of transfer

income, to +1 when all transfers are received by the richest households.

Page 82: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

62

Figure 4-8: Concentration Coefficients of ARD Expenditures, Income and Land (2006)

0.809

0.657

0.584

0.524

0.503

0.502

0.454

0.349

0.238

0.121

0.117

-0.073

-0.137

-0.142

-0.232

-0.265

-0.309

-0.315

-0.312

-0.315

-45% -25% -5% 15% 35% 55% 75%

Ingreso Objetivo

Irrigated land

Total APE

Total land

Rainfed land

Procampo (ASERCA)

Credito a la Palabra

Pre-transfer income

Total ARD

Opciones Productivas

Procampo (ENIGH)

Vivienda Rural

Seguro Popular

Despensa DIF

Desayunos DIF

Total RD

PET

IMSS-Oportunidades

Piso Firme

Oportunidades

Source: Scott (2008) using ENIGH 2006, ENIGH 2004 (Social Module), ASERCA Beneficiary data bases.

Note:Data for 2004 is used for the following programs: Piso Firme, Programa de Empleo Temporal (PET),

Deasyunos and Despensas DIF, Vivienda Rural, Opciones Productivas, and Crédito a la Palabra.

73. There is a sharp contrast between the distribution of APE and RDE. Under

certain assumptions,53

the distribution and income incidence of total ARD

expenditures in 2006 was estimated. A very different story emerges for APE and

RDE. More than half of APE is concentrated in the richest household/producer

decile, whereas RDE is progressively distributed, with the extreme rural poor (the

poorest 20 percent of rural households) obtaining 33 percent of transfers (Figure

4-9). APE is regressive even relative to the distribution of pre-transfer income, so

its incidence actually increases income inequality.

53

The assumptions used are as follows:

(i) The RDE transfers whose distribution could not be estimated directly (40 percent) are distributed on

average as those that were estimated (60 percent). This probably overestimates the progressivity of RDE,

given the weight of Oportunidades in the estimates.

(ii) The APE programs whose distribution could not be estimated (37 percent) are assumed to be distributed

as total (rain-fed & irrigated) cultivated land, as reported in the ASERCA data bases (except for the energy

and hydro-agricultural expenditures which are assumed to be proxied by the distribution of irrigated land).

This is probably a lower bound for the repressiveness of APE.

(iii) Given the important degree of underreporting of household income in ENIGH when compared to the

National Accounts, to obtain a realistic estimate of the incidence of ARD expenditures, HH income was

adjusted by the relevant factor (1.87) to make it consistent with the National Accounts. Since it is

reasonable to assume that underreporting in Mexico is more significant at the top than at the lower end of

the income distribution, both adjusted and unadjusted estimates are estimated.

Page 83: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

63

74. Results show a flat ARD distribution for the poorest 70 percent and a sharp

increase for the richest 10 percent, mainly through APE. The top 10 percent

receive more than half of total APE, but less than 2 percent of total RDE (Figure

4-9). Total APE transfers represent 20.7 percent of the adjusted average income

of the richest decile (almost 40 percent unadjusted), but just 7.6 percent of the

poorest (14 percent unadjusted) (Figure 4-10). On the other hand, total RDE adds

53 percent (almost 100 percent unadjusted) to the poorest deciles pre-transfer

income, but barely adds to the income of the top decile. To summarize, the

distribution of public ARD expenditures is flat for the poorest 70 percent, at less

than MxP 500 per capita per month, but increases sharply at the tenth decile,

where rural households obtain on average more than MxP 3,000 monthly per

capita (Figure 4-11).

Figure 4-9: Estimated Distribution of APE and RDE (%, 2006) [rural household deciles ordered

from left to right by pre-transfer per capita income]

1.6% 1.6% 2.5% 3.4% 4.0%5.2%

6.9%9.2%

13.4%

52.3%

17.2%15.8%

13.2%12.0% 12.1%

9.4%7.1% 6.6%

4.8%

1.8%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

household decilesAPE RD expenditure

Source: Scott (2008) , using ENIGH 2006

Page 84: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

64

Figure 4-10: Estimated Incidence of APE and RDE in Rural Household Income (Transfer as % of Pre-transfer

income, 2006) [rural household deciles ordered from left to right by pre-transfer per capita income]

7.6%5.1% 6.0%

7.1% 7.4% 8.1% 9.0%10.2%

12.6%

20.7%

52.9%

30.9%

20.5%

16.3%15.2%

9.8%

6.3%4.9%

3.1%0.5%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10household deciles

APE RD expenditure

Source: Scott (2008) , using ENIGH 2006

Figure 4-11: Estimated Average Monthly Transfer per Capita to Rural Households from APE and RDE

(MxP, 2006) [rural household deciles ordered from left to right by pre-transfer per capita income]

49 55 84 126 159 210 282 417719

3,005

339 336 287 291 328 255 199201

175

78

0

500

1,000

1,500

2,000

2,500

3,000

3,500

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

household deciles

MxP

APE RD expenditure

Source: Scott (2008) , using ENIGH 2006

75. APE cancels out approximately half of the redistributive impact of RDE. The

accounting effect of APE on the rural Gini coefficient is to increase it by 6.7

Page 85: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

65

percent (11.5 with unadjusted income), while RDE decreases it by 14 percent

(24.8 percent unadjusted), with a net reduction of 6.5 percent associated with total

ARD expenditures (see Table 4-1). In other words, the regressive nature of the

APE is so great that it cancels out approximately half of the redistributive impact

of RDE on relative inequality, measured through the Gini coefficient.

Table 4-1: Redistributive Effects of APE and ARD Expenditures

HH Deciles

Distribution Transfer Incidence

Transfers Pre-

transfer

income

Post-transfer income

APE RDE + APE + RDE + APE

& RDE APE RDE Total

Income:

Unadjusted

(Million MxP)

108,572 76,925 467,957

1 1.6% 17.2% 2.9% 2.7% 4.9% 4.4% 14.2% 99.0% 113.2%

2 1.6% 15.8% 4.4% 3.9% 6.0% 5.3% 9.5% 57.9% 67.4%

3 2.5% 13.2% 5.5% 5.0% 6.6% 5.9% 11.2% 38.3% 49.5%

4 3.4% 12.0% 6.5% 6.0% 7.3% 6.7% 13.2% 30.4% 43.7%

5 4.0% 12.1% 7.1% 6.6% 7.8% 7.2% 13.8% 28.4% 42.2%

6 5.2% 9.4% 8.5% 8.0% 8.7% 8.2% 15.1% 18.4% 33.5%

7 6.9% 7.1% 10.0% 9.5% 9.6% 9.2% 16.8% 11.8% 28.6%

8 9.2% 6.6% 11.6% 11.2% 10.9% 10.6% 19.1% 9.2% 28.3%

9 13.4% 4.8% 13.7% 13.8% 12.5% 12.7% 23.6% 5.8% 29.3%

10 52.3% 1.8% 29.7% 33.5% 25.8% 29.7% 38.7% 1.0% 39.7%

Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 23.2% 16.4% 39.6%

Gini 0.5839 -0.2652 0.3486 0.3887 0.2620 0.3118

Change in Gini 11.5% -24.8% -10.6%

Income:

Adjusted

(Million MP)

875,291

1 2.9% 2.7% 4.0% 3.8% 7.6% 52.9% 60.5%

2 4.4% 4.1% 5.3% 5.0% 5.1% 30.9% 36.0%

3 5.5% 5.2% 6.1% 5.8% 6.0% 20.5% 26.5%

4 6.5% 6.2% 7.0% 6.6% 7.1% 16.3% 23.3%

5 7.1% 6.8% 7.5% 7.2% 7.4% 15.2% 22.6%

6 8.5% 8.2% 8.6% 8.3% 8.1% 9.8% 17.9%

7 10.0% 9.7% 9.8% 9.5% 9.0% 6.3% 15.3%

8 11.6% 11.4% 11.2% 11.0% 10.2% 4.9% 15.1%

9 13.7% 13.7% 13.0% 13.1% 12.6% 3.1% 15.7%

10 29.7% 31.9% 27.5% 29.7% 20.7% 0.5% 21.2%

Total 12.4% 8.8% 21.2%

Gini 0.3486 0.3721 0.2990 0.3259

Change in Gini 6.7% -14.2% -6.5%

Source: Scott (2008)

Note: RDE = Rural Development Expenditure

Page 86: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

66

5. M&E AND INSTITUTIONAL ASPECTS OF ARD

PROGRAMS

MONITORING AND EVALUATION

76. The Monitoring and Evaluation (M&E) system in Mexico has been

undergoing major changes in the legal and institutional framework since the

late 1990s. In the 1970s and 1980s, evaluations were implemented, if at all, by

internal departments within the programs themselves, with limited transparency or

accountability. In 1997, the Progresa/Oportunidades program began its highly

acclaimed M&E system using multi-annual panel data sets and rigorous

experimental or quasi-experimental methods.54

In 2000, annual evaluations

became mandatory for all targeted programs in the 2000 Federal Budget Law.

Similarly, tax/expenditure incidence analysis was made mandatory for all public

spending in 2001 by the 2001 Federal Budget and Tax laws. Evaluations are

required to be submitted to Congress to feed into the annual federal budgetary

process. In 2005, the Consejo Nacional de Evaluación (CONEVAL) was created

by the Ley General de Desarrollo Social, with the dual mandate of generating

official poverty measures and coordinating the evaluations of all social

development programs, including all targeted rural social development

programs.55

In 2006, results based budgeting and a performance evaluation

system were made mandatory for all federal spending programs by the Ley

Federal de Presupuesto y Responsabilidad Hacendaria. The Logical Framework

was the methodology adopted to generate the relevant performance indicators. In

2007, General Guidelines for the Evaluation of Federal Programs (Lineamientos

generales para la evaluación de los Programas Federales de la Adminisración

Pública General) were issued by CONEVAL, and in May 2008, the results based

budgeting and the performance evaluation system were expanded to local (state

and municipal) government programs through a constitutional reform.

54

The credibility of the program‘s positive and internationally recognized results can arguably be credited

as a major factor in explaining the political survival of the program to two changes in administration, a

change in political party, and even a political regime change (from effectively one-party rule to alternating

parties). 55

CONEVAL is a decentralized federal public agency attached to SEDESOL. Its functions include

establishing M&E methodologies and performance indicators, disseminating evaluation results, identifying

priority intervention areas, setting up criteria for poverty measurement, and giving suggestions to

Government with respect to M&E of social programs and poverty measurement. CONEVAL is chaired by

SEDESOL and consists of six experts of well-established reputation and a technical secretary. Evaluation

work is jointly coordinated by CONEVAL, SHCP and SFP, which integrated the ―Evaluation System‖.

Page 87: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

67

77. To organize the evaluation work, Annual Evaluation Programs are

established each year indicating which programs will be evaluated and what

type of evaluation will be carried out.56

Programs have already been compiled

for 2007 and 2008. The Annual Evaluation Programs reports 130 and 202

evaluations to be submitted to Congress in 2007 and 2008 respectively. However,

the majority were basic ―consistency and results‖ evaluations, which often suffer

from insufficient depth, and only 3 (6) were impact evaluations in 2007 (2008).

78. The rapid development of the institutional M&E framework since the late

1990s, and especially since 2006, is remarkable but the actual implementation

of this ambitious framework is facing practical challenges, especially in ARD

programs. Annual evaluations have been limited and heterogeneous in quality,

depth, objectivity and comparability. This is especially true for programs in rural

areas where the beneficiaries are dispersed. These limitations stem from issues on

the supply side, i.e. the thin pool of qualified expert consultants who are able to

conduct quality evaluations, as well as the demand side, i.e. the limited resources

available to CONEVAL, SHCP, Secretaria de Funcion Publica (SFP), and

Congress to regulate and process the rapidly growing number of evaluations.

Also, although the Logical Framework methodology adopted is in principle a

simple and easily replicable method to achieve consistency between instruments

and objectives across programs, the consistent and informative application of this

method may be difficult to achieve in practice. The Logical Framework method

should be used as a minimum common denominator for the M&E system, to be

complemented with more substantive evaluation methods.

79. The evaluation of agricultural programs is particularly tricky for several

reasons. First, they are usually demand-led, and hence the actual beneficiaries

are not known beforehand. Second, they pose complex measuring challenges (of

farm related inputs, outputs, prices and assets), which require carrying out farm

management type surveys. Third, results vary among farms according to agro-

ecological conditions and factors such as weather and water availability, which

makes it difficult to select control groups and compare results. Finally,

beneficiaries are dispersed and costly to reach. Because of these challenges,

specific methodologies, beyond general evaluation principles and methods, are

not readily available to assess the impact of these programs. This is an area where

methodological research and trial and error experimentation is highly needed.

80. Limited availability of experienced talent in M&E hinders the

implementation and oversight of good M&E. There is a shortage of well-

trained M&E experts in universities and consulting firms in Mexico to carry out

the evaluations, as well as on the side of the contracting institutions (ministries

and agencies) to act as counterparts in the evaluations and monitor quality.

56

Various types of program evaluations are considered in the Lineamientos: consistency and results,

indicators, processes, impact, and ad hoc aspects. In addition, there are also strategic evaluations related to

the policy, institutional or strategic aspects of programs or sets of programs, and new programs must

undergo a design evaluation in the first year.

Page 88: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

68

81. ARD programs are monitored and evaluated only at the program level and

not at the level of PEC to track progress in rural development. Beyond

offering a minimum of consistency between evaluations, the new M&E

framework tracks results at the program level, and fails to provide a broader

perspective considering the links, complementarities and synergies among

programs. There is no autonomous and technical evaluation institution for ARD

programs looking at the entire ARD portfolio comparable to the role of

CONEVAL for social development, though even the latter has yet to institute an

evaluation methodology capable of converting the growing tide of individual

evaluations into a comprehensive evaluation of social spending.

82. Currently, there is no unified information system and data base for different

ARD programs, or even different agricultural support programs to

coordinate the distribution of resources at the beneficiary level. On the

contrary, each program (even within SAGARPA) has their own database of

beneficiaries and it is often not possible to link them. This makes it difficult to

analyze aggregate impacts, identify overlaps, or track the total resources received

by individual producers from different programs to allow for the establishment of

a ceiling on total APE transfers received, or identifying horizontal and vertical

inequities in these transfers. More ambitiously, a unified system would allow for

the targeting of complementary support packages as a function of the specific

socioeconomic characteristics and productive potential of producers. At present,

only a handful of programs, notably Oportunidades, have adequate beneficiary

data bases. An ambitious project to construct a unified data base of the principal

social programs was initiated by SEDESOL in the previous administration.57

An

IDB technical assistance project has been launched recently with the ASERCA

unit of SAGARPA to build a system of this kind for the agricultural support

programs as well as to design an improved Logical Framework for

PROCAMPO.58

83. Annual evaluations are costly to implement and unnecessary in most cases.

Currently, external evaluations of targeted programs are carried out annually.

This is expensive and in most cases unnecessary because of few program changes

from one year to the next. As a consequence, quality suffers, ―evaluation fatigue‖

sets in, and there is a tendency of program managers not to take evaluation results

sufficiently into account in their decision-making. It would be preferable to have

less evaluations of better quality and more relevance. Also, rather than covering

all program aspects, evaluations could cover in depth specific aspects in separate

years. The new CONEVAL evaluation framework seems to allow making these

adjustments.

57

This has been hampered by the failure to build a functional identification number system for the Mexican

population. The Clave Única de Registro Poblacional was created for this purpose, but currently contains

multiple registers. 58

The ―Improving systems and operational procedures of PROCAMPO‖ program was approved in March

2008. It is a technical assistance project with US$100,000 financed by the IDB and US$25,000 financed as

counterpart from SAGARPA.

Page 89: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

69

84. The weakest and most critical link in the improved M&E framework is the

insufficient feedback of the evaluation results into managerial and budgetary

decision-making. Even the most sophisticated and functional M&E system

becomes irrelevant for policy making if there are no effective mechanisms to

translate its results into actual managerial and budgetary decisions, from policy

reforms to changes in the behavior of final service providers in response to

accountability and incentive mechanisms. To date, there is little evidence that the

annual evaluations of ARD programs or the overall distributive analysis of public

spending/taxes have been used in budgetary decisions by the executive or

legislative branches of government, thus creating a space for political

interferences in the determination of the public spending program. A possible way

to provide feedback is for evaluation exercises to be followed by the setting up of

an action plan for program managers to address the issues identified in the

evaluations. The plan would be agreed between evaluators, program managers

and representatives of the evaluation system. Compliance with the actions agreed

upon in the plan would need to be monitored.

INSTITUTIONAL ISSUES

85. In this section some selected institutional issues are examined. They succinctly

cover two broad topics: (i) the political economy circumstances in which ARD

policy-making is conducted, and (ii) the challenges found in the implementation

of ARD programs.59

86. A crucial political-economy issue is the pressure of rent-seekers and interest

groups to influence programs and their design. This pressure has been behind

the creation or extension of some programs in Mexico as well as in other

countries, including high income countries, and resisting it may be difficult. One

reason is that ARD policies are regarded by some sectors as an arena of resource

dispensation rather than as economic instruments to improve distribution and

growth.60

Congruent with this is a view of ARD programs as a cost of

maintaining social tranquility in the countryside, to be adjusted according to

social negotiation or voting pressure. However, the political and public

administration system has increasingly employed a much more technical or

rational view in the last decades, and hence views of the above type are rapidly

receding. The present moment seems particularly appropriate for accelerating this

transition. The formulation of a national ARD strategy and the creation of an

ARD expenditure planning system advocated in Chapter 6 could be the triggers of

a stronger position vis-à-vis this type of pressures. The strengthening of

CONEVAL‘s M&E function would also favor this.

59

More detailed analysis and factual information is contained in World Bank 2005b on the first topic and

World Bank 2006a on the second topic. 60

This trend is not unique to Mexico. It is often observed in other countries as well, developing and

developed alike, where agricultural programs are often exempt from the usual scrutiny and evaluation

accorded to publicly funded programs.

Page 90: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

70

87. A related issue is the often-strained relationship between the executive and

legislative branches of government in the formulation of ARD policies and

budgetary allocations. More interaction between the Executive and the (strong)

rural lobby in Congress, particularly, but not only, during the budget formulation

process would improve the chances for a more rational ARD policy framework.

88. Another political economy issue is the relation between the federal and state

governments in ARD policies. With a few exceptions (mainly Alianza and

FAIS-FISM (Fondo para la Infraestructura Social Municipal), ARD programs

and expenses are fully centralized. Program design, funding and operational rules

are usually handled at the federal level.61

Under these circumstances, since state

governments do not have control of the rural agenda in their states, they do not

internalize the political and economic costs and benefits of ARD actions,

successes and failures. There is an ambiguous state of affairs in which neither the

federal government nor state governments feel truly accountable for ARD

outcomes. State governments are not necessarily unhappy with this, because, if

need be, it allows them to blame the federal level for program shortcomings and

avoid hard, possibly unpopular, decisions in the allocation of scarce funds. This

pushes the situation towards low-level policy equilibrium, particularly since state

governments would have clear advantages in designing and carrying out many

ARD actions. Certain courses of action to counter this trend are proposed in

Chapter 6.

89. Implementation matters, and is particularly complex in production-oriented

programs. How are programs implemented is almost as important as how they

are designed. Implementation challenges may jeopardize, even reverse, the

achievement of objectives.62

These challenges are particularly acute in

production-oriented programs compared to infrastructure or cash transfer

programs. The reasons are that for good implementation production-oriented

programs require a medium- to long-term perspective, a particular type of synergy

between ground level program operators and the responsible agency, high quality

participation of beneficiaries, and a large recurrent budget. The bottom line is

that these programs deal essentially with private goods, and public-private

convergence is hence of the essence.63

The above conditions are difficult to meet,

and appropriate implementation is therefore a challenge. Several aspects of the

operational challenges are highlighted below.

90. Macro type political and administrative circumstances may place constraints

on implementation. One such circumstance is the 3-year, no reelection electoral

system of municipal authorities, which hinders their involvement in medium- to

long-term endeavors like ARD. Another circumstance is the annually based

61

See World Bank (2006a) for an analysis of the decentralization of rural programs in Mexico. 62

For an analysis of implementation challenges of rural development programs in Mexico see World Bank,

2005b, Rural Poverty Study, Chapter 6. For the case of the rural development program of Alianza, see

World Bank, 2006a, Rural Decentralization Study, Chapter 3. 63

An illuminating analysis of this matter, based on the case of public programs in the State of Ceará, in

Brazil, is that of Judith Tendler (1997).

Page 91: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

71

budgetary system existing in Mexico, which does not favor the continuity of

programs and views required by ARD, and does not help giving security to

beneficiaries regarding the stability of program benefits.

91. Execution of the budget is limited to a short time window and relies on

deferred payment modalities. Overall the execution rate of the PEC is quite

high. The execution rate for the latest year available, 2007, shows an execution

rate of 97 percent for the entire PEC program (Table 5-1). However, the

existence of administrative and budgetary norms make it, in practice, difficult to

disburse program funds and typically limit the disbursement period to several

months in the year, thus placing big pressure on those executing the program64

.

An examination of the quarterly execution rates of the PEC budget, at glance,

present a smoothed disbursement pattern over the quarters (Table 5-2).

Table 5-1: 2007 PEC Budget by Ministry

Budget Branch (ramo) PEC 2007 (millions of pesos)

Approved Modified Executed % Executed

TOTAL 176,794.4 170,122.6 165,354.4 97%

SEGOB 300.0 300.0 300.0 100%

SRE 71.4 82.8 82.8 100%

SHCP 8,291.9 8,100.2 7,534.5 93%

SAGARPA 58,536.9 57,677.4 56,519.4 98%

SCT 2,857.8 2,857.7 1,707.5 60%

SE 838.5 837.3 837.2 100%

SEP 23,686.8 24,592.0 23,220.0 94%

SSA 15,940.5 10,752.0 10,752.0 100%

STPS 66.9 66.6 66.6 100%

SER 4,779.8 4,701.4 4,701.4 100%

SEMARNAT 14,289.8 13,026.1 12,551.1 96%

AP-SS 5,512.9 5,512.9 5,512.9 100%

SEDESOL 16,525.1 16,524.5 16,517.3 100%

SECTUR 76.5 76.5 76.5 100%

PSE 250.0 250.0 250.0 100%

TSA 694.0 689.6 649.6 94%

AP-FED 24,075.6 24,075.6 24,075.6 100%

Source: SHCP

Table 5-2: 2007 PEC Quarterly Execution Rate (Million MxP)

Quarter Allocated Executed (cumulative, incl. CLCs) % Execution (cumulative)

1Q 42,530.70 29,196.80 17.2%

2Q 42,530.70 85,341.60 50.2%

3Q 42,530.70 126,309.20 74.2%

4Q 42,530.70 165,354.40 97.2%

Total 170,122.80 165,354.40 97.2%

Source: Centro de Estudios para el Desarrollo Rural Sustentable y la Soberanía Alimentaria

64

Many APE programs are very sensitive to the timeliness with which the resources reach farmers,

especially in areas where the rainy season is short. Operational and budgetary norms often stand in the way

of timelines, and result in the late arrival of subsidies.

Page 92: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

72

92. Recurrent funds for program operation are scarce. Vigilance from SHCP that

program money is well spent, as much as possible going to final beneficiaries, is

to be praised, but it must be understood that shortage of operational funds may

jeopardize programs. It is important for budgeting authorities to realize that

production-oriented programs are particularly costly in recurrent costs if high

quality implementation is sought. Also, the level of operating cost is expected to

differ depending on project design, e.g. PROCAMPO requires very little

operational funds once the beneficiary roster has been compiled, while others, like

Alianza‘s PDR requires much more funding for effective implementation.

93. Organizational systems and cultures often lead to poor implementation. Due

to the segmentation of government agencies, rural programs often have different

breakdowns of geographical regions, different definitions, norms and procedures

for similar things, different timing and disbursement methods, and create their

own separate counterpart organizations. This makes program coordination

extremely difficult. Another key issue is how to overcome the culture of short-

term achievement often present in ARD program activities characterized by

focusing on quick results with insufficient strategic focus. The pressure to

disburse program funds is part of this. Pursuing quick results hinders inter-

agency and agency-client cooperation and beneficiary selection, and leads to low

expenditure quality.

94. There is insufficient client orientation and empowerment of beneficiaries.

Three main issues may be highlighted here: (1) poor program dissemination,

which is essential in demand-driven programs; (2) weak direct accountability of

program operators to clients/beneficiaries and weak ―client satisfaction‖ incentive

criteria; and (3) in some cases, an opportunistic and rent-seeking behavior of

program operators and service providers.

95. There are few incentives for program operators to perform well. Program

operators dealing with field activities and the interface with clients are generally

poorly paid and their knowledge and experience little valued. This refers not only

to the staff of the implementing agencies, but also to contracted private technical

service providers. The poor economic compensation and weak incentives to boost

morale for bottom level program operators is generally inconsistent with the

importance of their function. Some of the issues are: no link of payments to

performance and client satisfaction; little valuation of the operators‘ function,

with scarce consultation with them on program matters; insufficient training and

dissemination of best practices; no systematic performance evaluations; and an

insufficient networking system and a client-orientation culture.

Page 93: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

73

6. OPTIONS FOR MOVING FORWARD

96. Mexico‘s large ARD program represents a very significant fiscal effort by the

GOM on behalf of the rural population. Average public expenditure per capita is

now similar in the urban and rural sectors, unlike that in many Latin American

countries, where there is still an ―urban bias‖ in the allocation of public

expenditure. The present ARD program represents the outcome of the far-

reaching reform efforts which began in the late 1980s to modernize the sector and

introduce a more efficient, equitable and less distortionary policy environment.

97. Mexico‘s ARD policy reforms included many novel features signaling a clear

departure from past policies. They resulted in some international best practices

such as the success of the Oportunidades program in rural poverty reduction, the

decoupled design of PROCAMPO, and the strong global leadership of the GOM

in mainstreaming climate change in ARD issues. This chapter offers options and

alternatives for the GOM to move forward on further improving its ARD public

expenditure program.

98. The basic diagnostics in previous sections identify several challenges in the

current structure of ARD expenditure:

Low cost-effectiveness—a high level of spending in rural areas, with low

impact on growth, climate change adaptation, and poverty reduction.

Imprecise ARD strategic objectives and rationale.

Distortion in some important programs—causing the prices paid or received

by private parties to differ from their values to society, discouraging producers

and consumers from making economically efficient decisions and in some

cases resulting in negative environmental externalities.

Poor coordination among the many expenditure programs.

Regressive overall spending, especially in agricultural support programs.

Limited built-in monitoring and evaluation.

Implementation constraints.

KEY FEATURES OF THE ARD PROGRAM IN MEXICO

99. Resources for ARD in Mexico are large. The amount of resources spent by

Mexico in ARD is large, bigger than in other countries in Latin American and

bigger also than in many OECD countries, in relation to the sizes of the

agricultural sector, the rural population, and the public expenditure bill (see

chapter 2). Yet the results have been less than expected (see chapter 3). So the

Page 94: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

74

challenge for Mexico is not the size of ARD expenditures but their allocation and

quality—the thrust of Mexico‘s expenditure reform.

100. Some ARD programs have contradictory goals. There seems to be little

coherence among the objectives of some support programs to farmers.

SAGARPA and CONAGUA programs improve efficiency in irrigation water use,

but tarifa 9 militates in the opposite direction. Similarly, Alianza, Apoyos a la

Competitividad de las Ramas Productivas, and PROCAMPO Capitaliza aim

mostly at production intensification, competitiveness, and employment

generation. This aim is contradicted by Ingreso Objetivo, which mostly supports

crops that generate little employment and have no comparative advantage.

Similarly, input support programs, like the electricity and diesel subsidies

promote production patterns based on comparative advantage. Mexico should

address these inconsistencies in policy messages and incentives.

101. Public goods are undersupplied. The importance of public goods to promote

agricultural development is well established (see Box 2-2). Public goods ought to

be the main thrust of a competitively oriented APE program. Yet, considering all

fiscal costs examined in this study (budgetary and nonbudgetary), public goods

are only 24 percent of the cost of supports directly related to agricultural

development—and 43 percent of those related to total ARD. Rebalancing ARD

expenditures in favor of public goods would be one of the crucial aspects of

agricultural policy reform.

102. Some ARD programs have the perverse effect of encouraging activities that

generate negative externalities. Ideally, the programs should generate positive

externalities. The most obvious challenge is the incentive to deplete aquifers

created by the tarifa 9 subsidy to groundwater pumping. Others include incentives

to overuse agrichemicals, resulting in contamination of waterflows, and to

cultivate marginal lands, resulting in erosion and increased flood risk

downstream. Programs like tarifa 9 that encourage overuse of water also result in

maladaptation to future conditions, which are likely to be drier since Mexico is

expected to experience a decline in water runoffs of 10–20 percent nationally and

up to 40 percent along the Gulf Coast wetlands.65

Some policies, particularly

subsidies to grain production, are also known to contribute to deforestation.66

103. Redirecting agricultural expenditures to encourage activities that generate

positive externalities would produce substantial environmental gains. Several

windows of the ProÁrbol Program administered by CONAFOR already seek to

do this; opportunities should be sought to recast other programs along similar

lines. Such measures could also generate additional financing—for example, from

local water users and from national and global buyers of carbon emission

reductions.

65

The decline is in the difference between precipitation and evapotranspiration (World Bank 2008b). 66

Klepeis and Vance (2003), in a study of Southeastern Mexico, suggest that PROCAMPO‘s requirement

to keep land in production is linked to deforestation and deterioration of soil fertility.

Page 95: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

75

POLICY OPTIONS FOR REFORM

104. This section discusses some options and suggestions to reform ARD expenditures

in the light of the analysis of previous chapters. ARD expenditure as a whole is

examined, and options for a new overall structure are presented. The present

moment is particularly appropriate for these changes because of the opportunities

created by the medium- to long-term scenario of high agricultural prices. The

buoyant state of markets should make the transition smooth and the changes more

palatable to those who would see their subsidies diminished.

105. To make well informed decisions, the GOM will need to weigh the tradeoffs of

policy options based on considerations such as cost, sequential importance,

technical difficulty, risks, and impact. While some options promise greater

benefits in the longer run, others could be targeted for quick action. The chapter

summarizes policy options in five areas:

6) Improving the ARD planning system.

7) Rationalizing the overall farmer support system.

8) Improving the support system for small producers through gradual

decentralization.

9) Improving the M&E and institutional aspects of ARD programs.

10) Increasing the positive environmental externalities of ARD programs and

supporting the national climate change strategy.

1) Improving the ARD Planning System

106. A more effective planning system for ARD spending could be put in place.

The guidelines for allocating budgetary resources and the authority and planning

capacity of the Comisión Interministerial para el Desrrollo Rural Sustentable

(CIDRS) would have to be strengthened for PEC to be effective . A recent OECD

review of rural development issues in Mexico (OECD 2007c) highlights the

challenge faced by Mexico where SAGARPA, a sectoral ministry without

sufficient authority over peer sectoral ministries is mandated to plan the ARD

expenditures as chair of CIDRS. Box 6-1 summarizes the OECD analysis on

coordination of rural policies of its member countries (OECD 2006a). The OECD

proposal to move CIDRS from SAGARPA to the President‘s office would better

reflect the multisectoral character of rural development, and strengthen the

Commission‘s planning capacity. Another option is to place CIDRS under SHCP

because SHCP is primus inter pares as a ministry, has a multisectoral mandate

and view, and is responsible for looking into the effectiveness and quality of

public expenditure and preparing the federal budget. In addition to strengthening

CIDRS, a strong nucleus of agricultural policy analysts, staffed with experts of

Page 96: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

76

recognized academic excellence could be formed to operate autonomously under

the SAGARPA.

Box 6-1: OECD Analysis on Inter-Institutional Horizontal Co-ordination

OECD sees interinstitutional coordination as an aspect of meta-governance—or ―the governance of

government and governance.‖ In this framework horizontal coordination attempts to overcome sectoral

approaches in favor of an integrated policy approach to rural development. Coordination is needed to

―encourage the various institutional and managerial systems which formulate and implement rural policy to

work together.‖ To ensure consistency—that is, ―that individual policies are not contradictory and that they

converge in a coherent strategy‖—several horizontal co-ordination options are considered following OECD

member-country experience:

―a special unit reporting directly to a head of government or parliament [France];

an integrated ministry to address several issues of importance to rural regions [UK, Germany, Japan];

‗policy proofing‘ [UK, Canada]; and

inter-ministerial co-ordination via working groups and formal contracts [Mexico, Italy]‖

In Mexico OECD highlights the innovations from the LDRS and CIDRS, but acknowledges that

―SAGARPA has been much on its own leading the promotion and implementation of the LDRS [and that]

the fact that the CIDRS is chaired by one sector limits the multi-sectoral objective of the law.‖ In this last

respect, ―experience from OECD countries indicates that a horizontal commission which is chaired by one

sector (in this case, agriculture) may be limited in pursuing multi-sectoral objectives and hinders the full

involvement of other ministries in a national rural strategy‖. The alternatives proposed to strengthen the

CIDRS are:

―Assigning a meta-ministerial leadership to the CIDRS (…), which could be filled by the Chief of the

Executive‖.

―Rotated leadership of CIDRS (…) among different ministries. In this way the works of the

commission are not seen as monopolized by one institution‖

―The creation of an ad hoc independent institution in charge of rural policy with multi-sectoral

perspective, with budget and normative arrangements to enforce collaboration from the different

ministries‖.

―Strengthening the legal attributions of CIDRS (…), with stronger budgetary allowances rather than

the formality of presenting a ‗rural budget‘ to congress‖.

Source: OECD, 2006a, pp. 110–114, and OECD 2007c, pp. 118–122

107. The planning system for ARD spending should be based on a comprehensive

national ARD strategy. Without a comprehensive ARD strategy and planning

system for ARD expenditures it is difficult to achieve coherence among ARD

programs and their objectives. A comprehensive ARD strategy with consistent,

explicit, and selective objectives as well as quantifiable results and performance

indicators would be an important step toward better ARD policy. The strategy

could serve as a framework for individual programs, to be assessed by their

contribution to its objectives. M&E of individual programs could also be carried

out. Along with the strategy, an ARD budgetary planning system would be

required to ensure consistency between the strategy and budgetary allocations. As

seen, PEC has led to substantial progress in this direction, but so far it provides

only the framework—not the content—of such a system.

Page 97: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

77

2) Rationalizing the Overall System for Farmer Support

108. The federal public expenditure system in productive programs should be

reoriented in three ways.

Gradually discontinuing MPS to inputs67

and outputs, as well as compensatory

cash transfers (see Technical Note 1 in the Appendix of this chapter which

describes New Zealand‘s successful agriculture policy reform experience in

the Appendix to this chapter).

Substantially increasing allocation to irrigation improvement and

management; drainage and transport infrastructure; other rural infrastructure

(such as that provided by FAIS); research, extension, and training; sanitary

and phyto-sanitary services; market intelligence (including collecting weather

information through weather stations and agricultural statistics); emergency

programs; and other public goods.68

Increasing support to small producers.

109. Non-targeted production-oriented programs benefiting mostly commercial

farmers should be separated from productive and natural resource

management (NRM) programs targeting small producers, vulnerable groups,

and the poor which should be decentralized to the states. Resources for non-

targeted production-oriented programs could be maintained at the federal level,

but funds now spent by different ministries for targeted programs could be

pooled. The pooled funds could be distributed to state governments as block

grants according to an objective formula to allow state governments to create their

own programs that promote small producers. In addition, given the current

imbalance in favor of non-targeted programs, some resources could be moved

from non-targeted programs to the pooled fund. These decentralized funds could

also support programs that assist small producers in adapting to climate change

and increasing positive externalities in NRM.

110. Federal non-targeted programs that support on-farm and value chain

investments should be rationalized. These programs include PROGAN, Apoyos a

la Competitividad de las Ramas Productivas/Adquisición de Activos Productivos,

and the non-targeted programs of Alianza. One option is to merge these types of

67

Given the likely difficulty of immediately discontinuing tarifa 9, a major input subsidy program that

subsidizes electricity for farmers to pump groundwater, Asad and Dinar (2006) present some options for

reforming the program: (i) decoupling, so that each farmer receives the average subsidy; (ii) allocating the

subsidy based on historical consumption; (iii) assigning subsidies only to water concession holders,

thereby stimulating a more efficient and legal use of water and electricity; and (iv) a combination of one of

the preceding options with a payment per hectare approach to further target the subsidy. Each of these

options has political economy consequences that would need to be considered in the context of the policy

dialogue, but none of the options would be as politically charged as eliminating the subsidy altogether. 68

Certain functions within these activities should be carried out by the private sector due to the private

goods nature of the activity, e.g. implementing appropriate management practices, financing of the

certification process, developing traceable systems etc.

Page 98: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

78

program into a new single non-targeted support program for on-farm and

agriculture value chains investments. Another is to maintain different programs

but redesign them and perhaps eliminating some to avoid duplications, sharpen

their objectives, and make them more effective and results oriented.

111. Non-targeted programs, which benefit mostly commercial farmers, are better

administered at the federal level. This is because these producers tend to be

more specialized, better linked to the value chains, and less in need of a close

rapport with agency staff. A commodity or value chain approach rather than a

territorial one could be used for these programs, so it makes sense to decentralize

the mandate and resources for supporting small producers while managing non-

targeted programs at the central level.

112. The logic of deficiency payments needs to be reassessed. Deficiency payments

protect farmers‘ incomes from market events by providing a subsidy equal to the

difference between the market price and a reference price calculated to ensure a

―fair‖ income to farmers. Isolating farmers from price movements (particularly

price falls) interferes with market adjustment. Depending on the crop supported,

deficiency payments can encourage overuse of water resources, as in Mexico,

where water-intensive basic grain production is supported. Deficiency payments

may be justified on a strictly temporary basis under emergency conditions but not

as a permanent support system. One such deficiency payment program is

Mexico‘s Ingreso Objetivo which covers 10 basic crops (mainly grains) in certain

states and is used as a permanent system of income support to beneficiary

farmers.69

The program is expensive and inequitable and distorts production

decisions. More efficient market-based instruments based on price risk

management tools, insurance, and other public goods could also protect farm

incomes while promoting competitiveness, employment, and growth in a less

distortionary manner than deficiency payments.

113. The logic of decoupled compensatory transfers also needs to be reassessed. Lump-sum compensatory transfers have been much celebrated because, being

decoupled from production and prices, they are a non-distortionary payment to

farmers. They have been widely used in the European Union, United States, and

other countries to cushion the transition to market liberalization and the lifting of

price supports. Originally designed for a transition period of 15 years (1994–

2008), Mexico‘s PROCAMPO is this type of a large compensatory transfer

program. Having reached the end of the transition period and having cushioned

the NAFTA impact, the economic logic of this program should be analyzed, given

how expensive and inequitable it is. The GOM can reassess whether to keep

paying farmers more or less indefinitely because they planted corn (or other

eligible crop) 18–20 years ago, especially with the recent high agricultural prices.

69

This program is akin to the U.S. Marketing Assistance Loan program, a major countercyclical program

that allows farmers of designated crops to receive a loan from the government using production as

collateral. The program effectively guarantees a minimum price for the crops since producers can forfeit

the crop to the government when the loan matures and keep the loan principal as payment, if market prices

are lower than the guaranteed price.

Page 99: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

79

114. The role of compensatory transfer programs on easing rural liquidity

constraints should be clarified. Rural credit in Mexico is very limited, seriously

constraining investment capacity in rural areas.70

Because of this, public subsidies

can help ease liquidity restrictions for rural producers. But it would be better to

tackle the underlying challenge of increasing rural finance (Box 6-2)—for

example, by adjusting the regulatory framework to better reflect the

circumstances of rural financial markets,71

by picking up part of the risk of rural

credit operations, by subsidizing some fixed costs of providing financial services

to small dispersed producers, by supporting microfinance institutions with

training and technology, or by expanding the capacity and improving the focus of

government rural financial institutions such as Fideicomisos Instituidos en

Relación con la Agricultura (FIRA), Fondo de Capitalización e Inversión del

Sector Rural and Financiera Rural. Furthermore, promoting price risk

management tools and insurance can increase farmers‘ access to credit because

financial institutions regard these tools as guarantees in approving credit.

Box 6-2: Challenges Facing the Rural Finance Sector in Mexico

Rural finance in Mexico is characterized by inadequate outreach and limited access to finance. Nearly 70 percent of municipalities do not have a single bank branch, and close to 80 percent of the rural population does not have access to financial services Financial services in rural areas are provided mostly by numerous small, often weak institutions. There are three main challenges facing the sector at the retail level:

Consolidating local institutions and enhancing depositor confidence by ensuring that institutions are

regulated and supervised and by establishing a deposit protection fund offering a reasonable level of

security to savers.

Deepening penetration and outreach of the sector by strengthening the branch network of existing

institutions and by deploying innovative non-infrastructure-based approaches such as

correspondent/agent banking and mobile banking.

Adapting lending processes to the characteristics of low-income rural clients to mitigate self-selection

out of the formal banking system by potential clients and introducing financial products that respond to

needs of the local population (small savings, medium- to long-term maturity loans, national and

international remittances, among others). There are several new types of agencies (―para-financieras,‖

SOFOLES, SOFOMES) that are becoming important sources of rural finance using different means. It

would be useful to evaluate their effectiveness.

The national and policy levels also face a range of issues, notably more schemes supported by multiple institutions, which permits arbitrage among recipient banks/institutions and unhealthy competition among public institutions (in lending and in channeling subsidies), and a relatively large subsidy in interest rate and transaction costs. The main challenges at the policy level are initiating action to consolidate and integrate the various schemes and programs under one or two agencies, carrying out a stringent evaluation of the different forms of subsidy and their outcomes to improve efficiency of public funds, and reviewing

70

Rural finance is an extremely important policy issue in Mexico, but it is not addressed in this study partly

because of its technical nature and partly because, although there are some rural finance programs in PEC,

this being mainly a private area, most associated issues are not visible in a public expenditure analysis. 71

Some examples of proposed adjustment to the regulatory framework include amending legislation of the

minimum deposit requirement for niche financial companies such as housing mortgage companies and

consumer lending companies to enable them to accept deposits, which is a more demanded service in rural

areas than credit; reforming the structure of Financiera Rural to separate its role as a second-tier bank and

first-tier bank to alleviate unfair competition in the first-tier banking market; and defining norms to

standardize the operations of auxiliary financial service firms in areas such as credit registration forms,

credit reporting to government, and accounting reporting forms (Buchenau and del Angel 2007).

Page 100: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

80

the roles of the nodal agencies in the changing sector institutional capacity (for example, FIRA‘s ability to continue it subsidy program is expected to diminish significantly over the next five to six years).

115. Rural non-farm development has large potential for complementing

agriculture policies in fostering rural development. As shown in chapter 2,

rural nonfarm activities are extremely important for income generation and

employment in rural areas, but they receive only a small part of ARD

expenditures. Reaching this sector with promotional activities is a big challenge,

but so is the potential payoff. Difficulties arise from the multi-sector character of

rural nonfarm activities and the absence of organizations whose members are

engaged in rural nonfarm economic activities,72

which gives the sector little

visibility and common voice. The government‘s sectoral organization in economic

development also makes it difficult to formulate policies that support the sector.

This is particularly true because some important measures – including safety nets

in the short term and increasing human capital in the longer term – are the

responsibilities of different governmental agencies.

116. The suggestions described above for rationalizing the overall system for farmer

support imply, at the individual program level, the gradual discontinuation of

PROCAMPO and Ingreso Objetivo as well as the transformation of Alianza. The

rationale for these options and discussion of alternatives follows.

117. PROCAMPO. The future of PROCAMPO has elicited many ideas. So far,

notwithstanding the end of the NAFTA transition period, the program has been

maintained without major modifications. But there are airs of change, and

proposals are being voiced. Some attempt to make the program less regressive by

capping payments (making payment per hectare a decreasing function of size or

limiting eligibility to farmers under a certain size, say 5, 10, or 20 hectares).

Another proposal is to open the program to all farmers and link it to present farm

size rather than to the historical acreage of eligible crops. Thus, all farmers, by

virtue of being such, would receive a subsidy linked somehow, more or less

regressively, to farm size, with or without a limit on that size or a cap on

payments. Bolder proposals are to discontinue PROCAMPO and use its resources

for something else to benefit farmers or the rural population (such as expanding

Oportunidades, carrying out new environmental programs, or improving rural

education). The most detailed proposal divides PROCAMPO into two parts: an

unconditional cash transfer and a conditional cash transfer (see Box 6-3; Winters

and Davis 2007).

Box 6-3: Proposal by Winters and Davis (2007) on PROCAMPO Reform

The proposal by Winters and Davis (2007) divides PROCAMPO into an unconditional cash transfer and a

conditional cash transfer. The unconditional transfer would be paid to all farmers, regardless of crop, of up

to 5 hectares,1

as a fixed, lump-sum. Eligible land is defined as ―the average total land [under] production

72

This includes small traders, artisans, small entrepreneurs in different industries (dressmaking,

shoemaking, construction materials, and the like), providers of personal and technical services (hairdressers,

mechanics, electricians, and the like), and others.

Page 101: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

81

over the previous three agricultural seasons.‖2 Conditional transfers would be paid to all farmers,

irrespective of crop, of up to 10 hectares, proportional to the amount of land, and subject to certain

conditions on ―capacity building and/or the adoption of certain agricultural practices of resource

management.‖3 Participation in the conditional transfer would be optional. Farmers of less than 5 hectares

could receive both transfers. Conditionality would be ―region specific and determined by regional

SAGARPA offices.‖ The total payment to a household from the two transfers could be capped. For

households also participating in Oportunidades the payment from the PROCAMPO transfers plus the

payment from Oportunidades could be capped.

Observations. This proposal improves on PROCAMPO but has some shortcomings. With regard to the

unconditional transfer, what is the sense of making an unconditional lump-sum transfer to small farmers

when Oportunidades already exists? Oportunidades is well targeted and covers the entire rural area, so a

farming household that is not a beneficiary is not likely to qualify as poor.4 Why should it then receive an

unconditional cash transfer from government? What makes this household more deserving than other

nonpoor households? If the household already participates in Oportunidades, why should it receive a

separate payment from PROCAMPO that other Oportunidades beneficiaries do not receive? There is little

economic sense in this.

The conditional transfer raises two questions. First, exactly what conditionality would be applied and how

would it be monitored? The implementational difficulties of production-oriented programs suggests many

monitoring challenges. Second, is a size-related transfer conditional on certain recipient behavior better

than alternative ways to promote farm competitiveness for the size range of farms considered. Among the

alternative forms is support (through co-financing) of on-farm investments like those carried out by

Alianza. Much duplication and overlapping would be likely between this transfer and the Alianza PDR

program, which is targeted to the same type of farmers.

1 The authors indicate that the cutoffs of 5 and 10 hectares chosen for small and medium-size farmers are only

suggested definitions and that careful consideration should be given to other cutoffs. The authors also mention that the

beneficiaries of the first component could be selected by their poverty status, using a method similar to that of

Oportunidades. 2 No mention is made of livestock farms, and no difference is stated between rainfed and irrigated land. 3 The authors also say: ―The transfer could be conditional on adopting certain agricultural practices or attending public

lectures on productive activities and natural resource management and from these lectures presenting a management

plan for improving on-farm production practices.‖ 4 Oportunidades, like any other targeted program, suffers from exclusion errors. But Oportunidades is acknowledged to

be well targeted and well implemented, and hence this error should not be large. In any case, it would make little sense

to keep PROCAMPO as a default payment system for those missed by Oportunidades.

Source: Winters and Davis (2007).

118. Considerations for modifying or discontinuing PROCAMPO in its present

form. Although the rationale for discontinuing PROCAMPO may be clear

economically, especially given the existence of other programs that cater to small

farmers, modifications to the program may be more feasible for the short term. In

designing a new PROCAMPO, important considerations include:

Ensuring that a modified PROCAMPO does not cause major negative

environmental externalities, or, better yet, that it promotes

environmentally friendly activities.

Page 102: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

82

Enhancing, or at least maintaining, the level of decoupling between

production and the subsidies to avoid distorting production decisions.73

Improving equity—for example, by capping payments or reducing

payment per hectare as the number of hectares increases.

Building in incentives to induce farmers to switch to high value crops, and

Announcing a final date to discontinue the program and possibly a

timetable for reducing payments until full discontinuation.

119. Possible alternative uses of PROCAMPO funds. Funds from the existing

PROCAMPO could be allocated to a completely new program with different

eligibility or operating rules or could be combined with an existing program that

would keep PROCAMPO‘s identity. Worthwhile alternatives include an

augmented Oportunidades program ("CAMPOrtunidades"), new environmental

programs, and improved rural education programs. Another option is to expand

the noncontributory rural pension scheme, which pays individuals age 70 and

older who live in locations of up to 20,000 inhabitants MxP 500 a month. Given

this coverage and benefit amount and 2005 Conteo Nacional de Población

population data, the program would cost about MxP 10.2 billion. Expanding to

cover the population age 65 and older would increase the cost to MxP 15.2

billion, and to cover the population age 60 and older (as in Brazil) would cost

MxP 21.7 billion. Since the 2007 programmed cost of PROCAMPO was MxP

14.9 billion, the funds from the discontinued PROCAMPO would more than

allow the pension program to cover rural residents age 60 and older.

120. Ingreso Objetivo. Ingreso Objetivo has much smaller coverage than PROCAMPO

and is generally regarded as a distortionary program. Most experts have proposed

discontinuing rather than modifying it (Box 6-4; Sumner and Balagtas 2007).

Another option being discussed by GOM is to use price bands rather than a single

reference price, but details of this proposal are still being developed.

Box 6-4: Proposal by Sumner and Balagtas (2007) on Ingreso Objetivo Reform

Sumner and Balagtas (2007) make two recommendations for Ingreso Objetivo reform. The preferred one is

to discontinue the program for five reasons:

The subsidy is inequitable, concentrating on better-off farmers and states.

Expected high cereal prices in the coming years mean that payments will be very small or nil, making

this a unique opportunity to eliminate the program.

It would be better to use countervailing duties to compensate producers for the reduction in U.S. export

prices due to U.S. domestic support policies.

Resources used in the incremental production of program crops due to the subsidy would be allocated

to other uses, increasing efficiency.

Eliminating the program would reduce production from participants, thus raising domestic prices and

favoring nonparticipants.

73

PROCAMPO is currently partially decoupled because subsidy payments are based on historic production

patterns. But a condition of receiving payment is that the land in question is still in active productive use

(including forestry or certain ecological use). Thus, for example, land that is fallow would not be

considered as under eligible use. This has raised concerns over its effect on deforestation and soil

degradation.

Page 103: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

83

They also recommend improvements to the program if political economy reasons prevent discontinuation.

The first is to reduce target prices so that ―they reflect the ‗safety net‘ feature of the program,‖ setting target

prices ―so that payments are made only when market prices are truly low by historical standards

recognizing the long-run trend toward lower commodity prices in inflation adjusted terms.‖ Another is to

decouple payments, converting them into direct transfers to ―all producers with a history of marketing the

program crop, with no requirement that they maintain production in that or another crop.‖

Observations. Reducing target prices seems a reasonable second-best option, but a program of decoupled

direct transfers to farmers with a historical record of producing the program crops already exists:

PROCAMPO. If amended this way, Ingreso Objetivo would duplicate PROCAMPO while being more

poorly targeted. Another option is to pay the price subsidy not on the full amount produced but on a

smaller, intra-marginal amount, so that the Ingreso Objetivo payment does not affect producers‘ decisions.

This would improve the allocative distortions from the subsidy but not its distributional bias. Related to

this, Rosenzweig (2008) proposes to discount PROCAMPO transfers from the Ingreso Objetivo subsidy.

Source: Sumner and Balagtas (2007)

121. Alianza. Alianza para el Campo, Mexico‘s flagship agriculture investment

support program, is the largest demand-led program for co-financing private on-

farm investments. But Alianza is more than that: it is a financing umbrella for a

wide variety of SAGARPA activities, from fisheries to sanitary and phyto-

sanitary services, farmer organization, support to rural development councils,

training, research, information systems, and a host of other expenses. Many

actions financed under Alianza are regular SAGARPA activities—that is, part the

regular work of any ministry of agriculture. It is unclear why these activities are

financed under a specific, annually renewed program, subject to yearly-approved

operation rules.

122. Reorienting Alianza. Three measures are proposed to realign the program:

Separating all the subprograms, components, and activities that naturally

belongs within the regular program of work of SAGARPA and budgeting them

under SAGARPA‘s regular expenses.

Merging funds from Alianza PDR with those of other production-oriented

targeted programs to be decentralized.

Either (i) merging untargeted investment support Alianza subprograms with

other untargeted investment support programs, such as PROGAN and Apoyo a las

Cadenas Productivas, to create one single large program to co-finance on-farm

and value chain investments, or (ii) maintaining different production-oriented

untargeted programs and redefining them to structure a comprehensive system

that provides general investment support to on-farm and agriculture value chain

investments. The policy instruments available for commercial agricultural growth,

including Alianza, must be rationalized and made more effective. Rosenzweig

(2008) points out the weak focus on productive activities in the current APE and

emphasizes the need for new instruments for a more effective agricultural policy.

Page 104: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

84

Restructuring the investment support system for commercial agriculture would be

a major part of this effort.74

3) Improving the Support System for Small Producers through

gradual decentralization

123. Small producers face big and distinct challenges. Small producers‘ restrictions

and potentials differ from those of medium-size and large commercial farmers.

Small producers needs require adequate consideration in ARD expenses to make

them more competitive, especially given the highly regressive nature of the

agricultural support programs (see chapter 4). Several programs from various

ministries are already oriented toward small farmers (Alianza PDR, for example).

But challenges remain: the numerous programs overlap and lack a clear-cut

rationale, investments are so dispersed that effectiveness is reduced, and technical

assistance, training, and business focus are insufficient. Technical Note 2 in the

Appendix of this chapter summarizes Chile‘s technical assistance program, which

is clearly targeted toward small farmers.

124. Gradual decentralization to state governments of the mandate and resources

to support small producers would help address challenges.75

There are several

reasons for this:

Decentralization would facilitate a territorial approach for rural development,

which would help clustering investments (see below).

The number, dispersion, and heterogeneity of small producers favor

responsibilities at the sub-national level, where constraints and opportunities

can best be identified.

The sub-national level is also more appropriate for attaining synergy between

productive programs and other investments and services (such as NRM,

infrastructure or education) favoring small producers.

Resources could be more rationally used at the sub-national level if state

governments apply them according to state-level strategic plans for the

development of the small producers (see below).

125. In principle, such decentralized funds should be targeted mainly at states

where it can be most efficiently used by small producers, i.e., where it can get

the biggest ―bang for buck‖ in terms of growth and poverty reduction. In practice,

74

Rowenzweig (2008) offers the following as guidelines for such a restructuring: (i) employment

generation should be a critical aim of the support system because it is a major way for the growth of the

commercial sector to trickle down (crops and farming systems that are labor intensive should thus be

supported); (ii) instead of rigid operational rules of present programs, flexibility is needed to operate

severeal support instruments, from competitive funds to liquid guarantees, co-financing of relevant

investments, kickoff grants, support to strategic alliances between producers and other market agents, tax

concessions, and others (the use of these instruments should be selective rather than universal); and (iii) the

support system should embrace not only farmers but other agents in the value chains who create synergies. 75

There is a detailed analysis of a proposal to decentralize rural programs to state governments in World

Bank (2006a) and World Bank (2007c).

Page 105: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

85

political realities will mean that there are some tradeoffs necessary, but at the

least, the programs should be designed to allow monitoring of results over time,

so that future allocations can take past performance into account.

126. Because decentralization takes time to implement, a starting point could be a

discussion between the federal government and state governments to clarify

the following aspects:

Federal programs, subprograms, and components that could be

decentralized—that is, programs that are production-oriented and targeted to

small producers.

The formula for distributing funds to the states.

Other resources that should be transferred, such as staff, vehicles, operation

funds, equipment, buildings, and so on.

Eventual institutional support to some state governments from the federal

level to enable them to effectively carry out their new responsibilities.

The broad guidelines and the M&E system to be established by the federal

government for the use of funds.

Responsibilities for the federal government and state governments. Federal

government responsibilities would include setting minimum standards and

benchmarks for use of funds by state governments, conditioning fund transfer

on preparation of strategies and programs, setting up M&E systems for these

strategies and programs, enhancing state government implementation

capacity, and auditing use of block grants, independent of the audits by state

legislative bodies. State responsibilities would include creating and approving

a state strategy for developing the small producer sector and a logical

framework with clear objectives and measurable outcomes that could be

evaluated as well as any necessary counterpart funding from their own

resources.

127. After the transition period, decentralization would imply transferring to

state governments, in addition to the present FAIS to finance small rural

infrastructure, block grants for the decentralized development of small rural

producers (in productive and NRM activities).76

This, in turn, implies (i)

76

The idea is to decentralize to state governments the budgetary funds of programs oriented toward

improving the productive and competitive capacity of small producers. These funds are currently budgeted

under federal production-oriented targeted programs of various ministries, such as SEDESOL (. Opciones

Productivas), SECON (FONAES), SAGARPA (Alianza PRD), and SRA (FAPPA). Funds would be

distributed to the states as block grants, where the resources from different programs would be merged,

determined by an objective formula based on demand considerations, which should not be regressive.

Future programs that assist farmers in adapting to climate change and managing natural resources to

increase positive externalities would also be good candidates for funding under such block grants, since

such they would need to be carefully tailored to local agro-climatic and production conditions.

Page 106: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

86

phasing out corresponding federal ARD programs and allowing state governments

to replace them with their own programs, so that they can exert strong ownership

of the rural development agenda for the development of small producers in their

states; (ii) pushing ahead with administrative federalization (federalización

administrativa) to transfer to state governments the assets, staff, and other

operational resources of federal ministries required for state governments to

properly operate the newly decentralized funds; and (iii) strengthening the

implementation capacity of state governments to be able to takeover these

responsibilities.77

Decentralization of funds to support small producers would

facilitate the use of a territorial approach to rural development (Box 6-5).

Box 6-5: Applying a Territorial Approach to Rural Development in a Decentralization Option

Within the states the regional level is key to implement rural development activities with a territorial

approach. The collection of municipalities (regions) in which Mexican state governments divide their states

for planning purposes seem appropriate for a territorial approach to rural development—that is, for

clustering investment and implementing strategic territorial programs. Strong regional economic

coordination institutions are very important to that effect. Some states, for instance Michoacán, have

already created regional development councils. If strengthened with technical capabilities and provided

funds to co-finance productive programs for small producers, these councils could become the focal point

for rural economic development in their territories.

In most states, however, the coordination entities for rural development at the regional level are the

Comités Distritales de Desarrollo Rural Sustentable (CDDRS). These councils could be appropriate meso-

level entities for economic coordination of ARD activities in their regions but their institutional capacity

and participatory nature should be strengthened.

Regional councils (whether CDDRS or others designed by state governments) could combine participatory

principles with sound technical and market criteria to design long-term development strategies for small

producers in their territories. These strategies would be based on the potential of territorial assets and the

identification of development axes. Investment clustering could be achieved through programs decided in a

participatory manner, capable of attracting the interest of a sufficient number of producers in order to reach

a critical mass of output, and through the use of a value chain approach. Regional councils could also

design large projects capable of triggering rural regional development.

To fulfill these functions, regional councils would need to be staffed by core groups of well selected and

motivated technical staff, to be paid using the funds decentralized to the states. In addition, they should

receive a share of the decentralized resources to co-finance the financial investments in their regional

programs. Thus, regional councils would be the main operational vehicle of the rural development

strategies and policies of the states.

Source: World Bank (2006a).

4) Improving the M&E and Institutional Aspects of ARD

Programs

128. Alternatives exist to enhance the M&E system of ARD expenditures. Chapter

5 presented the recent important advances and areas for improvement in the M&E

of social programs: evaluations not only of single programs but also of the entire

PEC, development and integration of databases of the beneficiaries of ARD

77

See Wolrd Bank (2006a) for further discussion on options for decentralization in Mexico.

Page 107: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

87

programs, deeper program evaluations at longer intervals instead of the current

annual cycle, and systematic use of evaluation results for managerial and

budgetary decisions based on action agendas agreed upon by the evaluators, the

implementing agency, and a third party. Adherence to these agendas should be

monitored closely. As a logical follow on to the Ley de Desarrollo Rural

Sustentable, Mexico could also start a ―rural proofing‖ system to anticipate and

monitor national policies‘ impact on the rural sector. Canada and the United

Kingdom both found success with rural proofing systems (called ―rural lens‖ in

Canada; Box 6-6).

Box 6-6: Rural Proofing in the UK and Canada

The U.K. Government‘s Rural White Paper of 2000 obliges all domestic public entities to put a rural-

proofing mechanism in place through to systematically check policy design and implementation for impact

on rural areas, and to mitigate impacts where appropriate. Much like the ―rural lens‖ approach in Canada,

the process has helped interdepartmental coordination. Interest in rural proofing has spread from central

governments, becoming a tool for local authorities to analyze and improve. The British Commission for

Rural Communities, which acts as supervisory body to verify that rural proofing has been undertaken,

produces an annual report. The Treasury guidelines on SR04 highlight the need for rural proofing, but the

responsibility was on departments to translate it into their delivery plans for 2005–08.

In 1996, Canada produced the ―Thinking Rural‖ report, detailing new and explicit guidelines for rural

policy. The Federal Government created a Rural Secretariat within the Ministry of Agriculture and Agri-

Food to administer Canada‘s rural policymaking and to coordinate federal agency activity affecting rural

areas through an interdepartmental working group on rural issues. Subsequently, a Secretary of State for

Rural Affairs was established at the Cabinet level. All new policies were subject to a rural policy impact

assessment. In 1998 a rural lens checklist was introduced to determine whether a policy or program

addresses priorities for rural areas. The checklist covers the priority rural areas and the consideration,

delivery, communications, and M&E or rural impacts. The Rural Secretariat administers the Canadian

Rural Lens with staff from other departments, scrutinizing new policy initiatives. Rural lens staff can

advise the Minister to support (or not to support) new policy proposals. Although the Minister has only one

voice at the Cabinet table, opportunities to involve regional development agencies and their ministers are

sought. This gives departments an incentive to take the rural lens comments into account. If the rural lens

staff think that the rural perspective has not been properly addressed, they can influence the policy proposal

accordingly. The objective is not to advocate for putting rural considerations first, but to ensure that

decisions are fully informed of the implications for rural communities.

Source: OECD (2006), The New Rural Paradigm

UK The Countryside Agency (2004), Rural Proofing in 2003/04

129. Alternatives exist to improve program implementation. Implementation

challenges are complex and varied. Many are institutional limitations that take

time to resolve. Simplifying the number and type of programs would certainly

help respond to the implementation challenge, as would the approval of a

comprehensive ARD strategy. To help identify and address these issues,

CONEVAL has the process evaluations instrument, which could be widely used

to maintain the focus on implementation challenges. Issues that could be

addressed include:

Page 108: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

88

Revising the budgetary and administrative regulations under which ARD

programs are implemented to ensure that they provide sufficient flexibility

and do not unnecessarily impair or slow down implementation.

Paying due attention to the recurrent/operational cost needs of programs,

which are particularly large for production-oriented programs.

Improving dissemination of programs and the accountability of operators vis-

à-vis beneficiaries and using ―client satisfaction‖ criteria to assess

performance.

Improving the economic incentives and morale of program operators and

ensuring that incentives are well aligned with program objectives.

5) Increasing the Positive Environmental Externalities of ARD

Programs and Supporting the National Climate Change

Strategy

130. Strategies for supporting agriculture and for dealing with climate change

need to be mutually reinforcing. For the past two decades over 80 percent of

economic losses from weather-related disasters occurred in the agriculture

sector.78

Agricultural policies and climate change policies thus need to be

mutually reinforcing by incorporating two principles. First, farmers need to

respond to localized changes in climate depending on their individual conditions

and constraints. Policies should expand their options rather than encourage them

to make choices that do not correspond well to individual circumstances. Second,

farmers should not be encouraged to ―maladapt‖ by overusing scarce resources or

increasing production in high-risk areas. Both principles have implications for

agricultural policies that are congruent with the National Climate Change

strategy.

131. Expanding payments for environmental services (PES) programs beyond

forestry79

could create positive synergies between agricultural production

and the environment. Specific investment programs to reduce emissions that are

identified by the National Climate Change Strategy and that could be scaled up

include programs to increase the use of biomass (for example, through high-

efficiency wood burning stoves in rural communities and renewable energy

sources for rural areas as supported by Fideicomiso de Riesgo Compartido, or

FIRCO), livestock programs to rehabilitate degraded rangelands, and

78

Saldaña-Zorrilla (2007). 79

These include Pago por Servicios Hidrologicos Ambientales (PSAH), Programa Nacional de

Reforestacion (PRONARE), Programa de Conservación y Restauración de Ecosistemas Forestales

(PROCOREF) and Programa de Plantaciones Forestales Comerciales (PRODEPLAN) and would support

reforestation, more efficient forest management practices, and recovery of degraded forest lands. Forestry

programs, which have seen exponential growth in public expenditure allocation since 2000, could be

further scaled up, taking into careful consideration the current and future projection of ecological suitability

of the land in terms of soil characteristics and slope, as well as the financial viability of the productive

operation, to ensure that the right species of forests are being promoted in areas where they make sense

ecologically and financially.

Page 109: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

89

hydrometrological hazard risk management and water resources management.80

Scaling up these programs could be accomplished either through national

programs or through decentralized programs. Such scaling up should be

accompanied by appropriate monitoring measures to ensure that the programs are

responding to their objectives. In particular, there is considerable scope to replace

distortionary programs such as Ingreso Objetivo with targeted environmentally-

friendly payments for environmental services programs, which would reduce

distortions and provide income support to small farmers while also providing

valuable national and global externalities.

132. The discussion below on Mexico‘s umbrella forestry program, ProÁrbol,

highlights some challenges faced in PES programs and offers suggestions for

reorientation.

133. ProÁrbol. The ProÁrbol program is an umbrella framework under CONAFOR

that supports Mexico‘s forestry sector. Its far-reaching goals are aimed at

conducting forestry planning, improving production and productivity, promoting

conservation and forest restoration, and increasing sectoral competitiveness. In

terms of conservation efforts, it houses programs for reforestation, soil

restoration, forest fire prevention, sustainable forest management, and payment

for environmental services (Pago por Servicios Ambientales del Bosque,

PSAB).81

Previous and current administrations have allocated a significant

amount of budget to the sector since 2000, and the ProÁrbol budget has been

growing exponentially since,82

despite initial implementation and administrative

challenges.83

The program‘s performance still leaves much to be desired in terms

of meeting its goals (productivity, production level, conservation, and

competitiveness).

80

This may include improved water resources management programs that emphasize preserving

environmental services such as the Alianza para el Pueblo program, which supports efficient use of water

for irrigation, modernizing and rehabilitating irrigation districts, strengthening climate data collection,

processing, using and disseminating water, and recognizing ancestral practices and lessons learned by

communities affected by climate variability. 81

PSAB now receives over MxP 100 million a year in funding. Some 1.4 million hectares were under

conservation contracts in early 2008; 2008 contracts should bring this total to over 2 million hectares.

PSAH (and, subsequently, the water window of PSAB) pays landowners to conserve existing forests.

Payments are made ex post, once the conservation has been verified. Eligibility is based on both spatial

criteria (there is a map of eligible areas, based primarily on indicators of importance for water services) and

various prioritization criteria (each application receives from 0 to 5 points if they meet the stated criteria,

and the applications with most points are accepted); the actual criteria have evolved over time in response

to both technical and political considerations. Conservation contracts are for five years, and are renewable

providing applicants have sufficient points. Payments are uniform countrywide. They are stated in

multiples of the minimum wage, and amount to about US$40 per hectare per year for cloud forests and

US$30 per hectare per year for other forests. 82

Budget for the forestry sector in Mexico grew by 2,094 percent between 2001 and 2008 (Merino,

Rodriguez et. al., 2008). 83

For example, to streamline the work, the program initially conducted all transactions by bank transfers,

rather than by checks, which caused some delays and discontent among beneficiaries. Also, some

administrative guidelines—such as the verification procedures for plantations subsidies— were delayed.

Page 110: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

90

134. The status quo of the PSAB (ProÁrbol). Mexico undertook careful preparation

for the PSAB program. But these good intentions were overwhelmed by intense

implementation pressures. For example, criteria for payments for hydrological

environmental services were changed to spread payments more broadly,

irrespective of relative importance for water services, when it became clear that

focusing payments on areas where aquifers are most overexploited would

concentrate payments in only a few states. The program has also been used as a

vehicle to address unrelated activities, such as a commitment that Mexico made at

the Bishkek Mountain Summit to increase spending on conservation in mountain

areas; these were added to the eligibility criteria. The result was very poor

targeting, at least initially (Muñoz et. al. 2008). From 2003 to 2005 as much as 90

percent of forest area under contract was in areas with aquifers in equilibrium or

underexploited aquifers, and as much as 72 percent was in areas of low or very

low risk of deforestation. More recent assessments are not available, but

efficiency is thought to have increased (for example, location in an area of high

deforestation risk is now a priority criterion). A politically-driven requirement for

uniform payments also means that payments are often ill-suited to local

conditions—paying much more than opportunity costs in some areas (resulting in

much higher demand for participation than funding allows) and much less than

opportunity costs in other areas (resulting in limited participation in areas that

could provide very high levels of environmental services).

135. Reorientation of PSAB (ProÁrbol). PSAB shows that programs aimed at

improving environmental conditions are feasible and can attract considerable

interest from land users. But it also shows that such programs are as vulnerable as

other public programs to pressures that divert them from their stated objectives.

Considerable efforts are needed to ensure that these programs reach their

objectives efficiently.84

Even so, even an imperfect program aimed at improving

environmental conditions may well be better than one that generates negative

externalities. Technical Note 3 in the Appendix of this chapter presents some

international perspectives on programs for payments for environmental services.

136. Table 6-1 summarizes possible actions for each of the five policy themes

discussed above, identifying tradeoffs among the various criteria of policy options

such as cost, sequential importance, technical difficulty, risks, and impact. The

matrix highlights that while some options promise greater benefits in the longer

run, others could be targeted for quick action. Actions that are likely to have the

highest impact, and yet could be tackled in the short term include those to

improve the overall national ARD planning system, M&E system and some

changes in institutional or operational aspects. Other actions could be taken on as

84

The World Bank, with GEF co-financing, is supporting a project to increase the efficiency of Mexico's

PSAB program. The Mexico Environmental Services Project has three components: developing new

financing sources based on payments by local service users (primarily water users, but also biodiversity

users such as the tourism industry, and carbon buyers), increasing the efficiency of the current payment

program (primarily by moving away from the current countrywide one-size-fits-all approach to a

differentiated approach tailored to the conditions of particular areas), and one to support participation by

poorer ejidos.

Page 111: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

91

a mid to long term goal, such as decentralization of small farmer programs to state

governments. However, even for this longer term action, concrete immediate

steps are also identified, such as identifying the responsibilities of each level of

government and national benchmarks, that would facilitate the transition to the

longer term goal but could be implemented in the short term.

Table 6-1: Summary Matrix of Policy Actions

Policy Options

Implemen-

tation

Likely

Impact

Technical

Difficulty/

Risks

Fiscal Cost

or Savings

1. Improving the ARD Planning System

(1) Prepare and approve a national

ARD strategy Short High Medium Low Cost

(2) Reposition CIDRS within the

federal government to strengthen its

coordination capacity, and build an

effective ARD budgetary planning

system

Short Medium High No Cost or

Savings

(3) Create a nucleus of high-level

agriculture policy analysts under

SAGARPA umbrella.

Short Medium Low Low Cost

2. Rationalizing the Overall System for Farmer Support

(1) Increase expenditure allocation to

public goods: irrigation improvement

and management, drainage and

transport infrastructure; other rural

infrastructure (such as that provided

by FAIS); research, extension and

training; sanitary and phyto-sanitary

services; market intelligence;

emergency programs; and others

Short, Medium

and Long High Medium High Cost

(2) Modify PROCAMPO Short Medium Medium

No Cost or

Savings

(3) Discontinue PROCAMPO Medium High High High Savings

(4) Modify Ingreso Objetivo Short Medium Medium

No Cost or

Savings

(5) Discontinue Ingreso Objetivo Medium High High High Savings

(6) Modify input support programs

(tarifa 9, agro-diesel, others) Short Medium Medium

No Cost or

Savings

(7) Discontinue input support

programs with or without temporary

compensatory payments (tarifa 9,

agro-diesel, others)

Short High High High Savings

(8) Rationalize federal non-targeted

programs oriented to support on-farm

and value chain investments (mainly

PROGAN, Apoyos a la

Competitividad de las Ramas

Productivas/Adquisición de Activos

Productivos, and the non-targeted

programs of Alianza).

Short, Medium High High No Cost or

Savings

(9) Reduce the allocation to non- Short, Medium High Low Medium

Page 112: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

92

Policy Options

Implemen-

tation

Likely

Impact

Technical

Difficulty/

Risks

Fiscal Cost

or Savings targeted production-oriented programs

to increase support for small producers

(see 3 (1))*

and Long Savings

(10) Increase support to the rural

nonfarm sector

Short, Medium

and Long High High

Medium Cost

(11) Strengthen the rural finance

sector to increase service access

Short,

Medium, and

Long

High High Medium Cost

3. Improving the Support System for Small Producers through gradual decentralization

(1) Increase expenditure allocations to

support small producers*

Short, Medium

and Long High Low

Medium

Cost

(2) Pool resources from targeted

production/NRM-oriented programs of

different federal entities, decentralize

those resources to state governments

according to an agreed distribution

formula and decentralization protocol,

and discontinue the corresponding

federal programs

Medium, Long High High No Cost or

Savings

(3) Accelerate the decentralization of

ARD federal offices (federalización

administrativa)

Short,

Medium, and

Long

Medium High Low Cost

(4) Agree with state governments on a

protocol containing guidelines for

decentralization of funds to support

small producers: (i) national

benchmarks, (ii) fund distribution

formula, (iii) M&E system, (iv)

implementation support system, and

(v) state government responsibilities

Short Medium Medium No Cost or

Savings

4. Improving the M&E and Institutional Aspects of ARD Programs

(1) Adjust budgetary and

administrative regulations of ARD

programs to ensure flexibility and

timely execution

Short

Medium

High

No Cost or

Savings

(2) Increase recurrent cost allocations

for production oriented programs

Short, Medium

and Long

Medium

Medium

Medium Cost

(3) Improve the dissemination of ARD

programs

Short, Medium

and Long

Medium

Low

Low Cost

(4) Improve the accountability of

program operators at all levels and

introduce ―client satisfaction‖ criteria

to assess performance

Short, Medium

and Long

High

Medium

Low Cost

(5) Improve the economic and moral

incentives of medium and bottom level

program operators

Short, Medium

and Long

High

Medium

Medium Cost

(6) Carry out evaluations of the entire

PEC

Short, Medium

and Long Medium Low/Medium Low Cost

(7) Develop and integrate databases of Short, Medium Medium Medium Low Cost

Page 113: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

93

Policy Options

Implemen-

tation

Likely

Impact

Technical

Difficulty/

Risks

Fiscal Cost

or Savings ARD program beneficiaries and Long

(8) Carry out in-depth program

evaluations at less frequent intervals

Short, Medium

and Long Medium Low Low Cost

(9) Organize a system to agree on and

monitor action agendas deriving from

evaluation results

Short

Medium

Low

Low Cost

5. Increasing the Positive Environmental Externalities of ARD programs and Supporting the National

Climate Change Strategy

(1) Improve SAGARPA norms to

regulate slash and burn agriculture in

light of increasing forest fires

Short Medium Low No Cost or

Savings

(2) Increase research allocation to

research and technology transfer of

reducing emissions from agriculture

such as no-till technology, reducing

GHG gas from livestock, reforestation,

efficient use of inputs

Short, Medium

and Long High Medium Medium Cost

(3) Revise regulations to incentivize

farmers to sell electricity generated by

biomass to the grid**

Medium Medium High Medium

Savings

(4) Improve targeting of geographical

area and payment levels of payment

for environmental services programs,

and scaling up its operations

Short, Medium

and Long High Medium High Cost

(5) Replace distortionary support

programs with payments for

environmental services

Short, Medium

and Long High Medium

No Cost or

Savings

Implementation term: Short (less than 2 years), generally associated with changes in laws or regulations;

Medium (3–5 years), requiring some institutional changes; Long (more than 5 years).

Effects term: Short (less than 2 years); Moderate (3–5 years); Long (more than 5 years).

Impact: High, medium, low (relative to other policy options proposed in these notes, not relative to other

more general reform options).

Technical difficulty/risks of undertaking the options suggested: High, medium, low.

Fiscal cost to government: High (large public investment programs), medium (some public program

expenditure required), low (little public expenditure). Fiscal saving: high, medium, low.

* The suggested proposal is to shift resources from non-targeted production oriented programs to targeted

ones (eventually decentralized to state governments) to support small farmers. Thus, the net effect should

be budget neutral—that is the overall expenditure should not increase or decrease.

** The suggested proposal is expected to increase investments by farmers to generate biomass energy.

Although, this proposal per se is budget neutral, in the long-run this should result in fiscal cost saving since

as farmers begin to generate biomass energy, they would buy less subsidized electricity from the grid.

Page 114: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

94

APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 6: TECHNICAL NOTES

Technical Note 1: New Zealand’s Successful Agriculture Policy

Reform Experience

New Zealand historically pursued a policy of agricultural protection (1960-1980), but

after structural macroeconomic adjustment and trade openness the agricultural sector

experienced a gradual liberalization from subsidies and price controls. In the period from

the 1960s until 1980 New Zealand had strong price controls and subsidies to farmers in

order to keep production levels constant while encouraging exports (Johnson, R.W.N.,

2000). By 1983, for instance, New Zealand‘s producer support estimate (PSE) was 35%

of producers‘ income and the effective rate of assistance surged to 123% of total rural

household income (OECD, 2008). After 1983, New Zealand Government began to reduce

export and farm subsidies in the agricultural sector. During the 1990s further deregulation

reforms enabled the agriculture sector to benefit from greater synergies, better use of

resources, and a competitive industry structure that allowed better adjustment to markets.

These reforms led to an improvement of TFP growth to average 2.5% a year compared to

a 1.5% growth in the pre-reform period.

Source: MAF, 2006

Policy Impacts of Reforms

Sector Growth

From the period between the mid-1960s until the mid-1980s the share of agriculture

production to GDP fell steadily from 14% to 5.7%, given heavy regulation, price

distortions, low incentives to production and unfavorable exchange rates. A decade after

deregulation in the agriculture labor productivity has doubled. Despite less land devoted

to livestock and arable farming—from 14 million hectares in the 1980s to 12 million

hectares in 2000s—, productivity increased 85% in a 20 year period.

Page 115: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

95

Source: MAF, 2006

The competitive market structure generated after the reforms led to smooth adjustments

to external shocks and, as a result, resources were more efficiently allocated to high

productivity sectors. For example, among pastoral industries the reformed caused

resources to divert into dairy farming, a highly productive sub-sector. Consequently, total

stock units in the dairy sector increased by 65% while beef and sheep sectors declined by

2 and 43%, respectively. A consequence of reforms was to allocate more resources into

innovation, research and other important services that foster agricultural production

efficiency. The high value of agriculture production has allowed New Zealand to have

one of the highest propensities to invest ratios, and one of the highest percentages of

GSSE in relation to TSE for the development in Agriculture among OECD countries

(OECD, 2008).

New Zealand’s GSSE on Agriculture 1986-2008

Source: OECD, 2008

References: Johnson, R.W. 2001. ―New Zealand’s Agricultural Reforms and their International Implications”. IEA,

U.K.

Anderson, K., Martin, W., and Valenzuela, E. 2006. “The Relative Importance of Global Agricultural

Subsidies and Market Access”. World Trade Review. Vol. 5 No. 3.

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1 996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

GSSE as % of TSE

Mexico New Zealand United States European Union OECD - Total

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1 996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

GSSE as % of TSE

Mexico New Zealand United States European Union OECD - Total

Page 116: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

96

MAF. Agriculture in New Zealand: Past, Present and Future. ABARE and New Zealand Ministry of

Agriculture and Forestry 2008

OECD. 2008. Case Study: Domestic Reform, Trade, Innovation and Growth in New Zealand‘s Agricultural

Sector. TPWP No. 74. Paris.

Technical Note 2: INDAP: Technology Transfer Targeting

Small Farmers in Chile

Chile‘s Institute for Agricultural Development (INDAP) began in 1962 as an agency of

the Ministry of Agriculture, oriented exclusively at enhancing the productivity of small,

family farms through lending and technical assistance. INDAP‘s definition of small farm

families, which has remained unchanged over the decades, is simple: families with 12 or

fewer hectares (irrigated equivalent), with a net worth less of than US$100,000, and with

income deriving principally from agriculture. Other than INDAP, there is no government-

supported extension service; commercial operations are left to contract such services with

private agents and remain unsubsidized. INDAP is also the only significant source of

formal long-term credit for the low-income, small-farm sector.

Chile was one of the first countries to introduce public funding and private delivery of

agricultural technical assistance. INDAP has evolved over time while maintaining a

degree of continuity as it adjusts to changing conditions. The basic principle of

underwriting private extension services for only small farms has been maintained for

three decades, although the structures of INDAP‘s operation have adapted to experience

and new realities. The overall approach has proven itself operationally as a manner of

delivering extension, although its success in graduating farmers is less clear. It has also

maintained political support and funding, which have increased in real terms. Questions

remain about program coverage and success in aiding viable farmers to reach commercial

competitiveness.

Impact of INDAP’s small farmer assistance programs

The growth in clients of INDAP‘s technical assistance programs and subsidies and

expenditures has been well documented. A third of INDAP‘s transfers are now credit

subsidies, and two-thirds are subsidies for on-farm investment, technical assistance, and

managerial training (either directly to individual farmers or to farm groups and

municipality-run programs in poor areas). According to the OECD, INDAP‘s credit and

technical assistance programs reached in some form (perhaps minimally) approximately

116,000 people in 2006, or 42 percent of small farms (as counted in the 1997 agricultural

census). The share receiving significant technical assistance is approximately half.

The role of INDAP‘s technical assistance in moving farmers into a sustainable, higher-

income trajectory—their insertion into commercial structures—is less well known, and

there are simply no good measures of how many former clients have left the program and

succeeded on their own. Unlike the USDA extension service, which is meant to be a

permanent support for information dissemination to agriculture as an industry and not

specifically oriented to small farmers, INDAP is meant to focus on a specific subgroup of

poorer farmers who could, with assistance, reach viable scales.

Page 117: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

97

The two most recent evaluations conducted in the mid-1990s show that INDAP

contributes to more intense agricultural input use, including family labor, which increases

gross and net farm income. Lopez (2000), however, finds that INDAP programs do not

raise family incomes due to an off-setting reduction in off-farm income and that more

intense input use does not raise total factor productivity. The key determinant in total

household income appears to be internal household characteristics rather than external

factors, including geographic location. Berdegue and others (1998) find that INDAP

programs increase household income, but the effect could have been due to selection bias.

They also note that INDAP has less of an effect in some geographic areas. But these

studies should be complemented by an examination of what happens to these families

over time, an analysis that INDAP has neglected.

INDAP‘s basic mission—to graduate viable farmers into commercial agriculture—has

not been explicitly used in evaluating the program. It is unclear whether INDAP is

treating new cohorts of farmers over time or aiding the same group of beneficiaries

repeatedly. The number of small farmers is declining, but INDAP has been growing.

During the early 1990s INDAP‘s budget increased 11 percent a year in real terms, and

4.4 percent in the late 1990s. By the early 2000s government funding still covered about

85 percent of INDAP costs. Some Chilean experts speculate that the agency attends to

more or less the same group of beneficiaries over time, implying that the fiscal outlays

per client could amount up to US$3,000 or more per year—or about US$50,000 over the

last 15 years. These would be large sums relative to the incomes of the Chilean rural poor.

Panel data following INDAP clients would be useful for finding the proportion of farmers

that reach commercial viability and the factors contributing to their success.. When

applying the lessons from Chile‘s INDAP to other countries, this deficiency should be

remedied.

A summary of best practices for technical assistance from INDAP’s experience

Define the target audience within the small farm sector, identifying the subset of

farmers that could eventually generate sustainable income without government

subsidies. Do not pretend to cover all small farmers at the same time.

Set up a monitoring system to assess a program‘s ability to graduate clients to

sustainability after five to seven years. Periodic quantitative evaluations are needed

(recognizing selection effects between clients and the control group) that go beyond

detecting impacts on production and input use to assessing the impact on household

incomes from all sources.

For farm families that cannot reach a viable scale in production, focus aid on

transition to other income activities and on social safety nets and noncontributory

pensions.

To reduce the costs and inefficiencies associated with government programs, do not

subsidize extension service for commercial farms. There is a rationale to support basic

and adaptive research for agriculture as a whole.

Government support for—and supervision of—private delivery of extension services

can provide technical assistance more efficiently than embedding extension delivery

in a government bureaucracy.

Page 118: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

98

Do not rely on a voucher system that asks individual small farmers to make contracts

with extension providers because it may not generate the scale of demand that could

sustain a private market for extension services.

Use centralized coordination of extension services for standardized commodities, not

for products that require closer vertical coordination along the marketing chain.

Recognize that an extension delivery system cannot ―get it right‖ from the beginning,

but must adjust to mistakes and changing conditions. Information and monitoring, and

flexibility, are key to adjustment.

References

Diaz, Juan. 2007. ―Family Farm Agriculture: Factors Limiting its Competitiveness and Policy

Suggestions,‖ note prepared for the OECD Review of Agricultural Policies: Chile.

Berdegue, Julio, and RIMISP (Red Internacional de Metodologías de Investigación en Sistemas de

Producción), STOAS, Grupo de Investigaciones Agrarias (GIA) and EMG Consultores. 1998.

―Evaluación de Instrumentos de Fomento Productivo: El Programa de Transferencia Tecnológica

de INDAP.‖ Santiago, Chile.

Lopez, Ramon. 2000. Determinants of Rural Poverty in Chile: Evaluating the Role of Public

Extension/Credit Programs and Other Factors,‖ Chapter 9 of R. Lopez and A. Valdes, eds., Rural

Poverty in Latin America, St. Martin‘s Press.

Sotomayor, Octavio. 1994. ―Políticas de modernización y reconversión de la pequeña agricultura

tradicional Chilena,‖ ODEPA and IICA, Santiago.

Source: Valdes and Foster (2008).

Technical Note 3: Payments for Environmental Services in

Natural Resource Sectors

Managing natural assets well is difficult because the value of many—if not most—of

their environmental services cannot be internalized by private actors; they are

externalities and public goods. Individuals in society generally value natural assets, but

the incentives guiding private action rarely reflect their value to society as a whole. The

key to better managing natural assets is to design institutions that can measure the social

benefits and costs of environmental services and translate that information into

appropriate incentives for individual decisionmakers, such as farmers. The classic policy

proposals for better management focused on reducing negative externalities:

environmental taxes on emissions, mandated best practices, property rights allocation,

and support for institutions for common property management.

In agriculture and forestry environmental taxes are rarely used due to the high cost of

monitoring emissions. Emissions permits outside agriculture tend to be pollutant specific.

Better known in the natural resource sector are best management practices to reduce

environmental damage. Such practices are now more common—for example, when

managing native forests—and are often pushed by tourism-linked considerations and by

consumer preferences in wealthier countries valuing not only the product but the

environmental friendliness of production. In fact, there is growing emphasis on private,

third-party certification and voluntary implementation of standards, as with organic

produce in fresh fruits and vegetables for exports. This is due in part to the normal

Page 119: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

99

slowness of governments as many developing countries to adjust the design and

enforcement of best practices.

Recent policies have emphasized both market-oriented and government-supported

subsidies of environmental goods and services. These policies, such as incentives for

better land management, focus on Payments for Environment Services (PES) provided by

those who benefit from such services, including local, regional, and global beneficiaries.

PES programs can be found increasingly in both developed and developing countries,

ranging from contracts between farmers and local industries whose profits are sensitive to

water availability, to contracts between one country‘s industry and groups in distant

countries seeking carbon sequestration. According to the FAO, there are four main PES

markets: climate change mitigation, watershed services, biodiversity conservation, and

landscape aesthetics. In developing countries markets for reducing carbon emission and

conserving biodiversity are potential sources of new revenue for agriculture. The ultimate

beneficiaries of environmental services are usually dispersed, so intermediaries such as

governments and international public and private concerned entities are required. To date,

PES programs have been pushed by governments and are geographically focused. They

are usually direct payments in exchange for better land management, such as soil and

water conservation measures, and tree plantations for carbon sequestration. Beneficiaries

can pay via a surcharge to water bills or with fees for park visitors. There are two key

steps for designing efficient PES programs. First is targeting farmers or other managers

of natural assets whose adoption of better management practices can yield the highest

environmental benefits for the lowest costs. Second is the structure of compensation,

which not only induces better management but also is ―self-enforcing‖ by reducing

monitoring costs and assuring compliance.

Perhaps the most studied case of PES in Latin America is the Costa Rican National

Forestry Financing Fund, which began in 1997 and has led to similar efforts in other

countries. The fund officially recognizes that forest owners provide a bundle of

environmental services, including watershed protection, biodiversity conservation, scenic

beauty, and carbon fixation and sequestration. The PES system arose when the

government was searching for sustainable funding for both forest conservation and aid to

the forestry sector. A 2002 evaluation of the program found that the Costa Rica PES had

contracted more than 280,000 hectares of private forests, with more than 800,000

hectares pending, spending US$57 million between 1997 and 2002. Forest conservation

contracts paid over US$210 per hectare, and reforestation contracts US$538 per hectare.

Funding came primarily from fuel taxes, complemented by international donors.

One special consideration is the potential role of PES in alleviating poverty. Associated

with poverty are low levels of education, ill-defined property rights over natural assets,

and a lack of capital that could support households during long-term investments in

natural assets (such as planting trees). Poverty often leads to environmental degradation.

Being able to target poor farmers for PES would bring both environmental benefits and

poverty reduction. Yet while targeting the poor on paper might be logical, implementing

a PES plan would be constrained by the very structural characteristics that link poverty to

Page 120: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

100

environmental degradation in the first place: ill-defined property rights that make

contracting and long-term projects uncertain for both buyer and seller of the service;

small farm holdings that increase the transaction costs per unit of compensation and

reduce the viability of better management (such as crop rotation) and thus increase the

required compensation to entice farmers to better management practices; and lack of

credit as a short-term backup makes farmers more risk averse to adopting a new system

of management. Nevertheless, the World Bank, while recognizing that PES is not in itself

an antipoverty strategy, has suggested some pro-poor considerations in PES design:

devise specific mechanisms to counter high transaction costs and understand the social

context in which a PES would be applied to avoid adverse impacts on the poor and design

appropriate remedial measures. Making PES programs pro-poor, however, might increase

their costs, so funding must be found beyond the beneficiaries of environment services.

Donors who are more directly concerned about poverty could finance these additional

costs.

Both the World Bank and the FAO have programs to help policymakers and interested

parties design PES strategies. The World Bank has supported PES projects in many

countries, particularly in Latin America. Past World Bank–supported PES projects have

been implemented in Colombia, Costa Rica, and Nicaragua; projects are currently under

way in Costa Rica, Mexico, and Panama; and projects are in preparation in Brazil,

Colombia, and Ecuador. FAO implements a program called Payment for Environmental

Services for Agricultural Landscapes (PESAL), under its Agricultural Development

Economic Division (ESA). The ESA provides web links and tools for designing and

implementing PES with information on ecosystem services markets, recommendations on

setting up PES schemes, and links other international organizations in this field.

Source: Valdes (2008b).

Page 121: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

101

Page 122: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

102

7. REFERENCES

Asad, M., and A. Dinar. 2006, ―The role of water policy in Mexico: Sustainability,

equity, and economic growth considerations.‖ Latin America and the Caribbean Region

Sustainable Development Working Paper No.27. Washington: World Bank.

Avila, A. F., and R. E. Evenson. 2004, Total Factor Productivity Growth in Agriculture:

The Role of Technological Capital. Chap. 31 in R. E. Evenson, P. Pingali, and T. P.

Schultz, eds., Handbook of Agricultural Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

Buchenau, J and del Angel, G, 2007, ―Consultoría sobre Servicios Financieros Rurales‖

(background paper for the IDB study on Mexico Agriculture Public Expenditure, 2007).

Cortés, F, Felipe López Calva, Rodolfo de la Torre, 2005, ―Evaluación de la pobreza en

México‖, Seminario Universitario de la Cuestión Social, Instituto de Investigaciones

Sociales, UNAM. August 24, 2005.

Engel, S., S. Pagiola, and S. Wunder. 2008, ―Designing payments for environmental

services in theory and practice: An overview of the issues.‖ Ecological Economics,

Special Issue on Payments for Environmental Services in Developing and Developed

Countries, 65:4, pp.663-674.

Fan, S., Hazell, P., Thorat, S., 1999, ―Linkages between government spending, growth

and poverty in rural India‖.

FAO, 2005a, Evaluación Alianza para el Campo 2004.

FAO, 2005b, ―Base de Datos de estadisticas e indicadorese del gasto publico agricola y

rural (GPAGRURAL), Oficina regional para American Latina y el Caribe, Santiago.

FAO-SAGARPA, 2004, Evaluación Nacional de Alianza para el Campo, Informe

General.

Gordillo, G., De Janvri, A. and E. Sadoulet, 1999, La Segunda Reforma Agraria de

México: respuestas de familias y comunidades, 1990-1994, FCE, Mexico.

Page 123: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

103

Guerrero García Rojas, H., 2007, ―Politicas y gasto publico federal en infraestructura de

riego‖ (background paper for the IDB study on Mexico Agriculture Public Expenditure,

2007).

Klepeis, P. and Vance, C., 2003, ― Neoliberal policy and deforestation in Southeastern

Mexico: An assessment of the PROCAMPO program‖, Economic Geography, Volume

79, Issue 3.

Knutson (2007), ―Assessment of Mexico‘s Sanitary, Phytosanitary, and Food Safety

Policies and Programs and Their Implementation: Diagnosis and Proposals for Reforms‖

(background paper for the IDB study on Mexico Agriculture Public Expenditure, 2007).

Leyva-Parra, G., 2005, ―El Ajuste del Ingreso de la ENIGH con la Contabilidad Nacional

y la Medición de la Pobreza en México‖, in Székely (ed.).

Lopez, R and Galinato G. I., 2007, ―Should Governments stop subsidies to private oods?

Evidence from rural Latin America‖, Journal of Public Economics 91, 1071-1094.

Merino, L., Rodríguez, J., et. al., 2008, ―Estudio Estratégico Sobre el Sector Forestal

Mexicano‖. (Unpublished draft prepared for the World Bank).

Muñoz Piña, C., Avila Forcada, S. et. al.,2006, ―Agricultural Demand for Groundwater in

Mexico: Impact of water Rights enforcement and electricity user fees on groundwater

level and quality‖ (background paper for the World Bank study ―Economic Assessment

of Policy Interventions in the Water Sector‖.

Muñoz-Piña, C., A. Guevara, J.M. Torres, and J. Braña. 2008. ―Paying for the

hydrological services of Mexico‘s forests: Analysis, negotiations and results.‖ Ecological

Economics, Special Issue on Payments for Environmental Services in Developing and

Developed Countries, 65:4, pp.725-736.

Musgrave R., 1959, ―The Theory of Public Finance‖. McGraw-Hill, New York.

OECD, 2006a, ―Agricultural and Fisheries Policies in Mexico‖.

OECD, 2006b, ―OECD Rural Policy Reviews: the New Rural Paradigm: Policies and

Governance‖

OECD, 2007a, ―Producer and Consumer Support Estimates OECD Database 1986-2006‖.

OECD, 2007b, ―Producer and Consumer Support Estimates OECD Database 1986-2006:

USER‘S GUIDE‖.

OECD, 2007c, ―Mexico: Estimates of support to agriculture, Producer and Consumer

Support Estimates OECD Database 1986-2006‖.

Page 124: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

104

OECD, 2007d, ―OECD Rural Policy Reviews: Mexico‖

Oliver, L.G. and Santillanes, S., 2008, ―Cuantificación y clasificación del gasto público

rural en México‖, Background paper for this study.

Pagiola, S., G. Platais, and A. Arcenas. 2005, ―Can payments for environmental services

help reduce poverty? An exploration of the issues and the evidence to date from Latin

America.‖ World Development, 33, pp.237-253.

Pagiola, S., and G. Platais. 2007, Payments for Environmental Services: From Theory to

Practice. Washington: World Bank.

Pagiola, S. 2008, ―Payments for environmental services in Costa Rica.‖ Ecological

Economics, Special Issue on Payments for Environmental Services in Developing and

Developed Countries, 65:4, pp.712-724.

Rosenzweig. A., 2008, ―Apuntes para el Grupo de Trabajo sobre Procampo: la Política de

Fomento Productivo en México en el Sector Agropecuario‖, Sagarpa, mimeo.

Ruiz-Castillo, J., 2005, An evaluation of ―El ingreso rural y la producción agropecuaria

en méxico 1989-2002‖, published in 2004 by the SIAP (Servicio de Información y

Estadística Agroalimentaria y Pesquera) of SAGARPA (Secretaría de Agricultura,

Ganadería, Desarrollo Rural, Pesca y Alimentación).

Saldaña-Zorrilla, S.O., 2007, Socioeconomic vulnerability to natural disasters in Mexico:

rural poor, trade and public response‖‖, CEPAL, Mexico.

Scott, J., 2005, ―Transferencias Públicas (y Otros Ingresos) en Especie en la Medición de

la Pobreza‖, in Székely (ed.), 2005.

Scott, J., 2008, ―Assessment of ARD Public Expenditures‖, Background paper for this

study.

Sumner, D.A. and Balagtas J.V., 2007, ―Economic Analysis of the Ingreso Objetivo

Program in Mexico‖ (background paper for the IDB study on Mexico Agriculture Public

Expenditure, 2007).

Székely, M. and Rascón, E., 2004, ―México 2000-2002: Reducción de la Pobreza con

Estabilidad y Expansión de Programas Sociales‖, May 2004.

Székely, M. (ed.), 2005, ―Números que Mueven al Mundo: La Medición de la Pobreza en

México‖, ANUIES-CIDE-SEDESOL-Miguel Ángel Porrúa.

Taylor, Yunez Naude, Gonzalez, 2007, ―Estudios sobre Politicas Publicas para el Sector

Rural en Mexico‖ (background paper for the IDB study on Mexico Agriculture Public

Expenditure, 2007).

Page 125: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

105

Tendler, J, 1997, ―Good Government in the Tropics‖, Baltimore: The John Hopkins

University Press.

Valdes, A., 2008a, ―Agricultural Public Spending: Description and Assessment Relevant

to Latin America‖, Background paper for this study.

Valdes, A. 2008b, ―Payments for Environmental Services in Natural Resource Sectors‖,

Background paper for this study.

Valdes A. and Foster, W., 2008, ―INDAP: Public Funding and Private Delivery

Technology Transfer targeting Small Farmers in Chile‖, Background paper for this study.

Winter, P. and Davis, B., 2007, ―Designing a new PROCAMPO program: Lessons from

Oportunidades‖ (background paper for the IDB study on Mexico Agriculture Public

Expenditure, 2007).

World Bank, 2002, ―State-level Public Expenditure Review: The Case of Guanajuato‖.

World Bank, 2003, ―State-level Public Expenditure Review: The Case of Veracruz-

Llave‖.

World Bank, 2004a, ―Mexico Public Expenditure Review‖.

World Bank, 2004b, ―Access to Finance for Farmers and Agriculture Enterprises‖

(Unpublished).

World Bank 2004c, ―Poverty in Mexico: an Assessment of Conditions, Trends and the

Government Strategy‖.

World Bank, 2005a, ―Beyond the City the Rural Contribution to Development‖.

World Bank, 2005b, ―Income Generation and Social Protection for the Poor‖.

World Bank, 2005c, ―Infrastructure Public Expenditure Review (PER)‖.

World Bank, 2006a, ―Decentralization, Poverty, and Development in Mexico‖.

World Bank, 2006b, ―Mexico‘s Competitiveness: Reaching its Potential‖.

World Bank, 2007a, ―Water Public Expenditure Review‖ (Unpublished).

World Bank, 2007b, ―Policy Note on Sensitive Crops (Corn, Sugar, Beans)‖

(Unpublished).

Page 126: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review

106

World Bank, 2007c,‖Mexico 2006-2001: Creating the Foundations for Equitable

Growth‖. Policy Notes.

World Bank. 2007d, ―State and trends of the carbon market 2007.‖ Washington: World

Bank.

World Bank, 2008a, ―World Development Report 2008 Agriculture for Development.

World Bank, 2008b, ―Climate Change Aspects in Agriculture: Mexico Country Note‖,

Unpublished.

World Bank, 2008c, ―Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Latin America‖, Edited by

K. Anderson and A. Valdes.

World Bank, 2008d, ―Poverty and Social Impact Analysis of Groundwater Over-

exploitation in Mexico‖ (Draft).

Page 127: MEXICO AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMEXICO/Resources/EnglishPERDec16.… · Agriculture and Rural Development Public Expenditure Review