market structure and price variability of agricultural...

140
Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural Commodities in Central Sulawesi Province, Indonesia Triana Anggraenie Accomplished at the Tropical and International Agriculture Faculty of Agricultural Sciences Georg-August University of Goettingen

Upload: others

Post on 24-Jun-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural Commodities

in Central Sulawesi Province, Indonesia

Triana Anggraenie

Accomplished at the Tropical and International Agriculture

Faculty of Agricultural Sciences Georg-August University of Goettingen

Page 2: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Anggraenie, Triana

Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural Commodities in Central Sulawesi Province, Indonesia

Masterarbeit im wissenschaftlichen Studiengang Agrarwissenschaften an der Georg-August Universität Göttingen, Fakultät für Agrarwissenschaften

Studienrichtung: 1. Prüfer: Prof. Dr. Manfred Zeller 2. Prüfer: Dr. Bernhard Bruemmer Abgabetermin: 07 September 2005 angefertigt im:

Page 3: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

STATUTORY DECLARATION

I herewith declare that I composed my thesis submitted independently without having

used any other sources or means than stated therein.

date: 07 September 2005 signature:

Page 4: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

ABSTRACT

In the vicinity of Lore Lindu National Park, Central Sulawesi as a focus of research

area, integration of small farmers in the agricultural markets plays for rural

livelihoods. Agricultural markets in developing countries are often characterized by

inadequate physical and marketing infrastructure, high transport cost, and entry

barriers, therefore rural markets can be thin and isolated. Consequently, farmers deal

with prices that are volatile.

A survey was conducted to analyse structure, conduct and performance (SCP) of the

agricultural markets and to measure variability in agricultural input and output prices

across time and space. SCP analysis of the markets is mostly based on descriptive

statistics and analysis of variability in agricultural prices are conducted using

descriptive and econometric ARCH model.

In the research area, the typical agricultural marketing system is characterised by

oligopsonist market with regard to farmer producers, where market is dominated by

few large traders. For some commodities, there is a sort of vertical integration.

Degree of barrier to market entry in term of market license requirement is fairly low.

Involving in agricultural trading is relatively easy as indicated without any market

license required for small-scale business.

Each trader determines purchasing price independently. Price in Palu central market

is a primary reference for price setting. Payment method to farmers can be done by

cash, credit and in kind (barter). Due to written contract is not provided in credit

transaction, close relation and trust between the two participants are needed.

Road and market place are used as proxy of degree to market access. With better

market access, price of raw commodities such as cocoa increases and price variability

decreases. Price of consumer goods such as sugar increases and price variability

decreases with rising distance to central market. ARCH model applied for cocoa

indicates that prices are serially correlated and residuals of current and previous

periods are correlated.

i

Page 5: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table of Contents

Abstract iTable of Contents iiList of Tables ivList of Figures viList of Abbreviations vii 1. INTRODUCTION 1 1.1 Background 1 1.2 Research questions and objectives 4

1.3 Outline of the study 4 2. LITERATURE REVIEW 7 2.1 Agricultural marketing 7 2.2 Structure-Conduct-Performance paradigm 14 2.3 Alternative approaches of market analysis 20 2.4 Agricultural price variability 21 2.4.1 Sources and implications of seasonal and spatial price variability 21 2.4.2 Analysis of commodity price variability and risk 23 2.5 Summary 26 3. METHODOLOGY 28 3.1 Description of the study area 28 3.2 Sampling procedure, data collection, entry and cleaning 29 3.3 Methodology used in descriptive analysis 31 3.4 Methodology used in econometric analysis 35 3.4.1 Diagnostic and testing 35 3.4.2 ARCH model for price variability 37 3.5 Conceptual framework 39 3.6 Summary 41 4. AGRICULTURAL MARKET STRUCTURE 42 4.1 Cocoa market 42 4.2 Coffee market 48 4.3 Rice market 49 4.4 Maize market 54 4.5 Fertilizer market 56 4.6 Barriers to market entry 59 4.7 Summary 60 5. AGRICULTURAL MARKET CONDUCT 63

ii

Page 6: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

5.1 Profile of agricultural traders 63 5.2 Business practices 66 5.3 Trade associations 70 5.4 Summary 71 6. PERFORMANCE OF AGRICULTURAL MARKET 73 6.1 Access to market and infrastructure 73 6.2 Farmer’s share and gross marketing margin 74 6.3 Uncertainties, break even price and sensitivity analysis 78 6.4 Seasonal and spatial price variability 80 6.4.1 Seasonal price variability 81 6.4.1.1 Seasonal price variability of fertilizer 81 6.4.1.2 Seasonal price variability of cocoa 83 6.4.1.3 Seasonal price variability of coffee 86 6.4.1.4 Seasonal price variability of rice 87 6.4.1.5 Seasonal price variability of sugar 92 6.4.1.6 Seasonal price variability of cooking oil 94 6.4.2 Spatial price variability 97 6.5 Econometric results on price variability 103 6.6 Summary 108 7. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS 113 7.1 Major results 113 7.1.1 Agricultural market structure 113 7.1.2 Agricultural market conduct 115 7.1.3 Agricultural market performance 117 7.2 Policy implications 120 REFERENCES 122 APPENDICES 127

iii

Page 7: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

List of Tables

Table 3.1 Survey villages of the study 28Table 4.1 General characteristics of cocoa traders 45Table 4.2 General characteristics of rice traders 51Table 5.1 Characteristics of agricultural traders in research area 64Table 5.2 Specialization of trader activity in marketing chain 68Table 5.3 Relation between business duration and having regular and

searching new suppliers 69

Table 6.1 Characteristics of market access 73Table 6.2 Prices for cocoa in the marketing channel in October 2003 74Table 6.3 Prices for rice in the marketing channel in October 2003 75Table 6.4 Marketing margin for each participant in the marketing

channel 75

Table 6.5 Gross marketing margin of cocoa during 2003 76Table 6.6 Gross marketing margin of IR 66 super rice during 2003 77Table 6.7 Gross marketing margin of cimandi rice during 2003 77Table 6.8 Break even price and sensitivity analysis of cocoa 79Table 6.9 Break even price and sensitivity analysis of coffee 79Table 6.10 Break even Price and sensitivity analysis of rice 80Table 6.11 Lowest and highest cocoa price and seasonal gap in January-

December 2003 84

Table 6.12 Lowest and highest coffee price and seasonal gap in January-December 2003

87

Table 6.13 Lowest and highest cimandi rice price and seasonal gap in January-December 2003

90

Table 6.14 Lowest and highest IR 66 super rice price and seasonal gap in January-December 2003

92

iv

Page 8: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 6.15 Lowest and highest sugar price and seasonal gap in January-December 2003

93

Table 6.16 Lowest and highest cooking oil (super quality) price and seasonal gap in January-December 2003

95

Table 6.17 Lowest and highest cooking oil (medium quality) price and seasonal gap in January-December 2003

96

Table 6.18 Producer price distribution 99Table 6.19 Consumer price distribution 102Table 6.20 Unit root test using Dickey-Fuller test for natural logarithm

of weekly cocoa prices 103

Table 6.21 Unit root test using Dickey-Fuller test for natural logarithm of weekly rice prices

104

Table 6.22 Unit root test using Dickey-Fuller test for natural logarithm of weekly sugar prices

105

Table 6.23 Diagnostic test on homoscedastic model for cocoa 106Table 6.24 Diagnostic test on homoscedastic model for sugar 107Table 6.25 Diagnostic test on homoscedastic model for two varieties of

rice 107Table 6.26 Estimation of ARCH model for cocoa 108Table 6.27 Estimation of ARCH model for sugar 108 Table A1 Producer prices (Rp/kg), standard deviation and variability

for different commodities in January–December 2003 127

Table A2 Consumer prices (Rp/kg), standard deviation and variability for different commodities in January–December 2003

129

Table A3 Correlation between cimandi rice and fertilizer in Bolapapu 130

v

Page 9: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

List of Figures

Figure 2.1 Stages in a marketing system 8Figure 2.2 CDF for the probability distribution of gross margin 11Figure 2.3 Schematic categorization of issues in agricultural marketing 13Figure 2.4 Relationship between structure, conduct and performance 14Figure 3.1 Lorenz curve 34Figure 3.2 Framework for market analysis 40Figure 4.1 Marketing channel of cocoa 44Figure 4.2 Volume distribution of cocoa traded among traders 47Figure 4.3 Marketing channel of coffee 49Figure 4.4 Marketing channel of rice 52Figure 4.5 Volume distribution of rice traded among traders 54Figure 4.6 Marketing channel of dried kernel maize 55Figure 6.1 Weekly price of urea (Rp/kg) in 2003 81Figure 6.2 Weekly prices of NPK (Rp/kg) in 2003 83Figure 6.3 Weekly price of cocoa (Rp/kg) in January- December 2003 85Figure 6.4 Weekly FOB (Rp/kg) from Palu shipping port in 2003 85Figure 6.5 Weekly producer price of coffee (Rp/kg) in January -

December 2003 in 86

Figure 6.6 Weekly producer price of cimandi rice (Rp/kg) in January -December 2003

89

Figure 6.7 Weekly consumer price of cimandi rice (Rp/kg) in January-December 2003

89

Figure 6.8 Weekly producer price of IR 66 super rice (Rp/kg) in January -December 2003

91

Figure 6.9 Weekly consumer price of IR 66 super rice (Rp/kg) in January -December 2003

91

Figure 6.10 Weekly consumer price of sugar (Rp/kg) in January-December 2003

94

Figure 6.11 Weekly consumer price of super cooking oil (Rp/kg) in January-December 2003

95

Figure 6.12 Weekly consumer price of medium cooking oil (Rp/kg) in January-December 2003

97

vi

Page 10: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

List of Abbreviations

ANOVA = Analysis of Variance AR = Autoregressive ARCH = Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity CV = Coefficient of Variation FGLS = Feasible Generalized Least Squares kg = Kilogram LLNP = Lore Lindu National Park OLS = Ordinary Least Squares Rp = Rupiah STORMA = Stability of Rain Forest Margin TGMM = Total Gross Marketing Margin

vii

Page 11: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

1. INTRODUCTION

1.1 Background

Agriculture is one of the most important sectors of the Indonesian economy. In

Central Sulawesi Province, the agricultural sector makes an important contribution to

the regional economic development. In 2001, it generated 48% of the gross regional

domestic product. Food crops and cash crops were 15% and 22%, respectively

(Central Sulawesi Bureau for Statistics, 2003). Rice is the most important crop in the

food crops category and cocoa in the cash crops category.

Most of people who live in rural villages depend on agricultural activities as essential

sources for generating livelihoods. In the vicinity of Lore Lindu National Park,

Central Sulawesi as a focus of research area, integration of small farmers in the

agricultural markets, including export market (in this case for cocoa) plays for rural

livelihoods. Research of STORMA (Stability of Rainforest Margins) sub project A4

in 2001-2002 found that in the research area the most important source of income for

rural household is mainly based on agricultural activities: crop income, livestock

income, and income from employment offered in the agricultural sector. On average,

the three agricultural income sources account for 62% of the total household income.

From the three activities, income from cropping activities accounts for 45% of the

total household income and 92 % of all households has income from crops. The most

common crops grew by the households in the research area are wetland rice, maize,

cocoa and coffee. Rice and maize are used for home consumption as well as for sale,

while cocoa and coffee are mainly sold (Schwarze, 2004).

To improve the standard of living particularly for people who engage in agricultural

activities, agricultural and rural development should be taken place regarding to some

factors. According to Zeller and Minten (2000), in order to generate income, the rural

households combine two different factors, internal and external. Internal factor is

household resources that consist of physical capital, human capital and social capital.

External factors are access to financial market, agricultural input and output markets,

and land market, as well as the price and transaction cost in those markets.

1

Page 12: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

There are specific challenges of marketing in the agricultural sector due to the

characteristics of agricultural products such as raw material, bulky and perishable,

quality variation, seasonal variability in production, geographic concentration of

production, and varying cost of production. All those characteristics give rise to

market failures in the economy. Market failure refers to the situation in which market

fails to attain economic efficiency.

Moreover, agricultural markets in developing countries are often characterized by

inadequate physical and marketing infrastructure, information asymmetry among

producers and traders, and entry barriers. These factors contribute to high transaction

costs which can cause arbitrage failure and lead to inefficient allocation of resources

(McNew, 1996). Arbitrage failure refers to the situation where spatial price

differences exceed the transaction cost and other transfer cost involved in moving

good between the two markets (Park, et al., 2002). Summarized from many

literatures, Sexton, et al. (1991) found that the failure may be occurred due to

impediments to efficient arbitrage, such as trade barriers, imperfect information, or

risk aversion.

High transport cost and low agricultural productivity are also found in agricultural

market in developing countries, therefore rural food markets can be thin and isolated.

Consequently, farmers are confronted with food prices that are volatile and highly

correlated with their own agricultural output (Fafchamps, 1992).

Performance of agricultural input and output markets are as important as access for

the farm households to those markets. The access for the farm households to markets

can be proxied by the presence of infrastructure and market institutions. Following

Wanmali (1992) rural infrastructure can be divided into three different categories,

soft, institutional and hard infrastructures. Soft infrastructure consists of

transportation vehicles, communication and information, input distribution, marketing

and financial services. Government agencies, cooperation and trader organisations

are included as institutional infrastructure. Hard infrastructure is the presence of

physical facility such as roads, electricity and irrigation system.

2

Page 13: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Price has important role. For the farm producers, price contains information on

expected income as well as investment planning. The same situation as expected

income and investment planning is what price guided to the traders. What crops to

buy, where to buy and to sell, when to buy and to sell are some considerations to

make purchase, sale and investment decisions. Consequently, high variability of

prices can have unfavourable impact on both producer and consumer, threaten farm

incomes, prevent producers from making investment in agriculture, and eventually

drive resources away from agriculture. Thus, price variability can be a serious

concern for producer, traders and consumers alike.

Overcoming these problems for market development in a way that avoids

disadvantages to the farm households is a major challenge, therefore it is important to

study agricultural input and output markets, producer prices and its variability in

terms of space and time and as well as the factors influencing them. Besides, as

producer for most agricultural commodities who are greatly influenced by the price of

the agricultural output being produced and sold, farm households are consumers of

basic food items such as rice, sugar, vegetable oil and as well as fertilizer for

agricultural input. Obviously, the welfare situation of the households and the ability

to purchase consumer goods are affected by the consumer prices and its variability.

Therefore, it is also necessary to observe consumer price level and its variability

across the space and time.

With respect to the importance of agricultural development in accelerating overall

regional economic development, market, marketing process and infrastructures are

some aspects that should be developed in the agricultural sector. Therefore, an

improved knowledge of the agricultural input and output markets and the patterns of

price variability and some factors behind those would give additional information for

policy makers in providing a favourable policy environment for the whole society,

farm producers, intermediate agents and consumers.

3

Page 14: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

1.2 Research questions and objective

The objective of this study is to analyse structure, conduct and performance of the

agricultural input and output markets and to measure variability in agricultural input

and output prices across time and space. The study will analyse agricultural inputs,

outputs but also some basic food items.

The study is expected to give answers to the following questions:

• How are the agricultural commodities markets being organized? Is the

agricultural commodities trade composed of many small traders, who compete

with each other or is it dominated by few large participants?

• Are there any barriers to market entry? If so, what are the major barriers?

Which can be altered by policy, e.g. with respect to legal framework?

• What approaches do the traders use in selling, buying and pricing activities?

• What is the role of producer associations (cooperatives) or trade associations for

marketing of agricultural input and output?

• To what extent do the communities have access to agricultural input and output

markets?

• What is the marketing margin i.e. differences between producer price and the

retail price paid by consumers and within the agents in the marketing chain?

• What are the patterns of price variability of agricultural commodities in term of

time and space? Do villages with lower access to market have lower producer or

higher consumer prices? Do villages with lower access to market have more

seasonal fluctuation?What are the policy implications of the findings to above

questions?

4

Page 15: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

1.3 Outline of the study

This study consists of seven chapters, divided into the following description. Chapter

1 presents background information on market and price of agricultural commodities.

Research questions and objective are formulated in this chapter.

Chapter 2 reviews some theoretical and empirical literature on market and price

analysis. The theories that are described in this chapter are agricultural marketing,

structure conduct performance paradigm, agricultural price variability and alternative

approaches to conduct market and price analysis. Some advantages and limitations of

the theories and are described as well.

Chapter 3 focuses on the detailed methodology used for analysis. The chapter

presents a sampling procedure, sources and different type of the data. The process of

data collection and weakness occurred during the data collection is described. Then, it

is continued by the explanation of entry and cleaning process to get reliable data for

analysis. The chapter ends with the focus on the descriptive and econometric analysis.

Descriptive analysis such as mean, standard deviation, coefficient of variation,

methods to compare means, gini coefficient and Lorenz curve, seasonal and spatial

price spreads are detail explained. Econometric analysis such as diagnostic and

testing procedure for time series data (unit root test) and ARCH (Autoregressive

conditional heteroskedastic) model are detail described. Then, based on the theories

presented in the previous chapter, conceptual framework is formulated at the end of

this chapter to guide further analysis.

Chapter 4 presents detailed analyses of the structure of agricultural input and output

markets. The structure of cocoa, coffee, rice, maize and fertilizer markets in the

research area is described in detail. The findings from survey of traders are used to

describe the marketing channels by which the agricultural outputs move from the

farm to local or urban consumers. Another issue focused on market structure is

barriers to market entry. Relating to the research question in chapter 1, this chapter

ends with a review of the structure of the agricultural markets.

5

Page 16: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Chapter 5 provides information about agricultural market conduct in the research

area. This chapter discusses general information about the profile of agricultural

traders and their business practises. In relation to the research question presented in

the chapter 1, this chapter ends with a summary of the conduct of the agricultural

markets.

Chapter 6 concentrates on the analyses of the performance of the agricultural market.

First section examines degree of access to market and infrastructures. Second section

analyses marketing margin and farmer’s share. Then it is followed by uncertainty,

break-even price and sensitivity analysis. Fourth section analyses seasonal and

spatial variability of prices. This section presents figures and tables on the price

movement and it allows us to compare between villages. Then, in the next section

the results of the econometric analysis on price variability are described. Regarding to

the research question in the chapter 1, this chapter ends with a summary of the

performance of the agricultural markets and the price variability.

With regard to the research question presented in the first chapter, chapter 7

concludes the results of this study and considers some policy implications from the

findings of the study.

6

Page 17: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

2. LITERATURE REVIEW

This chapter presents some theoretical and empirical literature on market and

price analysis. The theory of agricultural marketing, structure conduct

performance paradigm, alternative approaches of market and price analysis are

described.

2.1 Agricultural marketing

Agricultural marketing refers to the performance of all business activities

involved in the flow of products and services from the point of initial agricultural

production until they are in the hands of consumer (Kohls and Uhl, 1990).

Marketing can be seen as a transformation process of the commodity in time,

space and form (Kotler, 1994). Those three dimensions refer to the condition

where consumers are able to buy commodity at different time from its harvest and

consumption, different place from farmers field and in the different form which is

preferred to be consumed. Another function of agricultural marketing is

transmission of price signals between farmer producers and consumers (Timmer,

1986; Ellis, 1992).

All institutions involved in moving goods and transforming from producer to end

consumers depicts a marketing channel. Figure 2.1 presents marketing channel for

a typical agricultural commodity. Assemblers (rural collectors), processors,

wholesalers, and retailers collaborate with farmers in the forward flow of the

agricultural commodity from farm producers to consumers. The hourglass

configuration describes the facts that the commodity is concentrated into larger

quantities and fewer firms as it moves to processor and then is broken down into

smaller quantities as it moves to many retailer and even more consumers (Rhodes

and Dauve, 1998).

7

Page 18: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Flow of payments

Production Assembly Processing Wholesaling Retailing Consumption

Flow of product

Figure 2.1 Stages in a marketing system (Rhodes and Dauve, 1998).

Marketing functions in agricultural commodities begin on farm and in villages.

Farmer producers grow and harvest the crops either to be consumed by their

family or supplied to the next marketing agents.

Rural assembler is the first link between the farm producer and other middlemen.

The assembler has activities of purchasing commodity from the scattered rural

production and assembled at local village, or sub-district level, or processing firm.

Therefore, in addition to assembly, transport is another key function in the

marketing process provided by this type of trader.

Processing is a process of transforming commodity from prior to onward

distribution. The processing enterprises use the agricultural commodities as raw

material to be processed into different form of products which are preferred by

consumers.

Wholesaling is the changing hands of commodity in bulk. Wholesalers generally

establish their shops around towns and large cities that are connected by

infrastructure facilities. Then, wholesaler sell the commodity either to retailer, to

exporters or export directly to foreign markets (Ellis, 1992; Mendoza, 1995).

Retailer has basic function in distributing commodities to the final consumers,

particularly in petty trading.

The marketing channels vary considerably in complexity and length. It could be

very simple and directly from farmers to consumers in the local market. The

longest pattern occurs when the products move from the farmers to the final

consumers through all the marketing institutions. Each step within the channel has

an activity that enhances the usefulness of the product or in other words, each

agent performs marketing functions and adds value to the product. The nature of

8

Page 19: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

the product and the form in which preferred by consumers determine the variety

of the marketing channels.

There are features of agricultural products such as raw material, undifferentiated

products (which are usually referred to commodity), bulky, perishable, variation

in quality, seasonal variability in production, geographic concentration of

production, and varying cost of production, which determine marketing activities.

The characteristics of product and the functions that have been performed by the

agents to meet all the three dimensions (time, space, and form) influence price

formation. Moreover, the number of middlemen within the channel and the costs

of marketing services provided in assembling, processing, transporting and

retailing product and profit taken by each level would obviously affect the price

formation.

The difference price between any two participants in the marketing channel is

referred as marketing margin. A marketing margin may be defined alternatively

as (1) a difference between the price paid by consumers and that obtained by the

producers, or as (2) the price of a collection of marketing services that is the

outcomes of the demand for and the supply of such marketing services (Tomek

and Robinson, 1991). When there are some participants in the marketing channel,

the margin can be calculated at different levels.

In term of marketing activities, marketing margin contains a variety of costs with

respect to the marketing process. Marketing costs generally consist of traders

profit, wages, interest, rents and storage costs, transportation costs, processing

costs, other costs for assembling, processing, packaging and retailing activities

and as well as transaction costs. The marketing margins among commodities may

vary due to characteristic and perishability of the products, number of participants

in the marketing channel, costs occurred in the marketing process and

differentiation of marketing functions performed.

Farm producers are price takers, who have very limited control over prices

received for their products. Moreover, the price often exhibits variability, that is,

changes over the time. The variability could means losses or profit, hence it leads

to a great uncertainty. Uncertainty is important concept since it is found to reduce

9

Page 20: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

production, investment and consumption and thereby trade (Sandmo, 1971).

Therefore it is important to appraise the prices in the context of risk

circumstances.

The great bulk of analytical investigation of risk has been concerned with “pure

risk” that is, variation about some measures of “representative” performance such

as the mean. This measurement, however, can be applied when farmers are risk

neutral or indifference. It means that the farmers as decision makers can make

decision solely and comfortably on the basis of the mean or expected value of

pertinent uncertain quantities (Anderson and Dillon, 1992).

However, risk neutral is encountered very rarely to be found in decision makers,

most people are risk averse and generally farmers are risk averse. Evidence of

farmers risk aversion was found in many of their action, include work by Brink

and Mc Carl, Dillon and Scandizzo, Biswanger as had been summarized by

Robison and Fleisher (1984). Any form of risk aversion implies a preference for

low variability in income and thus in prices (Barret, 1996).

Because of risk aversion of most farmers, it may be argued that a concept of

downside risk is more relevant in analysis of risk in agriculture. Downside risk

can be defined as a shorthand description for situation in which any significant

deviation from the norm lead to worse outcomes (Anderson, et al., 1977;

Hardaker, et al., 1997). Downside risk is concerned with the “placement” of risk

in a distribution. One distribution is said to have more downside risk than another

if it has more dispersion below a specific target or if it more skewed to the left

(Menezes, et al., 1980).

Another approach to measure downside risk in farmer side is using graphical

representation of probability distribution (Anderson, et al., 1977). The S-shaped

cumulative distribution function (CDF) can be applied in the measurement of

down side risk. CDF may be defined as P (x ≤ X*), it means that the probability

that x is less than or equal to a particular value of X*.

Then, the CDF can be combined with sensitivity and break-even analysis. Since

farmers face risk that prices may lower than expected, calculation of the

probability that price is below break-even point and the acceptable declining of

10

Page 21: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

prices to cover costs of production is important to avoid losses. If price decrease

below the variable costs, it will hurt the farmer producers even in the short run.

Figure 2.2 shows a CDF with a hypothetical value of gross margin. The figure

illustrates the downside risk, which can be defined as probability of cases where

break-even point occurred or the gross margin equal to zero. As commodity price

takers, the farmers should develop marketing plans to obtain higher prices in order

to cover per unit total cost of production.

0.000

0.200

0.400

0.600

0.800

1.000

lessthan 0

0 1-100 101-200 201-300 301-400 401-500 501-600

Range in Gross Margin

Cum

ulat

ive

prob

abili

ty

Figure 2.2 CDF for the probability distribution of gross margin

Marketing margin can also be high because of high real marketing costs.

Frequently farm-retail margin are high because the transport system to major

urban retail markets is inefficient and costly. A study carried out by FAO in

assessing retail-farm gate margins for rice in Africa in 1985 reported that the large

differences between the marketing margins are primarily due to genuine

differences in the cost of delivering rice to retail markets rather than to innate

inefficiency and excess profits by the agents involved in the distribution chain.

The study recorded that road networks are not as intensive, transport services are

less frequent and more costly, and average haulage distances are greater (Colman

and Young, 1997).

11

Page 22: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Marketing margins also show some extent of the market structure. Imperfect

competition will generate high marketing margin because of abnormal profit taken

by traders. Degree of competitiveness in the markets generally affects the extent

of trader’s profit, transaction costs, and price transmission between markets

(Minten, 1999).

Another approach to observe marketing margin is price spread. The price spread

can be classified into spatial and temporal dimensions (Ahmed and Rustagi,

1987). First category of spatial spread is price spreads between producer and final

consumers of a product market, also known as farmer’s share. It represents a

category in which the marketing margin is equivalent to the spread in prices at the

two ends. The other category of spatial spread reflects the differences in prices at

various regional markets at a particular time. The marketing margin and spatial

price spread are the same where (a) the two price points are integrated by a

functioning market or trade link and (b) the law of one price holds between the

two regions (Sexton, et al., 1991; Baulch 1997).

With regard to the temporal dimension, there are two common types of the

spreads in agricultural prices. These are the annual variation (price fluctuation

between years) and the seasonal variation (within a year).

Ritson (1997) illustrates schematic categorization of issues in agricultural

marketing with respect to its problem, analysis and policy (see figure 2.3). Figure

2.3 shows that there are three kinds of problems in agricultural marketing,

different type of analysis and potential marketing policy to overcome those

problems. Arrows in the figure represent the main relationship among elements.

Three kinds of problems in agricultural marketing are market power, excessive

margin and price signals. A growing concentration of food manufacturing and

distribution allows the marketing sector to exploit market power to detriment of

the farm sector and perhaps also consumers. This power might be expressed in

the form of excess profit or efficiency losses due to the lack of competitive

pressure, but in either case would be viewed in agricultural marketing as

“excessive margin”. But in addition to the impact of market power, margins

might be excessive, so it is often believed, because of inefficiency in the structure

12

Page 23: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

and organization of the marketing sector. Third, much attention has been devoted

to the efficiency of the agricultural market price mechanism in communicating

information between farmers and consumers - in particular, the problems of price

instability obscuring useful price messages between consumers and producers,

and price cycles delivering false message to expand and contract production. In

addition there is the question of whether price formation reflects efficient relations

between markets over time and space, and the contribution of futures markets to

pricing efficiency (Ritson, 1997: 13).

Problems in agricultural marketing

Structure Efficiency

Problem Market Power Excessive margins Price signals

Analysis S-C-P Marketing margin ** Market price

Policy Marketing board, Market intelligence Trade and price Cooperatives and and grading controls Competition policy Figure 2. 3 Schematic categorization of issues in agricultural marketing **= ARCH Adapted from Ritson (1997) with additional information added by the author

Agricultural market analysis is divided into three categories, application of

structure-conduct-performance analysis, analysis of marketing margin and price

movement over time and space. In addition to those analyses, this study use

econometric ARCH model to observe price variability.

Potential marketing policies based on previous problems are legal measures such

as competition policy, price controls, formation of producer marketing group or

cooperatives to counterbalance the power and various activities to improve

marketing efficiency such as quality standard and grading.

13

Page 24: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

2.2 Structure – Conduct – Performance paradigm

Industrial organization is a subject of economic science. It concerns with the

functioning of markets, and in particular, the ways in which firms interact and

compete with each other. The S-C-P postulates that the market performance or

social welfare features of the equilibrium in the economy is determined by the

conduct of the firms, which in turn is determined by the structural characteristics

of the markets (Figure 2.4). This paradigm was first formalised by Mason (1939).

Afterwards, Bain (1956) modified S-C-P paradigm based on the neoclassical

theory of the firm.

Performance Conduct Structure

Figure 2.4 Relationship between structure, conduct and performance (Fergusson, 1994).

Market structure refers to the characteristics and composition of the organization

of a market, which influence strategically the nature of competition and pricing

within a market. The structure can be identified by considering (either jointly or

separately) the number and size distribution of seller-buyer (degree of market

concentration), competition, entry condition (degree of difficulty for new entrants

to enter the market), products differentiation, and the extent of firms are

diversified or integrated (Fergusson, 1994).

According to degree of competition, markets can be classified into three different

forms 1) a high degree of competition, also called perfect competition; 2)

monopoly; and 3) imperfect competition (Stiglitz, 1997). Monopoly is the most

extreme situation when only one firm supplies the entire market, therefore no

competition. The forms of imperfect market competition are oligopoly and

monopolistic competition. Oligopoly is a situation when there are few firms

supply the market and each worries about how rivals will respond to any action it

undertakes. Monopolistic competition is defined as many firms (more firms than

in oligopoly, but not enough for perfect competition) exist in the market and each

firm can ignore the reactions of any rivals.

14

Page 25: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

The market has a major role as an instrument in achieving balance between

demand and supply, price formation function and as well as resource allocation.

From neo-classical point of view, ideally, perfect competition market supposes to

generate efficient outcomes and lead to the maximum total contribution to

producers and consumers welfare, since both parties cannot influence the price

and profit or utility of each party is at pareto optimal condition (Janssen and van

Tilburg, 1997).

Economists use perfect competition as a standard benchmark for the assessment

of market efficiency. In the perfect competition, market is supplied by a large

number of firms for large number of buyers therefore no individual can influence

price. The firms provide relatively homogenous products so one firm is

essentially a perfect substitute for the other firms. There are no artificial

restrictions on demand, supply or prices, such as government intervention or

collusion among firms. Mobility of resources and products exists in the economy

i.e. free of market entry barriers for a new firm (Tomek and Robinson, 1991). All

suppliers and consumers have perfect information, therefore perfect foresight and

market is certainty. However, actual market performance and its welfare impact

depend critically on how efficiently markets generate and transmit price signals

and how efficiently marketing activities are carried out (Timmer, 1986).

The basic principle behind the SCP paradigm is the perfect competition and

monopoly which are viewed as opposite ends of a spectrum of market structures

along which all market lie (essentially the models of perfect competition,

monopoly and monopolistic condition together with the various models of

oligopoly).

Mellor (1969) observed that in low-income countries substantial market

imperfections were found. The imperfect competition may be resulting from high

degree of barriers to market entry due to underlying technical and demand factors

such as unequal access to capital and information, inadequate size of market for

an economically viable competition, product differentiation, and natural factors.

In most developing countries, the typical agricultural marketing system is

characterised by a highly atomistic production side, in which there are numerous

15

Page 26: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

farmers growing perishable crops on small farms dispersed all over the country

side; and by an oligopoly market, where there are few traders (Kahlon and

George, 1985; Mendoza and Rosegrant, 1995). In addition, for some agricultural

products monopoly seems to be important features due to creation of state trading

organisations often called marketing boards (Colman and Young, 1997). Another

type of market imperfection in agricultural commodities arises from the

inadequate development of marketing infrastructure leading to costly and

uncertain costs involved in marketing process (Kahlon and George, 1985).

The most frequently used approach to measure market structure is market

concentration. Market concentration refers to number and size market distribution

of sellers and buyers in the market. Differences in the number and size

distribution of firms are key factors distinguishing the theoretical models of

competition in the market. Moreover, concentration can illustrate the degree of

market power. Concentration contributes to the firm behaviour within the market

due to its impact on interdependence action among firms.

The concentration shows the extent to which production or marketing of a

particular good or service is confined to a few large firms. The fewer the number

of firms and/or the more disparate their sizes, the more concentrated (and – the

implication is – the less competitive) the market (Fergusson, 1994:38-40).

Measures of market concentration seek to transform the information on the

number and size distribution of firms into a single value. Some are absolute

measures which combine the number of firms present and their size disparities.

With one exception (the concentration ratio) these consider all the firms in a

market, that is, they are summary measures. Relative concentration measures, in

contrast, focus on the effectively ignored differences in the number of firms

present. It is generally argued that the higher market concentration (the market is

more concentrated) and the more unequal the size distribution of firms and imply

less competitive behaviour and thus inefficiency. However, it is also notified the

critical interpretation of such relationship in isolation from other determinant

factors like barrier to market entry and economies of scale (Scott, 1995).

The four main absolute measures are:

16

Page 27: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

1. Concentration ratio (CRx)

This measures the cumulative market share of the largest X firms (ranked in

descending order size) in the market. The typical values of X are 4, 8, and 20.

The most frequent choice is the CR4 (the four-firm concentration ratio), that is the

sum of the market share of the largest four firms in the market. Kohls and Uhl

(1990) suggest that the CR4 has less or equal to 33% indicating a competitive

market structure, the concentration ratio of 33% to 50% and above 50% may

indicate a weak and strong oligopsonist market structure, respectively.

This measure is widely used in empirical studies, however it reveals some

limitations (Waldman and Jensen, 1998). First, since CRx describes the

percentage of market share held by a specific number of firms, changes in market

share outside the largest firms will not affect the CRx. Second, CRx provides no

information about the distribution of market shares among the top firms.

2. Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI)

This is defined as the sum of the squares of the market shares (output of the firm

divided by total output) of all firms in the market. This method shows an

advantage compared to the CRx, whereas data on all firms in the market are used

in the calculation. This point leads economists to prefer the HHI to simple

concentration ratio such as CR4 (Pepall, et al., 2002). However, the HHI is very

sensitive to the market share of the largest firms, due to the squaring of market

shares.

3. Hannah and Kay Index (HK)

The formula is almost similar to the HHI, instead of squaring, the market shares

are raised to the power α.

4. Entropy index

Market shares are weighted by the logarithm of the market shares.

The examples of relative concentration measures are:

1. Variance of the logarithms of firm size.

2. Gini coefficient which is derived from the Lorenz curve.

The Gini coefficient measures degree of concentration of a variable in a

distribution. It compares the Lorenz curve of an empirical distribution with

17

Page 28: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

perfect equality line (the 45o line). The value of the Gini coefficient ranges

between 0, where there is no concentration (perfect equality) and 1, where the

concentration is full (perfect inequality). With regard to its limitation, Gini

coefficient does not have unique value. It means that one or the same Gini

coefficient might arise from two different Lorenz curve1.

Considering the advantages and weakness of the approaches, this study applies

concentration ratio (CR4) and Gini coefficient which is derived from the Lorenz

curve to measure market concentration. The reasons are: (1) this measure combine

graph and values; (2) not only consider the largest four but also all firms in the

market; and (3) distribution of market share or sales can be seen from the graph.

According to Bain (1956) there are some elements of market structure that act as

barrier to market entry. The concept of barrier to entry can be defined as any

factors or market conditions that place potential new firms at a competitive

disadvantage with incumbent firms, thus it prevents the new firms to long run

entry into a market. According to this definition, a barrier to entry exists if a new

firm cannot achieve the same level of profits after entry that an established firms

earned before entry occurred (Waldman and Jensen, 1998). Three main types of

barrier to entry are: economies of scale, absolute cost advantages, and product

differentiation. Economies of scale or increasing return to scale can be defined as

a condition when a proportionate increase in all inputs results in a more than

proportionate increase in output (Stiglitz, 1997). In this case, with constant per-

unit input prices, long run average costs decrease as the quantity of output

increases. It acts as a barrier to entry in situation where there is a potential effect

of entry (due to increasing output in the market) on the market price of the

product. Control over crucial inputs, products protected by patents, access to

superior resources or production technologies or lower cost finance are sources of

absolute cost advantage. Product differentiation can act as barrier because it gives

individual producers some market power. Existing producers with differentiated

products have built up consumer goodwill and can raise its price without loosing

all consumers.

1 Refer to lecture scripts of Dr. Bernhard Bruemmer

18

Page 29: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Conduct is the patterns of behaviour, which enterprises follow in adapting or

adjusting to the markets in which they sell (or buy). It focuses methods employed

to set prices, whether independently or in collusion with others in the market,

sales promotion (advertising), and coordination policies and the extent of

predatory or exclusionary tactics directed against established rivals or potential

entrants.

In the case of perfect competition market when the concentration is relatively low,

there will be no personal contact in setting prices. Different from the perfect

market, oligopoly market has medium to high degree of concentration, collusive

behaviour within the firms in the market is likely be taken place.

Performance represents the economic results of structure and conduct, which

concerns to the question whether or not the firms operation enhance economic

welfare to the economy. It emphasizes the performance of the marketing system

as a whole. The performance is commonly measured in terms of productive and

allocative (economic) efficiency. In a broad sense innovation (progressiveness),

equity and employment creation are also considered as performance assessment

Several indicators can be utilized to assess market performance are stability of

price and marketing margin or spread prices, costs and volume of output, net

returns, farmer’s share of retail price and proportion of consumer’s income which

has been spent. Price efficiency also utilized to analyse market in its dimensions

of space and time (Pomeroy and Trinidad cited from Scott, 1995). Other

measurements can be utilized to assess market performance by applying degree of

market integration, relationship between transfer costs and inter-market price

differences, and relationship between seasonal price and storage costs to indicate

market competitiveness through time (Harris cited from Abbot, 1993).

Nevertheless, essential purpose of evaluating performance of a marketing system

might be thought as how well the system performs what society and the market

participants expect of it (Crawford, 1997). Consumers are likely to evaluate a

marketing system in terms of its performance in avoiding high and instability

prices. Farmers concern on accessibility of marketing infrastructure at reasonable

cost and factors influencing prices as well. Society is likely to give consideration

19

Page 30: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

to the marketing system’s contribution to employment. Government will take into

account contribution of marketing system on employment, investment, and

economic growth.

The most important hypothesis generated by the structure-conduct-performance

school of thought is that as market structure moves away from perfect

competition, market efficiency will decrease (Jabbar, et al., 1997; Dessalegn, et

al., 1998).

2.3 Alternative approaches of market analysis

Several authors focus on industrial organization theory to analyse the efficient

markets. Industrial organization framework suggests a relationship among

structure, conduct, and performance of the market namely S-C-P paradigm.

However, according to some literatures here are some major problems faced in

empirical application of S-C-P paradigm (Jabbar et al, 1997). The problems are:

1) under some circumstances, a given structure may not lead to theoritically

anticipated conduct and performance; 2) industrial organization studies focussed

maily on structure and performance, mush less attention has been given on

conduct due to data and measurement problems and underdeveloped nature o the

theory on conduct; 3) market performance depends not only on relationships

among similar firms but also on different categories firms in the marketing

environment.

Based on typology developed by Knudsen (cited from Fergusson, 1994), The S-C-

P focus its analysis on the decision makers with the main interest is in how these

groups interact and respond to changes in market circumstances. Another

assumption is the price system is the only explicitly modelled device that is

identified as a means for co-ordinating different activities. Implicitly, it stated

that there are no costs associated with the use of the price-mechanism or

transaction costs are zero.

The industrial organization theory seems to be incomplete since it basically limits

the study on price mechanism (based on assumptions of neo-classical economics)

and there was found also some empirical deficiencies. Therefore, there are also

20

Page 31: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

some alternative approaches to market analysis, such as transaction cost

economics (Williamson, 1975), institutional economics, or commodity system

analysis.

In addition, the collection of primary data on market structure, conduct and

performance has often been substituted by a heavy reliance on the analysis of

secondary price series data. The analysis of market performance has often been

limited to market efficiency analysis based on price integration parameters, such

as market integration or low of one price (Jansen and van Tilburg, 1997).

The SCP analysis according to Jansen and van Tilburg (1997), can be a good

starting point for the analysis of marketing system. However, it will be better if

the analysis is complemented by analytical approaches which take into account

the development of the marketing system in the economy.

Considering advantages and limitations of the presented theories and empirical

literatures in previous sections, this study applies the SCP analysis and is

complemented by analysis of price series data.

2.4 Agricultural price variability

This section describes some sources and implications of price variability.

Seasonal and spatial price variability are separately explained. Several methods to

measure price variability are reviewed in the next sub section. This sub section

ends with the selection of appropriate model used in this study.

2.4.1 Sources and implications of seasonal and spatial price variability

Agriculture sector in Indonesia contributed 19.6% and 17.2% to total gross

domestic product in 1999 and 2000, respectively (World Bank, 2005). Although

the agricultural sector is declining component of Indonesian economy, agricultural

product prices remain important economically and politically. Agricultural

commodity prices, their levels, variability and its determinants are of central

importance in the agricultural sector. Price is important determinants for farm

income, cost of food for consumers, important determinants of consumer welfare,

21

Page 32: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

export earnings for countries engaged in commodity trade, and profit for

agricultural marketing traders.

Market condition and all the market forces through supply and demand conditions

of agricultural commodities potentially affect the price formation and its

variability. Comparing to other non-farm goods and services, agricultural

commodity prices are more volatile. Increasing agricultural price variability can

have detrimental impacts on both producer of agricultural commodities and

consumers (Binswanger and Rosenzweig, 1986; Sahn and Delgado, 1989). The

price variability also undermines traders and processors incomes and the income

transfer among market participants.

In general, price variability can be classified into two different dimensions.

Different regions (spatial dimension) and different point of time (seasonal

dimension) are considered.

Seasonal price variability

The nature of agricultural commodities is that the production patterns have

seasonal character, while consumption is more or less stable throughout the year

leads the prices to be seasonally volatile. Seasonal price differences refers to all

aspects of storage i.e. storage costs due to seasonal variation in production

(supply) and demand. Other factors that are considered influence seasonal

variability are trader’s profit and transaction costs, including risk premium

(Ahmed, 1988).

Minten (1999) reported that two reasons could be invoked for seasonal price

movement in Madagascar, the cost of capital (Badiane, et al., 1997; Zeller, 1993)

and non-competitive market practices (Alderman and Shively 1996; Sahn and

Delgado 1989).

The patterns of production and storage tend to stimulate prices are lowest at

harvest and post-harvest time in rural areas and the commodities may flow from

these areas to urban areas. The prices will be higher in lean season when harvest

period approaches. The prices in urban area have the same patterns, they are also

seasonal but fluctuations are dampened. These are distressingly common

22

Page 33: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

characteristics of low-income economies phenomenon of seasonal flow reverse

direction as the harvest approaches again and rural farm household exhaust stocks

and become food buyer (Barret, 1996). In this season, prices in rural areas

become higher compared to prices in harvest and post-harvest periods. This

phenomenon results from urban concentration of storage, including of imported

transactional stocks, and from seasonal net demand in producing area (Timmer

1986; Barrett 1996; Minten 1999).

Spatial price variability

Again, the nature of many agricultural commodities are geographic concentration

in production, even remoteness of the farm producers to final consumers will

affect flow of the commodities and costs involved in moving the commodities

from the surplus to the consumer area. This feature means that presence of

infrastructure facilities such as roads and market site will influence price levels

and its variability. Taking the case of Madagascar, it is found that spatial

variability between communities is linked to the distance to a paved road, quality

of the road, access to soft infrastructure (measured by access to credit,

information, security and agricultural inputs) and degree of competition between

traders (Minten, 1999).

In most cases, price levels and its variability in spatial dimension can be explained

by transportation cost, including normal traders profit, transaction costs and other

transfer costs involved in moving goods from location of sale to final purchase.

Study in Madagascar found that high transportation and transaction costs lead to

significant spatial price variation for inputs and levels of outputs (Zeller and

Minten, 2000).

2.4.2 Analysis of commodity price variability

This sub chapter reviews several methods to measure price variability. This sub

chapter ends with the selection of appropriate model to be used in the analysis.

First measure of price variability is monthly price indexes. It calculates difference

between the lowest and highest monthly indexes. The average spread in seasonal

prices can be measured by the lowest price as a percentage of the highest prices.

23

Page 34: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Second approach, which is more comprehensive than price indexes, is descriptive

statistics. It measures the characteristics of distribution of price in levels and

period-to-period changes. Mean, and standard deviation are basic statistics as

measurement of central tendency and dispersion of the data. Although the

standard deviation can be used as a measure of variability, comparing directly two

or more standard deviations can lead to falsely conclude the results. Besides

depend on the value of mean, the standard deviation of the different unit

measurements cannot be compared. To solve this fault, coefficient of variation, as

a relative measurement can be applied.

Since the coefficient of variation is unit free, it facilitates comparisons of price

changes in different directions across different periods of time and for different

commodities. Although this measurement provides some information on the

nature of price variability, it ignores the dynamic properties of prices.

In time series data, there are some characteristic movements or components of

information that should be addressed before attempting to use the data for

prediction. Often the time series data can be broken down into four different basic

components: (1) a long-term movement (sometimes called trend, T). Many

economic time series have a common tendency of growing overtime or at least

over certain periods have downward trends; (2) a cyclical component (C); (3) a

seasonal movement (S). If a time series is observed at weekly or monthly intervals

it may exhibit seasonality, there is a recurring pattern or seasonality within each

year; (4) a random, error or irregular component: this movement is basically just

noise.

The difference between a cyclical and a seasonal component is that the latter

occurs at regular (seasonal) intervals, while cyclical factors usually have a longer

duration that varies from cycle to cycle. The random component is a small scale

variations that are not accounted for by long-term, cyclic, or seasonal movements

(Makridakis, et al., 1998; Wooldridge, 2003).

As it is known that the time series data may consist of the four movement

components, those behaviors should be accounted for before using the data for the

further prediction. Those characteristics should be recognized because ignoring

24

Page 35: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

the components i.e. the series are trending can lead us to falsely conclude the

analysis. Decomposition and adjustment is purposed to isolate those components,

that is, to de-compose the series into the trend effect, seasonal effects, and

remaining variability. Adding a time trend in the regression analysis will eliminate

the trending problem. If the series are seasonally not adjusted yet, a set of seasonal

dummy variables is included to account for seasonality either in dependent or

independent variables.

The weekly-collected price series in this research covered one-year period or the

number of observations are around 52, the underlying components in the data

cannot be clearly observed. Therefore, the series are not decomposed and it

straightforwardly used into the analysis.

Another method to calculate price variability is using an econometric model to

overcome possible weaknesses from previous approaches. Before estimating the

data using econometric time series model, diagnostic checking should be

conducted in order to satisfy the requirements of assumptions in the time series

analysis. The time series data should be stationary, that means its mean, variance

and covariances remain constant over time. The term non-stationary refers to the

condition when one of the characteristics of stationary cannot be satisfied. Non-

stationary time series data indicates the variances are infinite and implies that least

square estimation will not be valid and inferences derived from the results are

highly suspect. Unit roots test is the main techniques to test the stationarity of the

data. One of the several possible methods to conduct unit root test is Dickey

Fuller (D-F) test.

Time series data are that often exhibit the phenomenon of volatility clustering,

that is, periods in which their prices show wide swing for an extended time period

followed by periods in which there is relative calm (Gujarati, 2003). Systematic

behaviour of prices are usually in form of the “today” prices level may be

correlated with “yesterday” price or even “prices two days ago”. It implies that

“today’s variability” may be correlated with “previous days variability”. ARCH

(Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity) model that was introduced by

Engle (1982) can be applied to circumvent the tendency of price changes, which is

25

Page 36: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

frequently associated with the clustering of price changes. In this model,

conditional variance of error term at time t depends on the squared error term in

the previous time period. The variation from the ARCH model is GARCH model

(Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity), proposed by

Bollerslev (1986). The ARCH model can be generalized to the GARCH model

by adding conditional variance in the previous time period in the right hand side.

Shively (1996) measured some descriptive statistics such as coefficient of

variation, skewness and kurtosis as a picture of maize price variability. The results

confirmed that the wholesale maize price in Ghana during 1978-1993 were

volatile. However, different results were obtained from the formal analysis of

maize price levels and its variances using econometric ARCH model. The

previous calculations using descriptive statistics were incorrect and could not be

verified.

Moreover, the use of the ARCH model circumvents many of limitations of

previous studies that employed the industrial organization paradigm of market

structure, conduct and performance, and the methods of price spread analysis and

bivariate price correlation that have been utilized in evaluating market

performance (Mendoza and Rosegrant, 1995).

Recent studies by Aradhyula and Holt (1988, 1989, 1990), Han, Jansen and

Penson (1990), Yang, Koo and Wilson (1992), Barret (1995, 1997), Mendoza and

Rosegrant (1995), Shively (1996) adopt the ARCH/GARCH to estimate

variability in agricultural series data.

In this research seasonal price spread, coefficient of variation and ARCH model

are used in the analysis of price variability.

2.5 Summary

This chapter reviewed the theoretical and empirical literature on market and price

analysis of agricultural commodities. This review guides the formulation of

hypotheses and the conceptual framework. The conceptual framework is the

foundation to guide the further analysis.

26

Page 37: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Starting with the concept of agricultural marketing, this sub chapter review some

aspects related with the concept of marketing in general term and particularly in

agricultural commodity. Marketing channel for typical agricultural commodity

and intermediary agents involved in the marketing process are explained.

Due to their position as price takers, farmer producers face risk that the price

received is lower than expected. The measurement of downside risk to calculate

the probability that price is below break-even point and the acceptable declining

of prices to cover costs of production is important.

In order to analyse how well a market performs its functions, structure conduct

performance (SCP) paradigm which is highly depend on the collection primary

data can be applied. The SCP postulates that the structural characteristic of a

market determines the conduct of the firms in that market and in turn will

determine the market performance. The basic principle of the SCP is the perfect

competitive and monopoly which are viewed as opposite ends of a market

structure. Imperfect competition such as monopolistic competition and oligopoly

lie in between the two ends. Although there are some limitations in the SCP

analysis, this approach is good starting point for the analysis of marketing system.

To carry out market analysis, this study use structure conduct performance

paradigm, and it is combined with the analysis of time series data to observe the

seasonal and spatial variability in agricultural prices. The next chapter deals with

the methodology used for the analysis throughout the study.

27

Page 38: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

3. METHODOLOGY

This chapter focuses on the detailed methodology used to answer the research

questions. After presenting a sampling procedure, sources and different type of

the data, process of data collection, weakness occurred during the data collection,

entry and cleaning are described. Then, it is continued by the explanation of the

descriptive and econometric analysis. Descriptive analysis which contains mean,

standard deviation, coefficient of variation, methods to compare mean (t-test and

ANOVA), Gini coefficient and Lorenz curve, seasonal and spatial price spreads

are described. Econometric analysis which is started from diagnostic and testing

procedure for time series data such as unit root test and then it is followed by the

explanation of ARCH model are detail described. This chapter ends with

conceptual framework which is formulated based on the theoretical and empirical

literature to guide the analysis of the whole study.

3.1 Description of the study area

The research areas are villages located in the forest margin of the Lore Lindu

National Park (LLNP). The LLNP is situated in Central Sulawesi Province,

Indonesia. This research covers 8 villages in 3 subdistricts and provincial capital

city (Palu) as a central market of agricultural commodities (Table 3.1).

Table 3.1 Survey villages of the study

Research area Subdistricts Villages

Sigibiromaru Maranata Pandere Sidondo II Palolo Sintuwu Berdikari Rahmat Kulawi Bolapapu Tomado Municipality of Palu (central market)

28

Page 39: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

3.2 Sampling procedure, data collection, entry and cleaning For the analysis purposes, village and market survey was conducted through

STORMA survey. Besides Tomado, all survey villages are sub-sample in

STORMA project A4. These villages were randomly selected on the basis of the

STORMA sampling frame (Zeller, et al., 2002). Tomado is sub sample of

IMPENSO.

Primary data were collected through two types of questionnaires that had been

developed for different sources of information (village level survey and trader

survey). The village level survey was conducted through a continuous weekly

price survey of key agricultural inputs (Urea and NPK fertilizers) and major cash

and food crops as well as basic food items (see appendices). The data were

collected during January until December 2003.

The collected data consist of producer and consumer (retail) prices. Producer

prices represent prices at a primary market or farm-gate prices for cocoa, coffee

and different varieties of rice. Consumer or retail prices are prices at the final

consumers in each survey area. The retail prices that were gathered during time of

surveys were prices for fertilizers (urea and NPK), different varieties of rice,

sugar, cooking oil for two different qualities; super and medium.

The price data were collected in 8 villages and in addition the prices of the same

commodities were asked in Palu market. In each village and Palu, each

respondent was selected and asked to fulfill the price questionnaire at the same

day, for example on Wednesday every week. In order to facilitate the process of

data collection, these selected respondents were the persons who permanently live

in those areas. Once in every month, the researcher or enumerator collected the

price questionnaires and brought them to STORMA office to be processed.

The process of data collection was designed to be effective and efficient, however,

in the real situation there were some weaknesses occurred. The respondents did

not write the questionnaires at the same day. It has some implications on the

analysis. If the respondents wrote the questionnaire at the same day during that

week, the price levels and its movements can be accurately compared. Chapter 6

shows this limitation. Graphs of prices show that the price movement for

29

Page 40: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

different commodities started from 1st until 52nd weeks in 2003. It represents the

price levels in the same week for all research areas but the day could be different

from one place to another.

The other drawback is weakness of monitoring during the fill in questionnaires

because of the lag time between writing the questionnaire up and the data

collection.

A case study of the structure and behaviour of agricultural traders was conducted

during September 2003 until January 2004 through trader survey. For this study,

trader samples were selected using snowball sampling procedure so as to capture

traders engaged in marketing of agricultural commodities in the research area.

The snowball sampling is one of the approaches that do not imply randomisation

and is considered to be non-probability sampling. Although it may suffer lack of

representativeness, that means there is no way of knowing whether the samples

are representative of the population, this method is used in studies of difficult-to-

find populations. When it is impossible to do probability sampling under real

research condition, non-probability sampling is used (Black, 1999; Bernard,

2000).

This research applies snowball sampling because the sampling frame or lists of

population of traders is not available in the research area. To construct a sampling

frame is impossible because of time consuming and too costly. Following

Bernard (2000), the procedure of snowball sampling was: (1) asking the village

headmen for the list of persons with desired characteristics i.e. involved in

agricultural trading and marketing; (2) once the preliminary list had been

available, it was showed to several traders who were on the list and asked them to

give names of others who they thought as appropriate subjects to be contacted and

should be on the list; (3) the process continued until the list became “saturated”,

that was, no new names were offered; (4) the trader samples were selected based

on different stage in the marketing chain. Since the snowball sample may suffer

lack of representativeness, all the results on the structure and behaviour of the

agricultural traders presented in this study cannot be as inferences about the

traders population in the research area.

30

Page 41: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

The questionnaire was developed to cover information on: general information

about trader such as age, sex, level of education, household size and composition;

various aspects of their marketing business such as product handled, type of

supplier, type of clients, geographical scope of trading operation, marketing

functions performed, and cost of marketing activities; their perception on the level

of competition and problems they deal with in undertaking their business.

Secondary data were collected to enrich knowledge of agricultural commodities

market in central Sulawesi. The main sources of secondary data were different

organizations at the regional level such as Agricultural offices, Trade and Industry

office, Customs office, and other government and private organizations.

The price and trader data were entered in SPSS files. To reduce the typing errors,

the entry is compared with the information in the questionnaires. After entering,

the data were cleaned to check the missing values, wild codes, inconsistencies and

extreme values.

3.3 Methodology used in descriptive analysis

The data are analysed using different software packages, SPSS, STATA 8.0 and

Limdep. Descriptive statistics are mostly calculated using SPSS software

package.

For the single data set (single time series) the most common descriptive statistics

are mean, standard deviation, and variance. The mean is a measure the center of

the data set. The standard deviation and variance are calculated to measure the

spread of the data. Coefficient of variation (CV) is defined as the standard

deviation divided by the mean. The coefficient of variation expresses the

dispersion of observed data values as a percent of the mean. All is used in this

study to describe access to market and infrastructures, and its relation with price

level and its variability.

Consumer goods flow from central market to villages. Relationship between price

of consumer goods in central market and price in villages is treated as additive

model. It can be found in the equations below:

31

Page 42: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Pc = Price in central market

Pr = Price in remote village

Tcr = Transportation costs

crcr TPP +=

crcr TPP += cr PP >

)(),()()( crcrrcr TVarTPCovPVarPVar ++=

if = constant crT )()( cr PVarPVar =

Coefficient of variation (CV) = µ

SD

cccc

cc PCVPVar

PPVar

CV === )()(

ccrc

cc

crc

c

r

rr CV

TPPCV

TPPVar

PPVar

CV ÷+

=+

==)()(

11 >+=+

=c

cr

c

crc

r

c

PT

PTP

CVCV

The equations show that the price of consumer goods will be higher and the

coefficient of variation will be lower in the remote village compared to those in

the central market.

In contrast to consumer goods, the flow of agricultural commodities (raw

materials) is started from villages to central market. The equations below show

that the producer price will be lower and the coefficient of variation of agricultural

commodity in the remote village will be higher compared to those in the central

market.

)(),()()( crcrrc

crrc

crrc

TVarTPcCovPVarPVarTPP

TPP

++=+=

+=

rc PP >

if = constant crT )()( cr PVarPVar =

32

Page 43: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

11

)()(

)()(

>+=+

=

÷+

=+

==

===

r

cr

r

crr

c

r

rcrr

rr

crr

r

c

cc

rrrr

rr

PT

PTP

CVCV

CVTPPCV

TPPVar

PPVar

CV

PCVPVarP

PVarCV

To observe differences in the mean between different groups, independent

samples t tests and Analysis of Variance (ANOVA) are applied. To compare

means of 2 groups, independent samples t is used and for more than 2 groups one-

way ANOVA is applied. Before proceeding the t test and ANOVA the SPSS

produce automatically Levene test statistic to calculate the equality (homogeneity)

of variances in the different groups. The distribution of the dependent variable for

one of the groups being compared must have the same variance as the distribution

for the other group being compared. The SPSS results on Levene test shows the

value that can be verified whether the value is significant or not. If the value is

not significant, it means that the assumption of homogeinity variance is not

violated. From this point, when the assumption of homogeneity can be assumed,

in independent t samples test we follow along the top line and the bottom line if

the assumption is violated.

Levene's statistic is also calculated for the variances in the ANOVA. If this value

is significant, it shows the evidence that the homogeneity assumption has been

violated. In this case, the analysis should be re-run by selecting option for "Equal

Variances Not Assumed".

To measure market concentration, concentration ratio (CR4) and Gini coefficient

are used. The concentration ratio (CR4) measures cumulative share of the largest

four firm (ranked in descending order of size) and is calculated as :

∑=

=x

iix SCR

1 where:

CRx = the X firm concentration ratio

Si = the percentage market share of the ith firm

33

Page 44: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Figure 3.1 shows a Lorenz curve for a hypothetic market. Here all the firms

(traders) are ranked by size and cumulated in ascending order. Then, it is plotted

against the cumulative percentage of output. The greater deviation of the curve

from the perfect equality line, the greater inequality in firm sizes. The Gini

coefficient summarizes this information into a single value.

Referring to Figure 3.1 Gini coefficient is estimated by comparing the area

between diagonal and Lorenz curve to the maximum possible triangle area

between diagonal and the curve.

Cumulated percentage of traders

100806040200

Cum

ulat

ed p

erce

ntag

e of

vol

ume

outp

ut tr

aded

100

80

60

40

20

0

Perfect equality

Lorenz curve

Figure 3.1 Lorenz curve (own illustration)

The Gini coefficient is calculated as2:

1

221 1

−+=

∑=

NC

N

ii

G

ν where:

N = number of observations (traders)

vi = cumulated percentage of market share (volume output traded)

2 lecture script of Dr. Bernhard Bruemmer

34

Page 45: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

The marketing margin is defined as a difference between the price paid by

consumers and that obtained by the producers. Therefore it can be used as an

approach to measure spatial price spread. Another parameter related to marketing

margin is the farmer’s share. It can be defined as the ratio of producer price to

consumer (retail) price or the portion of the price paid by final consumer that

belongs to the farmer producers.

Mathematically, the total gross marketing margin (TGMM) and farmer’s share

can be calculated through these formulas:

iceConsumerpriceFarmgatepriceConsumerprTGMM −

= ;

100×=iceConsumerpriceFarmgatepreFarmershar or

1001 ×−=iceConsumerpr

TGMMeFarmershar

Seasonal price spread can be seen from the peaks and troughs in plot of price

series and measured by the lowest price as a percentage of the highest price.

3.4 Methodology used in econometric analysis

STATA and Limdep software packages are used for measurement time series

model. Before conducting econometric analysis, some techniques are applied to

adjust and test some assumptions in the time series data.

The price series in this study are transformed into natural logarithm. It is useful to

minimize the increasing variation in the price series and it is more interpretable

compared to other transformations (Makridakis, et al., 1998). Changes in a log

value are relative (percent) changes on the original scale.

3.4.1 Diagnostic and Testing

Since time series analysis needs a stationary data, before using the data into the

analysis, the first step should be done is unit root test. Finding unit roots in the

35

Page 46: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

data set means that the price series are non-stationary. The technique used in this

study to find unit roots is Dickey Fuller test.

The Dicky-Fuller (DF) test is used to test whether the time series is a stationary

series, under the formula:

ttt uYY ++=∆ −11 lnln δβ (1) or

ttt uYtY +++=∆ −121 lnln δββ (2)

Where:

= Natural logarithm of the first differences in weekly prices tYln∆

1ln −tY = Lagged of natural logarithm of the weekly prices

t = time or trend variable

The null hypothesis (H0) is that γ = 0; that is, there is a unit root- the time series is

not stationary. The alternative hypothesis is that γ is less than zero; H1: γ < 0. It

means the time series is stationary. If the null hypothesis is rejected, the

dependent variable is found to be stationary. Taking first differences of a non-

stationary variable is often can remove the non-stationary problem. Then, the

stationary data will be used in the estimating of ARCH process.

The ARCH (Autoregressive conditional heteroscedaticity) model allows for the

presence of heteroskedastic variance. In order to determine the presence of

heteroskedasticity, a formal test for the present of ARCH should be applied. A

Langrange multiplier test statistic is used to test under null hypothesis of no

ARCH errors or the conditional variances are homoscedastic. The alternative

hypothesis is that the model follows an ARCH form, which means that the

conditional error variance is given by an ARCH(p) process or conditional

variances are heterokedastic.

In an autoregressive (AR) model, the realization of present´s outcome is a

function of past outcomes. Formally, autoregressive model of order p or AR(p) is

witten as:

tptpttt YYYY εαααα +++++= −−− ...21110

36

Page 47: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

The AR(p) model show the outcomes in the past p periods have a direct impact on

the present outcome. As shown in the equation, the outcome in period t-1, t-2,

until t-p directly affect the present outcome. Akaike Informaton Criterion (AIC)

is used to determine the lag length in the AR(p) model.

The test procedure to determine the presence of heteroskedasticity as proposed by

Engle [1982] is (1) run the original model for lnprice in the equation 5 using OLS;

(2) save the residuals from the regression; (3) regress the squared residuals on a

constant and p lagged values of the squared residuals as given in the equation (3).

( ) 2110

2 ˆˆ −+= tt aaE εε (3)

The null hypothesis is rejected if the test statistic exceeds the critical value from a

chi-square distribution with p degrees of freedom. A test statistic is calculated as:

T·R2 (4)

where R2 is obtained from the auxiliary regression of squared error (ε2 t ) and p

degree of freedom is equal to the number of autoregressive term in the auxiliary

regression.

3.4.2 ARCH model for price variability

The ARCH (Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity) model explicitly

models time varying conditional variances by relating them to squared error term

in the previous periods. Formally the ARCH (p) model estimated for agricultural

prices is given by equations (5) and (6),

(5) tpt

p

iit YY εββ ++= −

=∑ lnln

10

where :

tYln = Natural logarithm of the commodity weekly prices

1ln −tY = Lagged of natural logaritm of the weekly price

p = identification of autoregressive process (AR) using Akaike Information

Criteria (AIC)

tjt

p

jjt νεααε ++= −

=∑ 2

10

2 (6)

37

Page 48: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

The random schock, tε , conditional on all historical information contained in

information set ψt-1 is normally distributed with zero mean and follows an ARCH

process with conditional variances h2t:

tε ⏐ ( )tt hN ,0~1−Ψ

Procedure for estimating the ARCH(p) model is based on method of scoring

(Engle, 1982). In line with the scoring method, Greene (2000:798) proposed four-

steps procedure for estimating the ARCH (p). Let the sample consist of yt and xt

for t=1,…,T. The procedure involves the following steps3:

1. Compute b = (X’X)-1X´y and e = y – Xb using all T observations. This result is

the initial estimator of β. It is consistent and asymptotically normally distributed,

but inefficient.

2. Regress e2t on a constant and e2

t-1 to obtain a = (a0, a1)´ using observation 2, ….,

T. This method is the usual approach for consistent estimation of the variance

parameters in an FGLS (feasible generalized least squares) procedure.

Under null hypothesis of conditional homoscedaticity, (T–1) times the R2 in this

second regression is a Lagrange multiplier statistic whose limiting distribution is

chi-squared with one degree of freedom. This result can be used to test the

hypothesis of homoscedaticity against the alternative of the ARCH model.

3. Using (a0, a1) computed at step 2, compute ht = a0 + a1 e2t-1, gt = (e2

t/ht – 1), zt1

= 1/ht, and zt2 = (e2t-1/ht – 1) for observations 2, … , T. Collect T – 1 observations

in g = (gt)t=2,…T and Z = (zt1, zt2)t=2,…,T. Compute update dα = (Z´Z)-1Z´g. The

asymptotically efficient estimator of α = (α0, α1)´is α´ = a + dα. This estimator is

asymptotically normally distributed.

4. Re-compute ht for observations 2,…, T using α´ from step 3. Then, for

observation 2, …., T – 1, compute rt and st.

3 The procedure for estimating the ARCH model in this study is closely following Green (2000:798). Steps 1 and 2 are procedure to test homoscedaticity of error variance as discussed on the previous sub section.

38

Page 49: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−=

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+=

+

+

+

+

1ˆ1

ˆ21

1

21

1

1

2

1

1

t

t

ttt

t

t

tt

he

hhs

he

hr

α

α

let v = (etst/rt)t=2,…,T-1 and W = (rtx´t)t=1,…,T-1. Compute update dβ = (W´W)-1W´v.

Then, the asymptotically efficient estimator of β is β´= b+ dβ. This estimator is

asymptotically normally distributed.

3.5 Conceptual framework

The framework of industrial organization is used for market analysis. The

framework shows three main components that are structural characteristics of a

market (market structure), competitive behaviour of market participants (conduct)

and in turn structure and conduct influence performance of the market (Figure

3.2).

The first component of the framework is structure, which can be divided into three

types market whether highly competitive, monopoly or imperfect competition. In

order to define the structure, there are indicators will be applied such as marketing

channel, barriers to market entry, degree of competition and concentration.

Marketing channel is depicted by looking at different levels, started from farm-

level marketing to traders (market) level and final consumers.

Market conduct refers to buying and selling activities and pricing behaviour of

each participant in the market. Buying and selling activities comprises such as

sources of commodities, buying and selling practices. Pricing behaviour

comprises factors in price setting.

Structure and conduct will influence performance of the market, which can be

measured by indicators such as marketing margins of each levels in marketing

channel; variability in farm producer and consumer prices in term of time and

space, and down-side risk regarding to the variability of agricultural price

received. The dynamic of price is captured by ARCH model that is preceded by

some diagnostic and test for price series data. Dickey fuller test, ARCH LM tests

for the price series are applied.

39

Page 50: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Degree of competition: - Highly competitive - Monopoly - Imperfect competition (oligopoly or monopolistic competition)

Marketing channel

Barriers to market entry

Degree of concentration and

competition

STRUCTURE

CONDUCT

PERFORMANCE

Buying and selling activities

- Sources of commodities - Buying & selling

practices

Pricing behaviour

- Who sets price? - Factors in price

setting

Marketing margin

Farm gate and consumer price variability in term of space and time

Farm level marketing

Trader level marketing

Figure 3.2. Framework for market analysis (own depicted, 2003)

40

Page 51: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

3.6 Summary

This chapter presented methodology used to answer the research questions. For the

survey, 7 villages were selected from 12 villages (sub sample of STORMA sub

project A4), and one additional village was selected from sub-sample of IMPENSO.

For weekly price survey, the questionnaire was asked in those villages and to

compare the prices with the price in urban area, the same questionnaire was asked in

Palu (central market). For trader survey the sample was selected using snowball

sampling. This method is used because the sampling frame was not available. To

construct a sampling frame is time consuming and too costly.

There are various methods in descriptive and econometric analysis used to measure

structure and performance of agricultural markets in this study. Starting with the

calculation of mean, standard deviation, coefficient of variation, the analysis is

completed by the t test and Analysis of Variance (ANOVA) to compare the mean

between two or more different groups. Lorenz curve and Gini coefficient is used to

measure degree of concentration, which in turn shows some extent of competition and

structure of a market. Marketing margin, price spread and variability of prices in

term of seasonal and spatial are calculated to measure performance of agricultural

markets. This study use econometric approach to complement the measurement of

market performance by measuring variability of prices.

41

Page 52: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

4. AGRICULTURAL MARKET STRUCTURE

This chapter attempts to answer the research question as previously presented in the

chapter 1. The questions are (1) How are the agricultural commodities markets being

organized? Is the agricultural commodities trade composed of many small traders,

who compete with each other or is it dominated by few large participants? (2) Are

there any barriers to market entry? If so, what are the major barriers? Which can be

altered by policy, e.g. with respect to legal framework?

In relation to those research questions, this chapter deals with a discussion of the

structure of the agricultural markets. The market structure of each commodity is

separately discussed. In the next section the barriers to market entry is described.

This chapter ends with the summary of the structure of the agricultural markets.

4.1 Cocoa Market In contrast to many other agricultural commodities such as rice and sugar, which are

highly regulated by the government, cocoa market in Indonesia is relatively free from

government intervention. The market is open to private traders, without any

involvement of marketing boards or the National Logistics Agency. Price controls,

export quota, and exclusive trade licensing are not imposed in the cocoa industry.

Moreover, since the government promotes non-oil exports by removing export taxes,

cocoa market tends to grow (Akiyama and Nishio, 1996).

The cocoa market in Central Sulawesi works similarly to the previously described

conditions; it performs with limited intervention from local government. The local

government levies a “retribution” charge when cocoa is passes through certain

checkpoints during transport from producer areas to urban markets or shipping ports.

This is principally implemented with the aim of increasing regional income in

decentralization era.

Marketing of cocoa is basically started from villages, where village traders have a

direct relationship with farmer producers. In this research, 20 traders were

interviewed. These traders can be classified into village and sub district assemblers.

42

Page 53: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

The 18 village assemblers tend to operate in one village where they live. The 2 sub

district assemblers do their business in various villages within a sub-district.

Before it is ready to be marketed, cocoa beans must be prepared through post harvest

activities. To obtain good quality cocoa beans, the beans should be fermented and

dried after harvest. However, according to explanation from traders and some

farmers, it is common in the research area that cocoa beans are not fermented or are

partially fermented. Of course, this reduces quality and may, in turn, affect price

received.

Farmers cut the cocoa fruits and without the fermentation process the beans are then

spread out in a layer and dried under the sun to get dried beans. Sometimes cocoa is

partially fermented by chance particularly during the rainy season. This occurs when

there is a lot of rain and no sunshine. During this season, cocoa should be kept inside

the farmers` house, therefore accidental partial fermentation occurs.

Further explanations from traders and agricultural officers, attribute unwillingness to

ferment their cocoa due to market limitations for fermented cocoa. Even after

complete fermentation, there is no price differentiation paid by traders; hence there is

no incentive for farmers to ferment their cocoa beans.

Starting from the farmer, there are various marketing channels to sell dried cocoa

beans as can be seen in Figure 4.1 and characteristics of the traders involved in this

marketing system are presented in Table 4.1.

The term municipal assembler is introduced here since the wholesaler term is not

completely accurate. Technically speaking, a wholesaler handles huge amounts of

cocoa but in the research area when farmers bring small amount to this trader the

beans are received as well. Hence, the term municipal assembler is a substitute for the

wholesaler. From this point of sale, cocoa flows to exporters who will ship it to

importing countries. As shown in Figure 4.1 farmers can sell their cocoa either to

village assembler, sub district assembler or his agents. Farmers prefer selling the

beans in their village if amount cocoa beans sold are not big enough. When farmers

have at least one sack of cocoa beans (50 kg), they prefer sell directly to the

43

Page 54: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

municipal assembler in Palu. In marketing their cocoa, farmers from remote villages

will choose sub-district assemblers who operate near their villages. Without any

contractual obligations, farmers can decide to whom they sell their cocoa, and it

depends on the price offered by traders. However, prior to harvesting period when

lack of capital is faced by most farmers, some village or sub-district traders usually

provide loans to the farmers. As a consequence of the loan provided by the traders, it

is obligatory to sell the cocoa beans to these traders.

Farmer

Agents of sub- district assembler Village Assembler

Sub district assembler

Figure 4.1 Marketing channel o

Trading is the main occupation

of the village traders reported

occupation is self-employment

are cocoa farmers who grow c

own farm, most village asse

Municipal Assembler/

Wholesaler

Exporter

f cocoa

of all sub district and most village traders. Only 17%

that trading is a part-time business and their main

in agriculture. Furthermore, 78% of the village traders

ocoa on their own farm. Besides collecting from their

mblers collect cocoa from other farmers within the

44

Page 55: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

village, in order to resell it to sub district or municipal assembler. The village

assemblers conduct their business on a small-scale basis with an average volume

traded of 501 kg per month. The sub district assemblers handle large amount of cocoa

with an average volume traded of 10.875 kg per month.

Table 4.1 General characteristics of cocoa trader

Characteristics Village assembler

(N=18)

Sub district assembler

(N=2) Age (years) 40 52

Male 78 100 Gender (%) Female 22 0 Primary school 33 0 Secondary school 39 0

Highest level of school attendance (%)

High school 28 100 Trading as main occupation (%)

83 100

Average number of years in business

7 25

Family background in trading (%)

27 100

Agricultural crops traded (average no)

2 3

Cocoa producer (%) 78 50

Besides being older, the sub-district traders are also well educated and more

experienced, having spent much more time engaged in cocoa trade than the village

traders. On average, the sub district traders have been in the business for 25 years.

Furthermore, all of them come from families that have experience in cocoa trade.

Comparing to the level of education of total household sample in subproject A4, the

education level of cocoa traders is relatively higher. On average, 30.7% of the

household members completed secondary school and 12.4% completed high school

(Schwarze, 2004). Number of village traders completed secondary and high schools

are 39% and 28%, respectively. All sub-district traders completed high school.

45

Page 56: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

The village and sub district traders do not specialize on cocoa trading. The average

number of crops traded is at least two commodities and they usually manage a small

retail shop.

In order to obtain a supply of cocoa and to anticipate competition between traders,

particularly for big traders, there are important strategies that have been implemented

in conducting their business. For the procurement, these traders cannot depend solely

on farmers produce; growing cocoa on their own farms is necessary. Hiring itinerant

agents who work on a fee basis is another strategy. These agents have other

occupation as “ojek” that is, using a motorcycle for public transport. Hence, because

of their mobility, it is easy for them to collect and buy cocoa beans from farmers

within the village and in neighbour villages.

Market Concentration

Market concentration refers to the number and relative size distribution of traders in a

market. In this study, CR4, Gini coefficient and Lorenz Curve were used as measures

of market concentration. For the cocoa traders in the sample, the CR4 is 82 %. It is

indicating a strong oligopsonist market since the largest four traders accumulated

market share of 82% from total market share of cocoa traders in the sample. The Gini

coefficient is 0,78. When the value moves far from zero it indicates a high degree of

inequality of volume cocoa traded, the distribution of cocoa volume traded is un-

equal and market is more highly concentrated. As can be seen from the Lorenz curve

below, the largest 20% of the traders account for about 80% of the volume of cocoa

traded in the research area. The bottom 60% have an insignificant share of less than

10%. The rest of the traders account for the remaining cocoa traded.

46

Page 57: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Cumulated percentage of cocoa traders

100806040200

Cum

ulat

ed p

erce

ntag

e of

vol

ume

coco

a tra

ded

100

80

60

40

20

0

Perfect equality

Lorenz curve

Figure 4.2 Volume distribution of cocoa traded among traders

As indicated in the previous literatures, when the Gini coefficient shows unequal

distribution of the firms, the market is more concentrated and it implies of less

competitive pressure. Thus, it may lead to inefficiency. However, it is notified as

well to be careful in the interpretation of this relationship. The other factors such as

barrier to market entry and economies of scale should be considered before making

any judgment about the market condition. From individual firm point of view,

inequality also shows some extent of the economies of scale where the big traders is

more efficient in term of costs occurred in trading activities compared to the small

ones. Transaction costs occurred in the trading activities such as searching

information and negotiation process which have fixed cost character give more

advantages towards the big traders. It should be less expensive on a per-unit basis to

operate at a large volume.

47

Page 58: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

4.2 Coffee Market There are only a limited number of traders and processor who actively engaged in the

coffee business in the research area. Only in two villages, Bolapapu and Berdikari,

could the coffee traders and hullers be interviewed during the survey.

The four coffee traders can be classified into two different levels. Two traders operate

as village assemblers and two run their business on sub-district levels. The village

traders tend to gather coffee only from the villages where they reside. They manage a

small scale business. Unfortunately respondents were not able to recall how many kg

of coffee had been traded during the year because coffee was temporarily obtainable

and the volume was not large. On the other hand, sub-district assemblers operate in

various villages within a sub-district with average volume traded of more than 9000

kg per month.

For the procurement system, big traders depend on farmers produce, growing coffee

on their own farms and hire itinerant collectors. As in cocoa trade itinerant collectors

are hired who act as agents on a fee basis. These collectors have the primary

occupation, of using motorcycles for passenger service. Due to their mobility, it is

easy for them to collect and buy coffee beans from farmers within the village and

neighbour villages.

Not all traders specialize their operation in coffee. Most trade more than two crops.

The combination of crops traded varies from coffee, cocoa, rice, and maize. Majority

of traders deal with green coffee beans (kopi beras) that are hulled and ready to be

sold. Only one trader who owns a hulling machine handles dried coffee beans (kopi

glondong).

At the farm level, after picking up ripe berries, farmers spread them out to dry it in

the sun. The process takes some days. The whole dried berries are then mechanically

or manually hulled to get “green coffee beans” which are ready to be sold. The huller

who owns the machine to hull dried coffee beans receives a fee for this service.

Farmers then can sell their coffee beans through a few different channels, as seen in

Figure 4.3.

48

Page 59: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Producer

r

Villag

Sub-dis

Co

Asse

Figure 4.3 Marketing channel of coffee

The flow of coffee marketing is as follow:

1. Although it is rare, farmers can directly se

2. Direct sale to the village assembler

3. Direct sale to the sub-district assemblers o

4. In a huge amount, farmers can directly s

municipal assembler in Palu.

4.3 Rice Market

Rice is by far, one of the most important crops gro

its role as a dominant staple food. Accord

consumption of people in Central Sulawesi is 19

mostly fulfilled by grain, which accounts for 59%

average people consume 140.9 kg of rice per capit

Rice is grown for home consumption as well as

coffee, which are mainly sold, the role of rice in fa

Hulle

e Assemblers

trict Assemblers

ffee Factory

Municipal mbler/Wholesaler

ll the coffee beans to the huller

r through agents of these traders

ell the coffee beans to wholesaler/

wn in Central Sulawesi, because of

ing to SUSENAS 1999, energy

22 gram per capita per day and is

of the total energy consumed. On

a per year.

for sale. Compared to cocoa and

rmer income is not as significant as

49

Page 60: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

those cash crops. However, rice is still of central interest, particularly in term of food

security.

Due to its importance for food security, state intervention is frequently found in

marketing of rice. Through its marketing parastatal, the government provides one

particular channel for farmers to sell their produce. This non-monopoly parastatal,

namely BULOG (Badan Urusan Logistik = National Logistics Agency) is not an

exclusive channel in marketing of rice. Farmer can also choose some alternative

market outlets through private traders. Thus, in general rice is marketed either

through marketing parastatal of state or is freely traded in the private system.

This section will describe the channel by which rice is marketed in the research area

and the characteristics of main participants who actively engaged in this process. It

covers two different levels of market, in village or local and urban markets and

marketing channel of rice in the research area is carried out by private traders as can

be seen in Figure 4.4 and general characteristics of the traders are reported in Table

4.2.

Prior to marketing of rice, farmers process the harvested paddy to remove its husks,

either mechanically or manually. Milling mechanically is preferred, since it enables

farmers to reduce working time. The paddy is processed by a miller on a fee basis.

This fee is paid in kind of rice and varies from one village to another.

In the research area there are 23 middlemen who do intermediary rice trading

between farmer producers and consumers, and 7 of which run a rice milling business.

These millers tend not to specialize on rice milling, since they buy and sell rice as

well. Four of these millers procure their supply from their own farms, other farmers

or even from accumulation of fees. However, their business covers only the villages

they live. The rest operate their business in various villages within a sub-district.

50

Page 61: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 4.2 General characteristics of rice traders

Characteristics Village assembler

(N=8)

Sub district assembler

(N=4)

Local retailer (N=11)

Age (years) 44 43 47 Male (%) 100 75 82 Gender Female (%) 0 25 18 Primary school 0 0 18 Secondary school 50 0 36

School Attendance (%)

High school 50 100 46 Trading as main occupation (%)

50 100 55

Rice Producer (%) 50 25 55 Rice Miller (%) 50 75 0 Local Retailer (%) 63 50 100 Average number of years in business

10 19 7

Family background in trading (%)

38 75 27

Agricultural crops traded (average no)

1 3 2

The other channel to sell processed rice is directly to a village assembler. These

assemblers obtain their supply of rice only from the village they dwell in. Afterwards

it is sold to retailers in local markets, local consumers, or sub-district assemblers. Of

8 traders, 4 manage less than 450 kg of rice per month, while the other traders handle

larger volumes. Only half the traders reported that trading is their main occupation.

A sub-district assembler buys milled paddy from several villages within a sub-district

and from this point rice flows to a wholesaler at the regency or municipal level, to

retailers or to local consumers. These traders run larger businesses with an average

volume of rice traded more than 5000 kg per month and tend to be more specialized

in trading than village assemblers and retailers.

A wholesaler deals with huge amounts of rice and is usually located in urban markets.

In this stage retailers perform their important role in urban area by purchasing the rice

and then sell it in small amounts to urban consumers.

51

Page 62: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Paddy

Village or Local Market

Urban Markets

s

Regenc

Figure 4.4 Marketing channe

Note : Farmers brin processed in

After payinbe consume

This is different from the common p

a wholesaler and sells it to consume

farmers to a retailer who operates in

where a market is not available). T

business mainly by retailing rice. So

Farmer

Rice

r

Mille

r Retailer

Village

Assemble

Retailer

y/Municipal Wholesal

Sub-district Assembler

l of rice

g Un husked paddy t order to get rice g some fee farmers tad or sold

rocess where a retaile

rs. In the villages ric

the local market or sh

here are 11 traders in

urce of supply could

Consumers in local

market

er

Consumers in urban markets or

other regions

o rice miller to be further

ke their processed rice to

r buys processed rice from

e can be sold directly from

ops (particularly in villages

the villages that run their

be obtained from his or her

52

Page 63: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

own farm, other farmers or a miller. Here trade is on a small basis with an average

volume traded of 200 kg per month.

Without any contractual obligations, farmers are free to choose to which traders they

want to sell their rice. However, most farmers receive a consumption loan, working

capital or some agricultural inputs such as fertilizer from traders or millers and have

an obligation to sell their rice to these traders or millers.

Market Concentration

Market concentration refers to the number and relative size distribution of traders in a

market. CR4, Gini coefficient and Lorenz Curve were used as measures of market

concentration. For the rice traders in the sample (village and sub-district assemblers,

and local village retailer), the CR4 is 86 %. It is indicating an oligopsonist market

since the largest four rice traders accumulated 86% from total market share of rice

traders in the sample. The Gini coefficient is 0,80. It is an indication of an un-equal

distribution and highly concentrated rice market. As can be seen from the Lorenz

curve below, the largest 20% of the traders account for about 90% of the volume of

rice traded in the research area. The bottom 74% have an insignificant share of less

than 10%. The rest of the traders account for the remaining rice traded.

Although the Gini coefficient shows unequal distribution of the traders which

implying the rice market is concentrated and less competitive. Thus it may lead to

inefficiency. However, the other factors such as barrier to entry and economies of

scale should be considered before making any judgment about the market condition.

From individual firm point of view, inequality also shows some extents of the

economies of scale where the big traders is more efficient in term of costs occurred in

trading activities compared to the small ones. The transaction costs occurred in the

trading activities give more advantages towards the big traders.

53

Page 64: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Cumulated percentage of rice traders

9687787061524335261790

Cum

ulat

ed p

erce

ntag

e of

vol

ume

rice

trade

d

100

80

60

40

20

0

Perfect equality

Lorenz curve

Figure 4.5 Volume distribution of rice traded among traders

4.4 Maize Market Nine maize traders were selected and interviewed. Nearly all traders in the research

area who engaged in the dried kernel maize business are village assemblers who live

within the farming village and tend to limit their procurement operations to their own

village. Only two traders buy their maize from other villages, but they handle a small

volume of maize, and are therefore they are still categorized as village assemblers.

According to the volume of maize handled, the traders can be grouped into two

groups. Four of the traders handle dried kernel maize with an average volume less

than 1000 kg per month. The rest buys and sells dried kernel maize in larger volume

with average amount of more than 1000 kg per month.

54

Page 65: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Only one trader specializes in maize trading. The other traders buy and sell on

average more than two other commodities, which include of some combination of

cocoa, coffee or rice. Two traders provided fertilizers for farmers with a credit

system. In order to procure their supply, only two traders depend on farmers produce.

The traders who have other activities in agricultural farming, such as growing maize

on their own farm have an additional source of supply to be sold.

There are various channels of marketing maize. These channels start on the farm and

flows to consumers in urban market. This can be seen in Figure 4.6.

P

Animal Husbandry

Perform as Processor

Farmer

Figure 4.6 Marketing channel of drie

The flow of maize through the mark

there are some post harvest activitie

the common post harvest activities f

Maize is typically dried under the s

processes are carried out completely

traders.

Maize flows from farmers to villag

buyers, that are shown in the figure,

further processing, the village assem

Village Assembler

erform as Retailer in local market

Municipal Assembler/ Wholesaler

Retailer in central market Local Consumers

d kernel maize

et begins at farm level. Prior to marketing maize

s that farmers must do. Drying and shelling are

ound in the villages before it is ready to be sold.

un and then shelled manually. After these two

, maize is ready to be transported and then sold to

e assemblers and from this point of sale various

can be identified as market outlets. Without any

blers have some optional channels through which

55

Page 66: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

to market their dried kernel maize, for instance, directly to animal husbandry,

wholesalers, municipal assembler or to retailer in central market (Palu). It is also

found that the traders sell their maize to local markets in order to meet the needs of

local consumers. The dried kernel can be processed into other forms, such as starch.

This adds value, which in turn influences price. Some traders who own machines to

mill the kernel benefit from this increasing value. They can sell this new form, maize

starch to animal husbandry firms and receive a higher price.

4.5 Fertilizer Market Starting in December 1998 distribution of fertilizer in Indonesia was liberalized and

followed a free market mechanism. Nevertheless, in order to facilitate farmers

obtaining fertilizer at on affordable price, the central government of Indonesia

through the ministry of trade and industry and together with the ministry of

agriculture, arrange a procurement and distribution system of subsidized fertilizers in

February 2003. The subsidized fertilizers are urea, SP-36, ZA and NPK. The

subsidized fertilizers are allocated for food crops farmers, animal husbandry farmers,

and small-scale estates. Farmers in the research areas apply mostly urea to their rice

paddy fields; therefore this part will focus in describing the marketing channel of

urea.

According to the ministerial decree of trade and industry no 70/MPP/Kep/2/2003,

producers of subsidized fertilizers are responsible for procurement and distribution of

those fertilizers from the first line (line I) until the fourth line (line IV) in the

provincial area where they are assigned.

As indicated in the decree, the marketing channel of subsidized fertilizers can be

describes as follows:

Line I, refers to is a warehouse of a fertilizer factory. Line II, is a warehouse of

fertilizers located in provincial capital cities. Line III, is a warehouse of a producer or

distributor located at the municipal or regency level. The distributors are companies

assigned by the producer to purchase, store, and sell the subsidized fertilizers in huge

56

Page 67: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

amounts to be sold to consumers through retailers as the fourth line (line IV). These

retailers are private or firms located in sub-districts and their main activity is selling

directly to final consumers in retail. They can be can be engaged in distribution of

subsidized fertilizer after receiving an assignment from the distributor.

As stated in the regulation, the warehouse line III is responsible for selling fertilizers

to distributors in the same line. However, line III does not operate in the distribution

of fertilizers in Central Sulawesi, and in this case line II simultaneously performs as

line III.

Previously PT Pupuk Sriwijaya (PUSRI) covered circulation of fertilizers in central

Sulawesi. However, since 2003 PT Pupuk Bontang Kalimantan Timur has been

responsible for distributing fertilizers in this province.

The Indonesian ministerial of agriculture, through ministerial decree no

427/Kpts/SR.130/8/2003 decided the highest retail price (in fourth line) by

consumers. The highest retail price (HET = Harga Eceran Tertinggi) for urea in

period (1 August – 31 December 2003) is Rp 1050/kg and Rp 1750/kg for NPK.

These prices should be unchanged in all areas in, both urban and rural in Indonesia

including remote villages in central Sulawesi.

In the research area, the common fertilizer used is urea and it is mainly applied to

fertilize rice paddy fields. Because demand for other kinds of fertilizer and other

agricultural inputs are lower, fertilizer traders in the research area focus their

activities on retailing urea. However, these traders do not specialize only on buying

and selling fertilizers. They also engage in other agricultural commodities such as

rice, and retail food items and other consumer goods. Hence, fertilizers are often

found in shops which sell food and consumer goods. These traders frequently fail to

pay attention in proper storage of fertilizer. They put fertilizers together with other

consumers good. Besides being seriously harmful to consumers health, this is not

permitted by regulation.

57

Page 68: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Although the study area covers 8 villages, fertilizer traders were only found in 4

villages; Sintuwu, Berdikari, Maranata and Bolapapu. Five retailers were selected

and interviewed during the survey time.

Generally, fertilizers trade is highly interrelated with food crops activities particularly

rice farming. To accelerate their business and to keep their supply rice traders or

millers offer farmers who frequently sell their rice or hulled their paddy to get urea or

other input required for rice farming and pay it with some charges soon after

harvesting. This is a common phenomenon found in marketing of fertilizers in the

research area.

For the traders or millers this system can be described as a sort of vertical integration

since it provides a controllable flow between input and output received. However, for

the farmer, it is an uneasy situation because some traders demand high prices. The

farmers do not have any bargaining power to negotiate how much to charge or how

prices should be paid. The payment varies from one trader to another.

In Bolapapu, fertilizers are openly sold in rice miller to all consumers. There are two

different payment systems: cash or barter. Even though lower prices are offered if

consumers pay cash, most people choose the barter system. Actually, barter is

another term of credit that occured in all villages. One kg of urea can be obtained by

paying one kg of rice. Of course, the price of fertilizer is relatively high in this

system as compared to the common trading system. The prices are Rp 1050/kg and

Rp 2600/kg of subsidized urea and rice respectively. In other words, the price that

should be paid during harvest season increases more than 100% off the subsidized

price of urea. Nevertheless, the farmers choose this barter system because of the time

available before payment.

Since there are only two planting seasons for a year in this village, it means that from

planting to harvest season takes 6 months. As a consequence there will be 6 months

gestation period before payment. According to the trader, this high price is a rational

consequence of barter the system because of gestation period and calculation of

interest rate.

58

Page 69: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

The other villages have very similar trading systems. In Sidondo II, the rice miller

offers the barter system as well. Similar to the situation in Bolapapu, the

compensation is one bag of rice (50 kg) for one sack of urea (50 kg). This cost can be

transferred into cash in the amount of Rp 70000. In other words, farmers can

purchase urea from the retailer with cash and it costs Rp 1400/kg. Since the normal

price of rice is Rp 2000/kg, if the farmers choose this barter system they will lose Rp

600/kg.

In comparison to traders in Bolapapu, traders in Berdikari and Sintuwu concentrate

their selling to what are called “member of trader”. A farmer who frequently sells

their rice or maize or hulled their paddy is referred to as a “member of trader”.

Although the urea can be bought with cash, the majority of consumers choose the

credit system. In Berdikari the credit system is called as “ijon”. Similar to the barter

system in Bolapapu, the price of urea and other inputs is higher since the traders

calculate gestation period as well as interest rate. In Berdikari the price of urea is

20% higher than the cash price.

Sintuwu has a different system than the other villages. According to some farmers´

explanation, itinerant traders who operate and collect maize in this village usually

provide fertilizers during the planting season. During the harvest period, farmers are

obliged to sell their maize to these traders. Income from this transaction will be

received after calculating the amount of input used.

Almost in all survey villages farmers receive credit in form of fertilizers and other

inputs from rice miller. Some farmers occasionally purchase urea and other

agricultural inputs in Palu when they sell their produce in this central market. Due to

those factors the fertilizer market in the research area do not rapidly grow

4.6 Barriers to market entry

Most of traders reported that it is relatively easy to be involved in agricultural trading

as indicated without any market license required for small-scale business. Only big

traders who deal with high volume traded need this license.

59

Page 70: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

It can be verified since ministerial decree of trade and industry no

289/MPP/Kep/10/2001 states that a firm is required to have a market license (SIUP =

Surat Ijin Usaha Perdagangan) if its financial and equity capital is at least Rp 200

million not including land and building. If a trader has capital less than the lowest

criterion, such as itinerant trader, no license is needed to trade. Although the license is

issued by local (regency or municipal) government at location where trading is

conducted, it allows traders to trade everywhere within Indonesian territory.

As stated in the decree, procedure of application, and rules of the license such as fee,

expired period should be the same from one region to another. Nevertheless, since

decentralization policy is implemented and as a reason for improving regional

development and income, application of the decree are various from one region to

another. According to explanation of trade officer, this situation leads to confusion

and inefficiency in trading business.

4.7 Summary

This chapter describes structure of agricultural markets. The structure is explained by

flow of marketing channel, market concentration and barrier to market entry. Due to

some limitations of data collection, structures of agricultural markets are mostly

described in term of marketing channel. Compared to coffee, maize and fertilizer

markets, cocoa and rice are described more detail.

The flow of cocoa beans is started from the farmer producer to village or sub-district

assemblers. The Sub-district assemblers handle higher volume of cocoa traded

compared to the village assemblers because they operate in larger area. The sub-

district assembler collect cocoa beans from some villages within a sub-district and

village assembler limit their procurement only in one village. From this point of sale,

the cocoa beans are transported to wholesaler/municipal assemblers in Palu before

being exported.

Cocoa market exhibits an oligopsonist market with regard to the farmer producers as

indicated by Gini coefficient of 0,78. The Lorenz curve shows that the largest 20%

60

Page 71: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

of the traders account for about 80% of the volume of cocoa traded in the research

area. The concentration ratio of CR4 is 82 %. It means that that the largest four of the

traders in the sample accumulated market share of 82% compared to all market

participants in the cocoa market.

Different to cocoa which can be sold directly after drying without any further process,

rice should be milled to remove its husks before it is sold. Since most farmers do not

mill their paddy manually, the paddy is transported to the miller to be processed.

Then the flow of rice is starting from this milling process. After paying some fee, the

farmer can sell their rice to local retailer or assembler. Due to its function as

dominant staple food, it implies of unique marketing system. It can be divided into

two different marketing systems for local and urban consumers. The local retailers

manage small basis business and retail the rice to the local consumers in their

villages. The village and sub-district assemblers sell their commodity to

wholesaler/municipal assembler in Palu or other urban areas.

For the rice traders in the sample (village and sub-district assemblers and local village

retailer), the CR4 is 86 % and the Gini coefficient is 0,80. It is indicating an

oligopsonist market with regard to the farmer producers. The largest four rice traders

accumulated 86% from total market share of rice traders in the sample. The Lorenz

curve shows that the largest 20% of the traders account for about 90% of the volume

of rice traded in the research area. The rest of the traders account for the remaining

rice traded.

The cocoa and rice markets show an indication of an un-equal distribution and

concentrated market. This condition implies of less competitive market due to

oligopsonist nature. Technically speaking, it may lead to inefficiency. However, one

should be careful in interpreting this relationship. The other factors such as barrier to

market entry and economies of scale should be considered before making any

judgment about market condition.

61

Page 72: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Inequality also shows some extents of the economies of scale where the big traders is

more efficient in term of costs occurred in trading activities compared to the small

ones. Transaction costs occurred in the trading activities such as searching

information and negotiation process which have fixed cost character give more

advantages towards the big traders. It should be less expensive on a per-unit basis to

operate at a large volume.

By looking at the characteristic of cocoa and rice traders, it can be seen that level of

education of these traders is relatively higher compared to other households in the

research area.

Markets for coffee and maize are not well developed as cocoa and rice markets.

Market destination of these commodities is limited either to the local consumers or to

local industry such as food processing industry or poultry.

The same case for fertilizer, this market is not well developed yet. Retailer of

fertilizers operate only in 4 out of 8 villages. These retailers perform as rice miller

too. The marketing system mainly by giving loan to the farmers in kind of fertilizers,

mainly urea and the payment will be made during the harvest, directly after the

milling process. For the traders or millers this system can be described as a sort of

vertical integration since it provides a controllable flow between input and output

received.

The barrier to market entry can be defined as a potential factor that prevents the new

entrants to enter the market. Technically speaking, market licensing requirement is

one potential factor that prevents new entrants to enter the market. In the research

area there is limited barrier to entry market in term of this license. The market license

should be held only by big traders with asset more than Rp 200 million.

62

Page 73: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

5. AGRICULTURAL MARKET CONDUCT Based on the research questions presented in the chapter 1 on the subject of

approaches used by the traders in selling, buying and pricing activities, and the role of

producer associations (cooperatives) or trade associations for marketing of

agricultural input and output, this chapter discusses the profile of the traders and the

conduct of agricultural market. The explanation is not discussed separately between

commodities. Behaviour of agricultural traders is explained in general.

5.1 Profile of agricultural traders

In the research area 36 traders who involved in trading agricultural commodities

either cash or food crops mainly cocoa, coffee, rice and maize and agricultural input

were interviewed during the survey. The selected traders are those who operate in the

whole time within a year. There are also some seasonal traders do businesses in the

villages. Because their seasonal activity and often live outside the villages they are

not covered by this study. Profile of traders can be divided into four different aspects

according to their resource endowment. Human, financial, physical and social capital

will be described in this section.

Human capital Generally the traders are relatively young with average age of 40 years. The majority

of agricultural traders are male, nevertheless one quarter of the sample are female.

On average, 41.7 %, 30.5% and 27.8% of traders educated at primary, secondary, and

high school, respectively. The percentage of traders who completed high school are

relatively higher compared to the household sample in STORMA household survey.

On average, 12.4% of the household sample completed high school.

Two third of traders do not come from family which have experience in trading. The

rest who come from family with trading background receive assistance from their

parents such as equipments, working capital and the most important knowledge of

entrepreneurships. Experience of traders being active in trade varies from 1 to 25

years, with average years in trading is 9 years.

63

Page 74: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

More than half traders have employees who come from their relatives. The average

numbers employees from relatives are 1.6 and 1.1 for male and female worker

respectively. The workers from relatives usually do not receive wage except living

cost and other private needs are fulfilled. If these employees receive wage, the

payment also lower compared to the standard wage. Only 14% of the traders hire

permanent workers. For big traders, temporary employees are hired during harvest

season when huge amount of produce should be handled. The wage for permanent

and temporary employee differs from one to the other villages and it ranges from Rp

5000 to Rp 15.000 per day.

Some of big traders also hire some agents who work on fee basis. These agents

collect produce from farmers within and neighbour villages. This system is found

mainly in procurement supply of cocoa.

Table 5.1 Characteristics of agricultural traders in research area Characteristics of traders based on their human capital Average age (years) 40 Gender (%) Male 75 Female 25 School attendance (%) Primary school 41,7 Secondary school 30,5 High school 27,8 Family background in trade (%) 33 Average number of years in business (years) 9

64

Page 75: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Financial capital More than 90% of traders reported that their own capital is a main source of working

capital. Although it is very limited, some traders finance their business by external

sources. Loans from non-governmental organization or bank are found to start up or

expand the business.

Physical capital In order to bring products from farmer producers to consumers, equipments are

necessary to help and make those marketing task easier. Physical capital refers to the

equipments such as transportation, storage, and communication facilities used in daily

trading activities.

Only 25% from all traders have storage facility. A warehouse usually has multiple

functions, to store stocks and put milling machine. All commodities regardless to its

purpose, to be further processed, to sell or home consumed and milling machine are

placed together in this warehouse. Majority of traders store their stock in their house.

Telephone as important tool of communication particularly to search out information

on prices or to offer product and in some cases to negotiate with clients is extremely

limited used by the traders. Only 8% of total traders have telephone. Conventional

method of communication such as face to face is the most important source of market

information.

Motorcycle is transportation facility owned and commonly used by almost all traders

to collect and sell their stocks. For small traders, motorcycle is necessary to transport

one or two sack of their commodities, mainly cocoa. Transportation cost that should

be paid by traders vary depend on the vehicles used, motorcycle or car. Motorcycle

whose own by almost all traders, gasoline is only costs counted for transportation.

The average cost paid for gasoline is Rp 4500 per a return trip. For one trip, traders

can load up to 2 sacks (each sack contains at least 50 kg).

Car and truck are owned by big traders to transport all commodities to next buyer in

central market or in other regency. For traders who do not have own car to transport

65

Page 76: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

big volume, public transportation is a choice. Calculation of transportation cost using

own vehicle varies between traders, some traders reported only gasoline as

transportation cost and the other adds some additional cost for driver and his

assistants. Therefore the costs range from Rp 25 to Rp 100 per kg per trip and the

average cost is Rp 80.50 per kg per trip. However some traders reported that they do

not spend transportation cost since big traders from Palu collect their products or they

sell their product in retail.

Social capital No traders are member and involved in formal organization such as cooperative or

trade association. None of traders involved in the informal organizations such as

informal saving group. However, since most of traders (69%) are local people,

relation with farmers as their supplier is easier to be managed. All traders notify that

personal reputation and good relationship with suppliers, buyers and people

surrounding their environment is one of key success in conducting their business.

5.2 Business practices

Quantity and quality inspection

All traders do inspection in order to obtain product that is suitable with the need and

demand of next buyer. For quantity purposes, weighing is done in the first process of

receiving process. After weighing, quality inspection is done with the purpose of

reducing losses because price will be deducted if quality is not fit with the

requirements. In term of quality inspection, moist contents, cleanliness, and texture

are activities conducted by the traders. Although these activities are important, all

traders depend only on visual inspection. None of them have tools to do such

inspections because as they said the tools are expensive. Process of inspection does

not take too much time and it varies from 1 until 5 minutes with average time is 1.63

minute. Long Experience as trader helps them to avoid losses from receiving low

quality of products and losses of expected profit.

66

Page 77: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Price setting and payment methods Purchasing price to be paid by each trader is determined independently. Without any

contractual obligation farmers can choose trader who offers higher price. Price in

Palu as central market is a primary source for price setting. Negotiation of price can

be applied in some conditions for example when farmers bring a lot of product and

differentiation of opinion concerning on quality and measures.

Cash is well known as payment method to farmers. Credit and in kind (barter) can be

done particularly when long relationships between trader and farmers are closely tied.

For all these contractual agreements, no written contract is provided thus close

relation and trust between the two participants are needed.

Farmers preferably choose in-kind payment when they have only small amount of

commodity. The exchange of cocoa and rice with basic food items and other

consumer goods are frequently made.

The universal transaction method applied with next buyer is cash. Big traders from

Palu such as municipal assembler, wholesaler or exporters provide credit for traders

who operate in villages so they can pay cash to the farmers particularly in harvest

season. Usually these payment systems are made when they have close relationship as

a result of regular supplies products.

Specialization in agricultural marketing and marketing functions performed

Traders tend not to specialize on one crop of five commodities surveyed, cocoa,

coffee, rice, maize and chemical agricultural input. On average, 53% of traders

specialize on one commodity and the rest deal with more than one commodity.

Apart of trading, most of traders have other activities either in agricultural activity or

non-farm enterprise. On average, 64% and 33% of total traders are farmers and have

non-farm enterprise, respectively. All these activities are conducted to facilitate and

make their business easier, such as for procurement and in-kind payment (barter).

67

Page 78: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Traders are not fully specialized in marketing function performs in the marketing

chain. As it can be seen in Table 5.2, for example one trader can be perform as sub-

district assembler, miller and retail at the same time for different commodities.

Table 5.2 Specialization of trader activity in marketing chain

% Traders Perform as

Rural assembler 97

Sub-district assembler 11

Processor (Miller) 28

Retailer 61

Relationship and network with suppliers and buyers

More than two third of traders have regular suppliers and next buyers. Majority of

traders admit that good price and short distance are influencing factors for choice of

supplier. Searching for new supplier is relatively easy according to 69% traders. 25

% reported that to find new supplier is very easy and in contrast only 6 % feel

difficult. In relation with business duration, frequencies of having regular

suppliers/buyers and searching for new supplier/ buyers can be seen in Table 5.3.

New entrants which experiences in trading less than 10 year (these traders started up

their business 1 year ago) have difficulties of searching new supplier. According to

explanation of cash crop traders, competition on searching of new supplier sometimes

fairly high, particularly when big traders from Palu travel directly to their village and

offer farmers relatively higher price than rural traders.

Reasons for choice of buyer are good price and regular transaction. As indicated by

some traders, the old-standing players in central market will make a fool new entrants

without enough experience in trading. Therefore they preferably choose buyer who

already had regular transaction. The regular transactions, which in turn develop trust

between each other, have additional benefit on financial support such as credit.

During harvest season, when cash should be prepared to pay bulk of produce, big

trader from Palu will provide credit to rural/local traders.

68

Page 79: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 5.3 Relation between business duration and having regular and searching new suppliers

Business Duration % Traders

Less than 10 years

(N=20)

At least 10 years

(N=16)

Having regular supplier 80 69

Searching for new supplier

Very easy 20 31

Easy 70 69

Difficult 10 0

Having regular buyer 80 81

Searching for new buyer

Very easy 10 19

Easy 70 56

Difficult 20 19

Very difficult - 6

Searching for new buyer is reported very easy and easy according to 64% and 14%of

total traders. 19% and 3% traders consider that finding new buyer is difficult and

very difficult respectively. In accordance with their business duration, it can be seen

in Table 5.3 some traders in both groups experience difficulties in searching new

buyer. The problem is more pronounced in food crops compared to cash crop traders.

For example, maize traders have limited outlets to sell their stocks, poultry industry

and retail market are the main market available. Thus, finding new buyer is a

problematical issue.

Conflict between traders and his/her suppliers and buyers sometimes occurred during

the trading process. Disagreement over result on quality inspection and measures are

69

Page 80: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

the most cases. Direct negotiation within a family atmosphere is a main solution for

this situation.

Market coverage Most of traders collect their supplies within area with radius less than 10 km. It

means that those traders procure their stocks mainly from village where they reside.

Only 14% travel more than 10 km to purchase their supplies and it is conducted by

big traders who operate in various villages.

Besides selling in his/her village and neighbour village, the most important market

destination of traders is Palu, where central market for agricultural commodities

located. Majority of traders travel more than 15 km to sell their stock and only 14%

of traders limit their selling area only in his/her village.

5.3 Trade associations Of the four outputs and agricultural input surveyed, trade association in Central

Sulawesi mainly works in cash crop such as cocoa (ASKINDO = Asosiasi Kakao

Indonesia, The Indonesian Cocoa Association). None of traders in the villages,

however, involves in this organization.

According to some exporters, ASKINDO as a room for persons or firms who active

engaged in cocoa trading only cover cocoa exporters as their member. As far as their

explanation, direct benefit of being a member of this organization, however, not as

much as they wish for.

Contrary to the explanation, as indicated by Akiyama and Nishio, 1996, the

association has a great contribution to policy applied in cocoa sector. The cocoa

market can be performed without or with very limited intervention of government.

The organization still being active to implement some important agendas to improve

the cocoa industry in Indonesia so their role to give benefit to all participants in cocoa

industry including farmer producers will be achieved.

70

Page 81: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

5.4 Summary

This chapter describes the conduct of agricultural market by description the behaviour

of agricultural traders in the sample. It explains profile of the traders, approaches

used by the traders in conducting their business such as selling, buying and pricing

activities, and the role of producer associations (cooperatives) or trade associations

for marketing of agricultural input and output.

There are 36 selected traders in the research area involved in trading agricultural

commodities mainly cocoa, coffee, rice, maize and fertilizer. Profile of traders can be

divided into four different resource endowments, human, financial, physical and

social capital.

Generally, the traders are relatively young with average age of 40 years and educated.

One third of the traders come from family with trading background and this gives an

additional advantage as they receive assistance from their parents such as equipments,

working capital and knowledge of entrepreneurships. Relatives is important source of

employee since more than half traders have employees who come from their relatives.

During harvest season when huge amount of produce should be handled, large traders

hire temporary employees.

To finance their business own capital is a main source of working capital. Only 25%

from all traders have storage facility which has multiple functions. Although it is

important tool of communication particularly to search market information, only 8%

of total traders have telephone. Due to that fact, face-to-face communication is the

most important source of market information. Motorcycle is transportation facility

owned and commonly used by almost all traders to collect and sell their stocks

particularly to transport one or two sack of their commodities.

No traders are member and involved in formal and informal organizations. Most

traders (69%) are local people, therefore relation with people surrounding their

environment is easier to be managed which in turn influence their success in

conducting their business.

71

Page 82: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

For quantity inspection, weighing is done in the first process of receiving process,

and then it is followed by simple quality inspection trough visual inspection.

Purchasing price paid by each trader is determined independently. Cash is well

known as payment method to farmers. The other methods, credit and in kind (barter)

can be done when long relationships between trader and farmers are closely tied. For

all these contractual agreements no written contract is provided. Thus close relation

and trust between the two participants are needed. Traders tend not to specialize on

one crop of five commodities surveyed, not fully specialized in marketing function

performs in the marketing chain and have other activities either in agricultural

activity or non-farm enterprise.

More than two third of traders have regular suppliers and next buyers. New entrants

whose experience in trading is less than 10 year have difficulties of searching new

supplier. Searching for new buyer is reported very easy and easy according to 64%

and 14%of total traders. 19% and 3% traders consider that finding new buyer is

difficult and very difficult respectively. The problem of difficulties in searching new

buyers is more pronounced in food crops compared to cash crop traders.

Most of traders collect their supplies within village where they reside. Only 14%

travel more than 10 km to purchase their supplies and it is conducted by large traders

who operate in various villages. Majority of traders travel more than 15 km to sell

their stock. None of traders in the villages are being a member of trade association

such as ASKINDO = Asosiasi Kakao Indonesia, The Indonesian Cocoa Association).

The members of this association are mainly exporters.

72

Page 83: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

6. PERFORMANCE OF AGRICULTURAL MARKET In relation to the research questions presented in the first chapter on the subject of

performance of agricultural market, this chapter attempts to answer the following

questions: (1) to what extent do the communities have access to agricultural input and

output markets? (2) what is the marketing margin i.e. differences between producer

price and the retail price paid by consumers and within the agents in the marketing

chain? (3) what are patterns of price variability of agricultural commodities in term of

time and space? Do villages with lower access to market have lower producer or

higher consumer prices? Do villages with lower access to market have more seasonal

fluctuation?

6.1 Access to market and infrastructure Table 6.1 shows that in the research area most of villages are accessible by car, which

connected those villages to the provincial capital city, Palu. Only one village,

Tomado in sub-district Kulawi is not accessible by car because road available in the

village is walking track. The nearest road accessed by car can be reached after

walking by 4 hours.

Table 6.1 Characteristics of market access

Village Accessible by car

Type of road Condition during rainy season

Presence of market site

The nearest market

Tomado No Walking track - (4 hours walking) NO Bolapapu Sintuwu Yes A/CR Difficult NO Rahmat Berdikari Yes A/CR No Problem NO Bahagia Sidondo II Yes A/CR No Problem NO Bobo Maranata Yes A/CR No Problem YES - Pandere Yes A/CR No Problem YES - Rahmat Yes G/DR Difficult YES - Bolapapu Yes A/CR No Problem YES -

Four villages of the village sub-samples are reported have regular market and the rest

do not have market. Road and market place are infrastructures available in the

villages which are utilized as a proxy of degree to market access. In relation to the

73

Page 84: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

two infrastructures, all the villages can be arranged into 3 different groups starting

from the lowest until the highest degree of market access: 1) not accessible by car and

no market-low access; 2) accessible by car and no market-medium access; and 3)

accessible by car and have market-good acess. The fourth group to be compared to

other groups is Palu as central market. Tomado has characteristics of the first group.

The second group consists 3 villages, Sintuwu, Berdikari and Sidondo II. Maranata,

Pandere, Rahmat and Bolapapu belong to the third group.

6.2 Farmer’s share and gross marketing margin

Based on selling and buying prices, marketing margin at different levels can be

calculated using the gross margin formula. Using data in Table 6.2 and 6.3 the results

for two commodities are presented in Table 6.4.

Net marketing margin can be calculated if data on marketing costs are available.

Because marketing costs are not well documented, marketing costs are difficult to be

collected, thus the marketing margin presented in the table only the gross marketing

margin.

Table 6.2 Prices for cocoa in the marketing channel in October 2003

Marketing participant Selling price (Rp/kg)

Farmer producers 8655

Village Assembler (VA) 10480

Municipal Assembler (MA) 11016

Consumer (Proxied by fob Palu)* 11016 * = not a seller, only a buyer

74

Page 85: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 6.3 Prices for rice in the marketing channel in October 2003

Local market

Marketing participant Selling price (Rp/kg)

Farmer producers 1810

Village Assembler 2269

Retailer in the village (RV) 2348

Consumer in the village* 2348

Urban market

Farmer producers 1810

Village Assembler 2269

Retailer in Palu (RU) 2781

Consumer in Palu* 2781 * = not a seller, only a buyer

Table 6.4 Marketing margin for each participant in the marketing channel

Cocoa (%) Rice (%) Gross Marketing Margin (GMM) in the local market in the urban market

Total GMM 21.43 22.91 34.92

GMMRA 16.56 19.55 16.51

GMMMA 4.87 - -

GMMRV - 3.36 -

GMMRU - - 18.41

Farmer’s share 78.57 77.09 65.08

Variability of the marketing margin

Some studies have attempted to show that variability in prices provoke changes in

magnitude of the marketing margins. Therefore it is important to observe whether the

margin relatively stable or fluctuate if commodities prices change. The variability of

the marketing margins are presented in Tables 6.5, 6.6, and 6.7.

75

Page 86: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Gross marketing margin of cocoa in all villages are reported in the Table 6.5. It

exhibits fluctuations during 2003. The average gross marketing margin; differential

prices between producer price and consumer price (approached by FOB Palu) is

16.90%.

Table 6.5 Gross marketing margin of cocoa during 2003 Months Gross marketing margin of cocoa Tomado Sintuwu Sidondo 2 Pandere Bolapapu Rahmat January n.a 2.61 14.51 n.a 3.72 4.55 February n.a 5.36 18.56 20.77 7.56 5.36 March 15.22 18.86 22.49 16.58 10.68 18.86 April 3.82 12.94 17.09 9.46 5.81 12.94 May 0.69 11.62 15.27 16.63 18.00 11.62 June 13.96 31.16 32.02 25.79 31.16 31.16 July 28.07 23.04 28.96 8.09 10.09 22.30 August 26.62 n.a 24.79 4.84 19.28 20.20 September 29.32 n.a 26.01 10.55 7.24 18.28 October 29.20 14.67 22.84 8.77 20.12 21.71 November 21.12 10.68 28.55 6.43 24.37 20.19 December 31.21 18.31 20.46 5.41 20.46 16.16 AVERAGE 19.92 14.93 22.63 12.12 14.87 16.94 16.90

Table 6.6 shows that gross marketing margin in Pandere, Sintuwu and Rahmat have

negative values. The GMM formula (differential prices between producer price and

consumer price in central market) shows that consumer prices in those villages are

relatively higher compared to those in Palu. During the first six months, Rahmat and

Sintuwu have negative marketing margin and around 2 months in Pandere. The

negative margin might be occurred due to several reasons. First, there is no trade link

between the two areas. Second, it is an indication that reversal flow of IR 66 Super

rice occurred in those villages. After harvest, rice flows to urban market and during

the lean season rice is bought from Palu and transported to these villages.

In contrast to IR 66 rice, cimandi rice shows different phenomena. The margins

always have positive values and relatively stable throughout the year. Although the

margin in Rahmat is calculated based on consumer price in that village, the margins

76

Page 87: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

remain positive and stable. According to Thomsen and Foote as cited by Mendoza

(1995), except during periods of definite changes in prices of goods or in the rates of

costs, the margin rate percentage remains stable throughout the years. This situation

is caused by some of the cost components change less rapidly than prices. Prices may

change everyday, but marketing costs do not change for weeks or even months.

Table 6.6 Gross marketing margin of IR 66 super rice in 2003

Months Gross marketing margin of IR 66 super Tomado Pandere* Sintuwu* Rahmat*

January n.a n.a n.a n.a February n.a 0.00 0.00 0.00 March 29.30 2.33 -4.19 -4.19 April 27.27 0.00 -7.39 -7.39 May 33.33 7.14 -3.57 -3.57 June 35.00 -3.75 -7.50 -8.13 July 17.95 -17.95 -12.82 -7.69 August n.a n.a n.a n.a September 35.71 24.11 n.a 9.60 October 49.30 25.39 24.72 8.99 November 36.79 25.93 16.05 12.59 December 31.03 8.05 2.30 -2.01 AVERAGE 32.86 7.12 0.84 -0.18

* = Based on consumer price in the village Table 6.7 Gross marketing margin of cimandi rice in 2003

Months Gross marketing margin of cimandi rice Sidondo 2 Maranata Pandere Bolapapu Rahmat*

January n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a February 18.37 19.39 12.24 24.49 12.76 March 11.92 17.17 7.07 24.85 5.05 April 13.60 14.00 4.00 21.28 1.00 May 17.00 23.20 16.00 17.60 9.50 June 23.27 26.53 11.22 13.47 7.76 July 23.96 25.00 0.00 11.67 9.90 August n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a September 29.00 32.00 28.00 17.60 14.00 October 32.00 33.50 29.60 15.52 13.00 November 25.16 30.32 31.18 20.86 19.14 December 15.48 23.21 19.05 11.43 10.71 AVERAGE 20.98 24.43 15.84 17.88 10.28 17.88

77

Page 88: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

6.3 Uncertainties, Break Even Price and sensitivity analysis Depending solely on expected (average) prices as risk calculation are not applicable

for risk averse agents. Since farmers are risk averse, calculation of downside risk,

which can be defined as a shorthand description for situation in which any significant

deviations from the norm or expected situation lead to worse outcomes is important

to be measured. If prices decrease below the variable costs, it will hurt the farmer

producers even in the short-run. As commodity price takers, the farmers cannot

determine market price and since there is a risk that prices may be lower than

expected, it is important to assess the acceptable declining of prices to cover cost of

production.

In order to get the possible decline of prices to cover per unit variable cost of

production, the collected producer prices of cocoa, coffee, and rice during the

research time in 2003 are compared with the break-even price of those commodities.

The break even price is a situation where the gross margin is zero. The Break-even

prices are calculated based on gross margin analysis from household survey

conducted by STORMA sub project A4 in 2001. The gross margin is the value

obtained from the difference between the expected gross income earned and the

expected variable costs incurred in the farm activity.

Comparing the two variables directly will not be meaningful because time periods are

not the same. To overcome the problem of time differentiation, prices are adjusted

for inflation using Consumer Price Index (CPI) Central Sulawesi. The CPIs are IDR

299.39 and 342.10 in 2001 and 2003, respectively.

The possible declines of some commodities prices to the break-even prices both in

nominal and percentage are presented in Tables 6.8, 6.9 and 6.10. The variable costs

of production included in the calculation are land preparation, planting or seed,

fertilizer, irrigation, pesticide and transport or processing. All tables show that the

prices can drop quite a bit to cover variable cost. In all villages cocoa and coffee can

drop up to more than 90% of average prices and rice up to more 60%.

78

Page 89: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Therefore it can be concluded that there is no short-run downside risk faced by the

farmers in the research area. The short run down side risk for tree crops is low

basically because most costs incurred are fixed such as planting of trees and

opportunity cost of land.

The advantage of gross margin analysis is can be used for a short-term farm analysis.

One of the shortcomings of the gross margin analysis is leaving the remuneration of

fixed factors such as family labour and land. In the long run, however, all costs

incurred in the production (variable and fixed) must be covered.

Table 6.8. Break Even Price and sensitivity analysis of cocoa Sensitivity analysis

Possible decline of prices to BEP Village Average price of cocoa

in 2003 (Rp/kg) Nominal (%)

Tomado 10115 9862 97.50Sintuwu 11321 11068 97.77Berdikari 10938 10685 97.69Sidondo 2 10058 9805 97.48Maranata 12885 12632 98.04Pandere 11330 11077 97.77Bolapapu 11204 10951 97.74Rahmat 10808 10555 97.66CPI Central Sulawesi in 2001= 299.39 and in 2003=342.10

Table 6.9 .Break Even Price and sensitivity analysis of coffee Sensitivity analysis

Possible decline of prices to BEP Village Average price of coffee

in 2003 (Rp/kg) Nominal (%)

Tomado 4167 4148 99.53 Sintuwu 5173 5154 99.62 Berdikari 4166 4147 99.53 Maranata 5170 5151 99.62 Pandere 4584 4565 99.58 Bolapapu 5040 5021 99.61 Rahmat 4902 4883 99.60 CPI Central Sulawesi in 2001= 299.39 and in 2003=342.10

79

Page 90: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 6.10 Break Even Price and sensitivity analysis of rice Sensitivity analysis

Possible decline of prices to BEP Village Average price of rice

in 2003 (Rp/kg) Nominal (%)

Tomado 1740 1090 62.63 Sintuwu 2000 1350 67.49 Berdikari 1809 1159 64.06 Sidondo 2 2109 1459 69.17 Maranata 2208 1558 70.55 Pandere 2358 1708 72.43 Bolapapu* 2460 1810 73.57 Rahmat 2250 1600 71.10 CPI Central Sulawesi in 2001= 299.39 and in 2003=342.10

* = Price of Cimandi Rice

6.4 Seasonal and spatial price variability

From viewpoint of physical transmission from production side to final consumer,

marketing has three dimensions, time, space and form. Concerning on the spatial and

temporal dimensions this section describes results on the analysis of price and

marketing margin. The form dimension represents the final product has different

form compared to its sale by farmers or in other words the final product has value

added. The form dimension is relatively complex since it involves several participants

in the market, which are not included in the survey such as processing firms,

therefore it is not covered in this analysis.

Degree of access to market influences price level, marketing margin (price spread)

and its variability. Villages with higher access to market are expected to receive

higher prices for producer prices and pay lower prices for consumer prices. With

regard to the price variability, it can be expected that remote villages will have higher

variability in producer price and lower variability in consumer prices.

80

Page 91: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

6.4.1 Seasonal price variability Seasonality is one of characteristic of agricultural activities. Different growing

season and harvesting time, consumption patterns, timely marketing period and as

well as prices are some features of this characteristic.

6.4.1.1 Seasonal price variability of fertilizer

Figures 6.1 and 6.2 show that prices of urea and NPK in year 2003 relatively stable.

According to explanation of agricultural officer in Palu, on average application of

fertilizer by the farmers in Central Sulawesi relatively low compared to other

provinces. There are not many differences in demand of fertilizers between planting

time and other seasons. No demand shock contributes to the stability of fertilizer

prices.

In the research area, prices for different fertilizer can be gathered only in two villages,

Bolapapu and Berdikari. Bolapapu is village with good access to market meanwhile

Berdikari has low access to market, since market place is not available in this village.

Weeks in 2003

5249

4643

4037

3431

2825

2219

1613

107

41

Pric

e of

ure

a (R

p/kg

)

3000

2000

1000

0

Villages

berdikari

bolapapu

palu

Figure 6.1 Weekly price of urea (Rp/kg) in January-December 2003

81

Page 92: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

The lowest price in Berdikari was Rp 1050 but in Palu was Rp 1130. These two

prices cannot be compared because the lowest price in Berdikari occurred during

week 32-36, meanwhile there was no data available in Palu market. The highest price

in Berdikari is Rp 1300 and Rp 1250 in Palu. Similar to the case of urea, the lowest

prices of NPK in Berdikari and Palu cannot be comparable since data were not

available during weeks 30-36 in Palu market. The lowest and highest prices of NPK

are Rp 1520 and 2500 in Berdikari respectively. In Palu the lowest and highest prices

are Rp 1800 and Rp 1950.

The prices in Palu can be expected not excessively deviate from Berdikari, because

the prices in Berdikari could be the price in Palu without any calculation of

transportation costs. There are two possibilities in explaining this condition. First,

There is a mistake occurred in data collection process. Although respondent had been

asked to write the purchase price of urea in the village, he wrote the price regardless

the place where it is bought. Second, during those weeks, Indonesian government

through ministry of industry and trade together with ministry of agriculture launched

a fertilizer subsidy project for agricultural sector. Through ministerial decree of

industry and trade number 70/MPP/Kep/2/2003 and ministerial decree of agriculture

number 427/Kpts/TP.130/8/2003 the highest retail price of urea was set up Rp

52.500,00/zak or Rp 1.050,00/kg wherever it is bought.

Figures 6.1 and 6.2 show that prices of urea and NPK in Bolapapu were highest

during weeks 28-30. One possibility to explain those circumstances is those weeks

were harvesting time and it implied that the repayment of borrowed fertilizer should

be accomplished.

In Berdikari, seasonal spread of urea is relatively lower compared to NPK, where

during the peaks, price of urea rises up to 24% and 60% for NPK. In Bolapapu,

differential prices between the peak and the trough for urea are relatively similar to

Berdikari. The difference are 24% for Urea and 40% for NPK. Meanwhile, in Palu

both fertilizers seem to show relatively stabile almost the year, whereas the seasonal

spread between the two seasons around 10%.

82

Page 93: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Weeks in 2003

5249

4643

4037

3431

2825

2219

1613

107

41

Pric

e of

NP

K (R

p/kg

)

4000

3000

2000

1000

Villages

berdikari

bolapapu

palu

Figure 6.2 Weekly prices of NPK (Rp/kg) in January–December 2003

6.4.1.2 Seasonal price variability of cocoa

Cocoa is one of main cash crop in Central Sulawesi. It provides high contribution to

regional income and particularly to the household income since cocoa beans is one of

major exported commodity from this region.

In Central Sulawesi harvesting period of cocoa can be attained twice a year. The first

period is between September until December, and it produces highest production,

therefore it is called main crop. The second harvest is between March – July, it is

called intermediary or mid crop.

With regard to harvesting period, it allows to predict that the prices will decrease

during these two harvest times. In relation with supply side, in weeks 36 – 52 it is

expected that the prices might fall and during week 10 – 31 (in the mid crop) the price

will not decrease as deep as the main crop season.

83

Page 94: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

It can be seen from Figure 6.3 that prices of cocoa in the research area are

characterized by almost similar in timing of peaks and troughs. Figure 6.4 shows the

FOB (free on board) price from shipping port. This is used as proxy of world market

of cocoa. The figure shows that the FOB decreased in weeks 21 – 25. It shows that

on average the world cocoa price has similar trend to the local prices. It seems that

the local price follows the movement of the FOB price and do not follow the pattern

of harvesting time.

Since cocoa beans are exported commodity, one possibility to explain unusual

circumstance is looking at world market of cocoa. The world prices of cocoa were

influenced by supply and demand of world cocoa production, therefore the local

prices can not be estimated separately from prices, supply and demand of cocoa

world production.

Table 6.11 Lowest and highest cocoa price and seasonal gap (January-December 2003)

Cocoa producer price (Rp/kg) Villages Lowest Month Highest Month

Seasonal Spread

Mean 7800 14500 Tomado SD 447.21

October 500.00

April 6700

Mean 8000 16125 Sintuwu SD 353.55

June 853.91

February 8125

Mean 7700 13875 Sidondo II SD 447.21

November 853.91

February 6175

Mean 9687.50 16062.50 Maranata SD 375.00

September 1419.73

April 6375

Mean 8625 13775 Pandere SD 2625.99

June 263.00

March 5150

Mean 8000 16125 Rahmat SD 353.55

June 853.91

February 8125

Mean 8000 15750 Bolapapu SD 816.50

June

February 7750

Mean 10776 17038 Palu (FOB) SD 996.05

June 981.07

February 6261.85

84

Page 95: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Weeks in 2003

5249

4643

4037

3431

2825

2219

1613

107

41

Coc

oa p

rodu

cer p

rice

(Rp/

kg)

18000

16000

14000

12000

10000

8000

6000

Villages

sintuwu

berdikari

maranata

pandere

sidondo II

bolapapu

rahmat

tomado

Figure 6.3 Weekly price of cocoa (Rp/kg) in January- December 2003

Weeks in 2003

504542373330272421171410741

FOB

cac

ao (R

p/kg

) in

Cen

tral S

ulaw

esi

20000

18000

16000

14000

12000

10000

8000

Figure 6.4 Weekly FOB (Rp/kg) from Central Sulawesi shipping port in January-December 2003

85

Page 96: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Although peaks and troughs are relatively similar in all villages, different villages

have differences in seasonal spread. The biggest amplitudes during this year were

found in Rahmat and Sintuwu. The price during the peak was double than price in

the trough. Market site is not available in Sintuwu, however people from this village

can easily for selling their cocoa to Rahmat, the nearest village with a market. Since

Rahmat is accessible by car, it performs as a destination market for commodities from

Sintuwu, and as source of information for traders who operates in Sintuwu.

6.4.1.3 Seasonal price variability of coffee

Coffee is not an export commodity because it is mainly produced to support regional

demand. Prices of coffee received by farmers are not so high compared to cocoa

prices. Most of coffee trees still can be found in Bolapapu but in other villages, most

of trees have been replaced by cocoa.

Weeks in 2003

5249

4643

4037

3431

2825

2219

1613

107

41

Cof

fee

prod

ucer

pric

e (R

p/kg

)

9000

8000

7000

6000

5000

4000

3000

2000

1000

Villages

sintuwu

berdikari

maranata

pandere

bolapapu

rahmat

tomado

Figure 6.5 Weekly producer price of coffee (Rp/kg) in January-December 2003

There are variations of coffee prices in villages during January to December 2003.

During week 10 – 20 (early of March-middle of May), prices in Bolapapu, Maranata

86

Page 97: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

and Sintuwu were higher compared to the other weeks. The highest price was in

Bolapapu Rp 8000/kg. The biggest amplitude in the seasonal spread within a year

could be found in this village. The prices during the lack season were more than

double compared to the prices after the harvest season. The smallest amplitude could

be found in Tomado, a remote village. The prices during the lack season increased

33% than the prices after the harvest season.

Table 6.12 Lowest and highest coffee producer price and seasonal gap in January- December 2003

Coffee producer price (Rp/kg) Villages Highest Month

Seasonal Spread Lowest Month

Mean 3750 5000 Tomado SD 288.68

November 0

May 1250

Mean 3750 6625 Sintuwu SD 0

January 342.33

March 2875

Mean 3750 4750 Berdikari SD 238.05

October -

June 1000

Mean 4225 6375 Maranata SD 95.75

October 250

April 2150

Mean 3625 6031 Pandere SD 171.16

December 148.78

June 2406

Mean 3750 6625 Rahmat SD 0

January 342.33

March 2875

Mean 3675 8000 Bolapapu SD 537.74

September 0

March 4250

6.4.1.4 Seasonal price variability of rice

In the research area, the variety of rice varies from one village to another. There are

villages with many varieties available in it shops or markets and on the other hand

there are villages with limited varieties. In Bolapapu, respondent had reported only

prices of cimandi and IR 66 super was the only variety reported by respondent in

Tomado. Therefore, in order to make comparison, only two varieties from local and

high yielding variety (cimandi and IR 66 super, respectively) have been selected and

will be discussed. Price of rice could be gathered in two different marketing

participants, producer and consumer. Producer price is prices received by farmer

producers and consumer price is price paid by final consumers.

87

Page 98: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Producer price of cimandi could be collected in Sidondo II, Maranata, Pandere and

Bolapapu. The biggest amplitude in the seasonal spread within a year could be found

in Pandere with the price during the lean season was 50 % higher than after harvest

season. The smallest amplitude could be found in Bolapapu with differentiation price

during the two seasons was 17 %. Consumer prices of cimandi were gathered in all

villages and Palu. The similar condition for consumer prices were found, whereas the

biggest and smallest amplitudes occured in Pandere and Bolapapu where during the

lean season the price was 50 % higher than after harvest season.

The consumer price in Palu as central market and mostly as destination market of rice

from all villages is expected will be higher compare to all villages. From figure 6.7 it

can be seen that prices in Palu were higher compare to other villages and relatively

stabile with CV 7,43% during the year. The stability of prices in Palu is caused by

sufficiency stock of rice available in Palu. Rice from all villages in research area and

other regions flow to Palu.

Figure 6.7 shows that the consumer prices in the villages tended to increase from

early of the year except in Palu whereas at that time the prices were relatively stabile.

The highest price occurred in Pandere during week 9-17, one reason for this situation

was rural farm household exhausted stocks and became food buyer. In this season the

reversal flow from Palu to the village might occur and prices in the village became

higher compared to prices in the post-harvest periods.

88

Page 99: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Weeks in 2003

5249

4643

4037

3431

2825

2219

1613

107

41

Pro

duce

r pric

e of

cim

andi

rice

(Rp/

kg)

4000

3000

2000

1000

Villages

sintuwu

berdikari

maranata

pandere

sidondo II

bolapapu

Figure 6.6 Weekly producer price of cimandi rice (Rp/kg) in January-December 2003

Weeks in 2003

5249

4643

4037

3431

2825

2219

1613

107

41

Con

sum

er p

rice

of c

iman

di ri

ce (R

p/kg

)

4000

3000

2000

1000

Villages

sintuwu

berdikari

maranata

pandere

sidondo II

bolapapu

rahmat

palu

Figure 6.7 Weekly consumer price of cimandi rice (Rp/kg) in January-December 2003

89

Page 100: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 6.13 Lowest and highest price and seasonal spread of cimandi rice in January – December 2003

Price of cimandi rice (Rp/kg) Producer price Consumer (retail) price

Villages

Lowest Highest Seasonal Spread

Lowest Highest Seasonal spread

Mean 2281 3094 813 SD 62.50 62.50

Sintuwu

Month November April Mean 2125 2725 600 2375 3075 700 SD 0 205.40 125 68.47

Sidondo II

Month October March November April Mean 2016 2688 672 2172 2813 641 SD 31.25 125.00 31.25 125.00

Maranata

Month December April December April Mean 2000 3000 1000 2167 3250 1083 SD 0 0 72.17 153.09

Pandere

Month November July November April Mean 2250 2650 400 2520 2770 250 SD 0 57.74 83.67 44.72

Bolapapu

Month January June January October Mean 2344 3094 750 SD 62.50 62.50

Rahmat

Month December April Mean 2625 3125 500 SD 306.19 0

Palu

Month December April 386.47 IR 66 super is one of high yielding variety rice grown in Pandere, Maranata,

Berdikari and Tomado. Comparing to the local rice variety, cimandi, average prices

of IR 66 super were relatively lower. The biggest amplitude of producer price

occurred in Pandere with differential price between lean and harvest season was 50%.

In other village, the price during the lean season was 30 % higher than after harvest

season.

90

Page 101: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Weeks in 2003

5249

4643

4037

3431

2825

2219

1613

107

41

Pro

duce

r pric

e of

IR 6

6 (R

p/kg

)

3000

2800

2600

2400

2200

2000

1800

1600

1400

Villages

berdikari

maranata

pandere

sidondo II

Figure 6.8 Weekly producer price of IR 66 super rice (Rp/kg) in January-December 2003

Weeks in 2003

5249

4643

4037

3431

2825

2219

1613

107

41

Con

sum

er p

rice

of IR

66

(Rp/

kg)

4000

3000

2000

1000

Villages

sintuwu

berdikari

maranata

pandere

sidondo II

rahmat

palu

Figure 6.9 Weekly consumer price of IR 66 super rice (Rp/kg) in January-December 2003

91

Page 102: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 6.14 Lowest and highest consumer prices and seasonal spread of IR 66 super rice in January – December 2003

Price of IR 66 super rice (Rp/kg) Villages Producer price Consumer (retail) price

Lowest Highest Seasonal Spread

Lowest Highest Seasonal spread

Sintuwu Mean 2094 2953 859 SD 187.50 138.58 Month October April Tomado Mean 1410 2000 590 1800 2500 700 SD 201.25 0 273.86 - Month October July October July Pandere Mean 1875 2875 1000 2042 3000 958 SD 0 0 57.74 0 Month November July November July Rahmat Mean 2213 2953 740 SD 104.58 138.58 Month November April Palu Mean 2175 2800 625 SD 273.86 68.47 Month December September Prices in villages are commonly lower compared to those in urban market such as

Palu, however consumer price of IR 66 super tends to rise exceedingly in early of the

year particularly in Pandere and Sintuwu. The similar condition occurred in week 45-

50 whereas prices in the villages were higher compared to prices in Palu. The biggest

amplitude of consumer price in the seasonal spread within the year could be found in

Pandere with the price during the lean season was 50 % higher than after harvest

season. In these two periods, reverse direction of rice from Palu to the villages could

be one reason for the high prices.

6.4.1.5 Seasonal price variability of sugar

As it is expected, price of sugar in the villages were higher compared to the price in

Palu since the flow of sugar move from Palu to those villages. The prices in

Berdikari were not included in the figure and in the analysis because of unreliability

of the data.

92

Page 103: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

The biggest amplitude in the seasonal spread during the year occurred in Sidondo II

with the differential price between the lowest and the highest reached up to 40%. In

Sidondo II, the lowest price was Rp 4125/kg and the highest was Rp 5625/kg.

However the highest price was Rp 6000/kg occurred in Tomado. Since the lowest

price in Tomado Rp 5167/kg, the amplitude between the peak and the trough was 1,2

times or the increasing price between the two level of prices was 20%.

Table 6.15 Lowest and highest consumer prices and seasonal spread of sugar in January – December 2003

Sugar price (Rp/kg) Seasonal Villages Lowest Month Highest Month spread

Tomado Mean 5167 March 6000 September 833 SD 288.68 0 Sintuwu Mean 4333 January 5375 April 1042 SD 288.68 250 Sidondo II Mean 4125 January 5625 May 1500 SD 250 250 Maranata Mean 4013 January 4938 April 925 SD 62.92 125 Pandere Mean 4750 September 5940 March 1190 SD 0 134.16 Bolapapu Mean 4500 January 5875 July 1375 SD 0 250 Rahmat Mean 4038 January 5375 April 1337 SD 149.30 250 Palu Mean 4200 February 5125 May 925

SD 0 250

93

Page 104: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Weeks in 2003

5249

4643

4037

3431

2825

2219

1613

107

41

Sug

ar p

rice

(Rp/

kg)

7000

6000

5000

4000

3000

sintuwu

berdikari

maranata

pandere

sidondo II

bolapapu

rahmat

palu

tomado

Figure 6.10 Weekly consumer price of sugar (Rp/kg) in January-December 2003 6.4.1.6 Seasonal price variability of cooking oil Two types of cooking oil are gathered to capture various quality of product available

and consumed by the villagers. Super and medium quality of cooking oil prices were

collected during research time. Although classification has been created,

standardization of quality are various from village to village. For example in Sidondo

II, consumers can buy palm oil in special package (bottled) with a trademark or brand

and it is called as super quality of cooking oil. In other villages, super quality is oil

sold without any brand and un-bottled. Traders pour the oil directly to a plastic or

used bottle and it can be measured in kind of liter or kg. In order to get consistency

of measurement data, Sidondo II and Berdikari are excluded from the analysis.

94

Page 105: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 6.16 Lowest and highest consumer prices and seasonal spread of cooking oil super quality in January – December 2003

Price of cooking oil – super quality (Rp/kg) Villages Lowest Month Highest Month

Seasonal Spread

Mean 4167 6000 Tomado SD 288.68

March 0

December 1833

Mean 4217 7500 Sintuwu SD 635.09

January 0

October 3283

Mean 4238 6000 Maranata SD 25

October 0

February 1762

Mean 5060 6776 Pandere SD 155.56

February 162.23

July 1716

Mean 3905 4950 Rahmat SD 122.98

June 0

March 1045

Mean 3000 6000 Bolapapu SD 0

January 0

October 3000

Mean 4750 5500 Palu SD 288.68

March 273.86

September 750

Weeks in 2003

5249

4643

4037

3431

2825

2219

1613

107

41

Pric

e of

coo

king

oil-

supe

r qua

lity

(Rp/

kg)

8000

7000

6000

5000

4000

3000

2000

Villages

sintuwu

maranata

pandere

bolapapu

rahmat

palu

tomado

Figure 6.11 Weekly consumer price of cooking oil-super quality (Rp/kg) in January -December 2003

95

Page 106: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Figure 6.11 shows the timing of peaks and troughs of super quality of cooking oil in

all villages and in Palu. The biggest amplitude in the seasonal spread within the year

could be found in Bolapapu. The prices during the peak reached up to double or was

100 % higher than the trough. The smallest amplitude occurred in Palu with the

differential price between the two conditions was around 10%. For medium quality of

cooking oil the biggest amplitude during the year took place also in Bolapapu. The

differential price between the peak and the though was 80%.

Table 6.17 Lowest and highest consumer (retail) prices and seasonal spread of cooking oil - medium quality in January – December 2003

Price of cooking oil – medium quality (Rp/kg) Villages Lowest Month Highest Month

Seasonal spread

Mean 3667 4250 Tomado SD 0

March 288.68

May 583

Mean 3850 5000 Sintuwu SD 0

May 0

October 1150

Mean 4875 6000 Sidondo II SD 750

September 0

May 1125

Mean 4000 6000 Maranata SD 0

October -

February 2000

Mean 4125 6215 Pandere SD 0

February 150.62

July 2090

Mean 3850 4455 Rahmat SD 0

September 122.98

June 605

Mean 3300 5913 Bolapapu SD 0

January 275

November 2613

Mean 4480 5500 Palu SD 204.94

April 500.00

September 1020

96

Page 107: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Weeks in 2003

5249

4643

4037

3431

2825

2219

1613

107

41

Pric

e of

coo

king

oil-

med

ium

qua

lity

(Rp/

kg)

8000

7000

6000

5000

4000

3000

Villages

sintuwu

maranata

pandere

sidondo II

bolapapu

rahmat

palu

tomado

Figure 6.12 Weekly consumer price of medium cooking oil (Rp/kg) in January -December 2003

6.4.2 Spatial price variability

Table 6.18 shows distribution of producer price for different commodities. The

distribution is classified into three groups based on degree to market access, low,

medium or high. Central market is not included since producer price in this study is

defined as price received by producer in farm gate or in local market.

Spatial or location of producer will influence price received as well as its variability.

The lower degree of market access, the producer prices will be lower and the

variability will be higher.

Among three groups, cocoa prices are high in villages with good access to market.

With rising distance from Palu central market, the cocoa prices are getting lower.

The lowest prices received by farmers in remote village. Cocoa in exported prices

97

Page 108: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

(free on board) is collected to compare with the prices in village prices. Starting from

the lowest access to market, average prices of cocoa are (in Rp/kg) 10.063, 10.757,

11610 and 13.200, respectively.

One-way ANOVA is used to observe significances of the differences in average

prices for each group. Before proceeds the ANOVA the SPSS produce automatically

Levene´s statistic to calculate the equality (homogeneity) of variances in the different

groups. Under this test, the significant value (0,138) is not significant which means

that equal variances are assumed. Under the assumption of homogeneity of variances,

the ANOVA results that the average prices between groups are significantly different

at one percent significance level. Nevertheless, this value does not exactly provide

information which average are significantly different to which other average prices.

Coefficient of Variation (CV) is calculated to observe the variability in the prices.

Contrary to the average price levels, variability of cocoa shows expected

phenomenon that remote villages will have higher variability of prices. The values of

CV arise from 18,73% in central market, 21,73% in villages with good access to

market, 22,54% in villages with low access to market and the highest is 28,45% in the

remote area.

Producer price of coffee shows similar phenomenon as cocoa. The price levels are

lowest in the remote area and in villages with good access to market the price levels

are higher. Since the Levene´s statistics give significant value at one percent level, the

assumption of homogeneity variances are violated. One–way ANOVA under this

condition (equal variances not assumed) shows that the differences in price levels

between groups are highly significant at one percent level.

However, the variability of coffee prices shows an opposite as it is expected. The

variation in prices in rural area is the lowest compared to the other groups. This

remote area cannot be reached by car and does not have market. The remoteness

arrives at low competition between traders compared to what occurred in adjacent or

urban area.

98

Page 109: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 6.18 Producer Price Distribution

Degree of Market Access Price (Rp/kg) Low

(Group 1) Medium

(Group 2) High

(Group 3) Mean 10062.5 (*) 10757.14 (*) 11610.43 (*) SD 2862.64 2425.13 2522.826 CV 28.45 % 22.54 % 21.73 %

Cocoa

N 40 140 211

Mean 4162.5 (*) 4641.32 (*) 4929.80 (*) SD 523.64 909.24 1146.043 CV 12.58 % 19.59 % 23.25 %

Coffee

N 40 72 211

Mean - 2275.85 (*) 2482.40 (*) SD - 250.39 294.249

Membramo rice

CV - 11.00 % 11.85 %

Mean - 2272.03 (*) 2543.48 (*) SD - 241.18 357.67

Kepala rice

CV - 10.62 % 14.06 %

Mean - 1809.09 (*) 2274.38 (*) SD - 199.78 283.914

IR 46 rice

CV - 11.04 % 12.48 %

Mean - 2074.6 (*) 2275.97 (*) SD - 245.61 284.138

IR 66 rice

CV - 11.84 % 12.48 %

Mean 1733.75 (*) 1934.38 (*) 2280.83 (*) SD 279.74 208.02 280.83 CV 16.13 % 10.75 % 12.31 %

IR 66 super rice

N 40 44 103 CV is calculated as (standard deviation/mean)*100 (*) between groups difference statistically significant at the one per cent level

In the research area, the variety of rice varies from one village to another. There are

villages with many varieties available in it shops or markets; on the other hand there

are villages that the traders sell only one or two varieties. Therefore only one variety

(IR 66 super) can be comparable in all groups. The lowest producer price level and

the highest variability of IR 66 super are found in remote area. In villages with good

access to market (group 3) farmers receive higher prices. The average price level

99

Page 110: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

(Rp/kg) is 1733 in remote area, 1934 and 2280 in villages with medium and high

access to market, respectively. The Levene´s statistics results on assumption of equal

variances are violated therefore equal variances not assumed is selected in the

subsequently step of analyses. One-way ANOVA shows that the price levels are

significantly different between groups at one percent level of significance.

Table 6.19 shows distribution of consumer prices for different basic food items and

fertilizers. Flow of food items and fertilizers, which are not produced in the villages

such as sugar, generally moves from central market to rural area. Therefore, it can be

expected that the prices in villages will be higher compared to central market.

However, there are also basic food items which villages can sufficiently produced and

enough to be consumed by the villagers, such as rice. Referring to the equation

presented in the methodology, variability of consumer price is expected will be higher

in central market and decrease according to distance to this market.

Price of sugar in remote area is the highest and the lowest is in central market. Under

condition of equal variance not assumed, the differences of average price between

groups are highly significant at one percent significance level. Variability of sugar

prices in remote village is the lowest. The consumer price in the remote village are

relatively higher compared to other villages, therefore it contributes to produce the

price variability which is relatively low.

Two types of cooking oil are gathered to capture various quality of product available

and consumed by the villagers. Super and medium quality of cooking oil prices are

collected during research time. Although classification has been created,

standardization of quality are various from village to village. In one village, Sidondo

II, consumers can buy palm oil in special package (bottled) with a trademark or brand

and it is called as super cooking oil. In other villages, super quality is oil sold without

any brand and un-bottled. Traders pour the oil directly to a plastic or used bottle and

it can be measured in liter or kg. In order to get consistency of measurement, data

from Sidondo II is excluded from the table.

100

Page 111: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

The average prices for cooking oil seem to be inconsistent. It might be occurred due

to different opinion on the quality. The prices in remote village are lower compared

to the central market. Therefore, calculation of variability for super and medium

quality seems to be inconsistent.

In the research area, prices of fertilizer (Urea and NPK) can be gathered only in

Berdikari and Bolapapu. These two villages can be used as representative of villages

that have low and good access to market. Although Berdikari is a village with low

access to market (group 2) because market site is not available, this village has good

access to road therefore people from this village can be easily purchase different

fertilizer from nearest market or even from Palu. It can be seen from the table that

prices are lower compared to Bolapapu and almost similar to the Palu prices. A

reason for lower fertilizer prices in Berdikari is that reported prices are simply prices

without any additional costs such as transportation cost.

Differential prices between Palu and Bolapapu are caused by transport cost and other

cost involved in transporting fertilizer in these two regions and unique system applied

in fertilizer trade. In Bolapapu there are 2 alternatives available for purchasing

fertilizers, cash or credit. Most of the farmers in this village choose the second

alternative to acquire fertilizers. In other words credit is the most favoured system in

the village. According to explanation of fertilizer trader and respondent, the common

fertilizer applied by most of people in the village is urea. In the planting time,

farmers receive a loan in kind of fertilizers from the shop and the repayment will be

accomplished in harvesting time and it charges 1 kg rice for 1 kg urea.

101

Page 112: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 6.19 Consumer Price Distribution Degree of Market Access Price

(Rp/kg) Low (Group 1)

Medium (Group 2)

High (Group 3)

Central Market (Group 4)

Mean 5837.50 (*) 4743.57 (*) 4764.45 (*) 4588.10 (*) SD 327.92 550.63 515.791 352.138

Sugar

CV 5.62 % 11.61 % 10.83 % 7.68 % Mean 4727.27 (*) 6709.06 (*) 5237.52 (*) 5062.79 (*) SD 516.76 1683.61 994.358 412.324 CV 10.93 % 25.09 % 18.96 % 8.14 %

Super cooking oil

N 33 80 206 43 Mean 3975 (*) 5754.14 (*) 4837.09 (*) 4779.07 (*) SD 251.92 1442.66 825.225 433.457

Medium cooking oil

CV 6.34 % 25.07 % 17.06 % 9.07 % Mean - 2682.68 (*) 2713.77 (*) 2919.19 (*) SD - 294.5 285.371 197.799

Membramo rice

CV - 10.98 % 10.52 % 6.78 % Mean - 2685.16 (*) 2780 (*) 2919.19 (*) SD - 289 291.06 197.799

Kepala rice

CV - 10.76 % 10.47 % 6.78 % Mean - 2434.9 (*) 2499.68 (*) 2720.35 (*) SD - 403.53 286.397 228.234

IR 46 rice

CV - 16.57 % 11.46% 8.39 % Mean - 2477.07 ** 2480.33 ** 2584.88 (**) SD - 294.9 290.33 249.114

IR 66 rice

CV - 11.91 % 11.71 % 9.64 % Mean 2203.75 2384.23 (*) 2480.33 (*) 2578.49 (*) SD 310.58 357.23 304.125 250.035

IR 66 super rice

CV 14.09 % 14.98 % 12.26 % 9.70 % Mean - 2624.12 (*) 2625.36 (*) 3020.35 (*) SD - 286.63 261.844 224.404

Cimandi

CV - 10.92 % 9.97 % 7.43 % Mean - 2618.02 (*) 2662.04 (*) 2884.3 (*) SD - 287.1 231.48 195.09

Buri-buri rice

CV - 10.97 % 8.70 % 6.76 % Mean - 1206.84 (*) 2628.18 (*) 1201.16 (*) SD - 82.252 117.364 32.893

Urea

CV - 6.82 % 4.47 % 2.74 % Mean - 2000.13 (*) 2978.18 (*) 1855.81 (*) SD - 272.852 190.215 52.064

NPK

CV - 13.64 % 6.39 % 2.81 % CV is calculated as (standard deviation/mean)*100 (*) between groups difference statistically significant at the one per cent level (**) between groups difference statistically significant at the ten per cent level Number of observations for Group 1, 2, 3 and 4 are 40, 140, 211 and 43, respectively and otherwise is directly pointed out in the table.

102

Page 113: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

6.5 Econometrics results on price variability Due to some missing data, not all commodities prices in all villages can be analysed.

Cocoa and two varieties of rice are selected to represent the important commodities in

the research area particularly for perennial and annual crops. To observe the

variability in prices of food items, sugar is selected.

The underlying assumption of stationary time series data should be fulfilled before

attempting to use the data in the analysis. Before estimating the variables using

ARCH model, a diagnostic testing is applied. Dickey Fuller is used to test whether

the natural logarithm of prices of cocoa, rice and sugar are stationary.

Tables 6.20, 6.21 and 6.22 shows the results from DF test. It should be noted that

the critical values are different for different models, without trend (only constant

variable) or with a trend variable in the right hand side. The tables below show that

the estimated t values in absolute value are higher than the critical value. This means

that in all villages the natural logarithm of price data reveals stationary series.

Table 6.20 Unit root test using Dickey-Fuller test for natural logarithm of weekly cocoa prices (number of observations = 51) Natural logaritm of cocoa prices

Trend variable

Test statistic (c = without

trend)

Test statistic (t = with trend)

Coefficient Std error LnFOB -1.610 -3.819 -.0044 .0013 LnTomado* -1.432 -1.562 -.0017 .0019 LnSintuwu -1.636 -1.853 -.0014 .0013 Ln Sidondo 2 -1.422 -2.155 -.0021 .0013 LnBolapapu -1.371 -1.674 -.0015 .0013 LnRahmat -1.515 -1.757 -.0014 .0013 Critical values for c at 1% = -2.405, 5% = -1.677 and 10% = -1.299 (N = 51) for t at 1% = -4.148, 5% = -3.499 and 10% = -3.179 (N = 51) for c at 1% = -2.426, 5% = -1.685 and 10% = -1.304 (N = 41) for t at 1% = -4.233, 5% = -3.536 and 10% = -3.202 (N = 41) * Number of observations of Tomado are 41

103

Page 114: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 6.20 shows that the natural logarithm of cocoa prices in all villages are

stationary. The test statistic for FOB prices shows that the time variable is

statistically significant. Therefore it can be concluded that the natural logarithm of

FOB prices is stationary around deterministic trend.

Almost all natural logarithm of rice prices is stationary except in Maranata. First

differences of the natural logarithm of prices series often remove the non-stationary

problem. Table 6.21 shows that the first differencing of the natural logarithm of rice

prices in Maranata, the test statistics for are less negative than negative critical value.

In other words, the first differences of natural logarithms of rice prices in Maranata

are stationary. The natural logarithm of rice prices in Sidondo2 and Tomado are

stationary around deterministic trend. Table 6.22 shows that natural logarithm of

sugar prices is stationary.

Table 6.21 Unit root test using Dickey-Fuller test for natural logarithm of weekly rice prices Natural logaritm

of rice prices Number of

observations Test statistic (c = without

trend)

Test statistic (t = with

trend)

Coefficient of trend variable*

Cimandi rice LnPalu 41 -2.691 -3.012 -.0010 (.0008) LnSidondo2 51 -2.083 -3.579 -.0018 (.0006) LnBolapapu 51 -2.375 -2.242 4.61e-06 (.0004)LnMaranata 51 -0.952 -2.706 -.0015 (.0006) First Diff of LnMaranata

50 -8.825 -8.792 -.0002 (.0003)

IR 66 Super rice LnPalu 41 -2.680 -2.871 -.0010 (.0009) Ln Tomado 41 -2.621 -3.512 -.0039 (.0017) Critical values for c at 1% = -2.405, 5% = -1.677 and 10% = -1.299 (N = 51) for t at 1% = -4.148, 5% = -3.499 and 10% = -3.179 (N = 51) for c at 1% = -2.426, 5% = -1.685 and 10% = -1.304 (N = 41) for t at 1% = -4.233, 5% = -3.536 and 10% = -3.202 (N = 41) * Standard error in paratheses

104

Page 115: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 6.22 Unit root test using Dickey-Fuller test for natural logarithm of weekly sugar prices (number of observations = 51) Natural logaritm of sugar prices

Trend variable

Test statistic (c = without

trend)

Test statistic (t = with trend)

Coefficient Std error LnPalu* -1.941 -2.268 -.0007 .0004 LnTomado* -3.486 -3.543 .0006 .0006 Ln Sidondo 2 -2.769 -2.824 .0005 .0007 LnMaranata -2.183 -2.303 -.0003 .0002 LnBolapapu -2.099 -2.382 .0007 .0006 LnRahmat -3.028 -3.039 -.0005 .0005 Critical values for c at 1% = -2.405, 5% = -1.677 and 10% = -1.299 (N = 51) for t at 1% = -4.148, 5% = -3.499 and 10% = -3.179 (N = 51) for c at 1% = -2.426, 5% = -1.685 and 10% = -1.304 (N = 41) for t at 1% = -4.233, 5% = -3.536 and 10% = -3.202 (N = 41) * Number of observations are 41

Before conducting diagnostic test for the presence of ARCH effect, Akaike

Information Criterion (AIC) is calculated to determine the lag length in the AR(p)

model. Afterwards, the analysis is followed by regression the equations which

contains the lag length as indicated by AIC using OLS. Most of the results show that

only the first or the second degree of autoregressive is statistically significant.

As seen in the figure of cocoa price movement in the previous sub chapter, it seems

that the cocoa price has a structural break. To cover this phenomenon, dummy

variable is created and included in the regression analysis. However, the coefficients

of dummy are not statistically significant. Therefore it is not included in the further

analysis.

According to the AIC, the lag length for cocoa in Bolapapu is AR(3), however only

AR(1) and AR(2) are statistically significant. AIC suggests the lag length for cocoa

in Rahmat is AR (3) and the OLS for this model is statistically significant. For sugar

in Sidondo2, the lag length is statistically significant until the optimal AR(2) as

suggested by AIC. Based on the DF test, trend variable is included in the diagnostic

test for rice in Sidondo2 and Tomado and for cocoa in Palu.

105

Page 116: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Diagnostic test for ARCH effects are conducted based on the procedure proposed by

Engle (1982) that is (1) run the original model AR(1) or AR(2) for lnprice in using

OLS; (2) save the residuals from the regression; (3) regress the squared residuals on a

constant and 1 lagged values of the squared residuals.

Diagnostic test for ARCH effects in the autoregressive AR(1), AR(2), with or without

trend variable are reported in Table 6.23, 6.24 and 6.25. Under the hypothesis of H0

= no ARCH effects and H1=ARCH(p) disturbance, the tables suggest that not all

series are subject to ARCH. The two varieties of rice in all areas show the

conditional variances are homoscedastic. The same results are found for sugar,

except in Sidondo2. The cocoa price series in Palu, Bolapapu and Rahmat shows that

the model follows an ARCH form, which means that the conditional error variance is

given by an ARCH(1) process or conditional variances are heterokedastic.

In the presence of ARCH effect, the analysis is continued to estimate the ARCH

model. All results is reported in Table 6.26 and 6.27.

Table 6.23 Diagnostic test on homoscedastic model for cocoa

Research area AR(p) LM test for Cocoa (df=1) (OLS) TR2 P > χ2

Palu 1 5.531 0.0187 Palu (trend) 1 6.861 0.0088 Bolapapu 1 8.341 0.0039 Bolapapu 2 10.125 0.0063* Rahmat 1 4.177 0.0410 Rahmat 3 0.693 0.4051 Sintuwu 1 1.219 0.2695 Sidondo2 1 0.024 0.8671 Tomado 1 0.031 0.8605 * df =2

106

Page 117: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 6.24 Diagnostic test on homoscedastic model for sugar Research area AR (p) LM test for sugar (df=1)

(OLS) TR2 P > χ2

Palu 1 0.023 0.8786 Bolapapu 1 0.310 0.5775 Rahmat 1 0.027 0.8689 Maranata 1 0.170 0.6801 Sidondo2 1 8.229 0.0041 Sidondo2 2 5.214 0.0224 Tomado 1 0.122 0.7271

Table 6.25 Diagnostic test on homoscedastic model for two varieties of rice*

Research area LM test for cimandi (df=1) LM test for IR 66 Super (df=1)

TR2 P > χ2 TR2 P > χ2

Palu 0.015 0.9028 0.003 0.9575 Bolapapu 0.541 0.4620 - - Maranata * 0.431 0.5115 - - Sidondo2 0.495 0.4817 - - Sidondo2 (trend) 0.023 0.8792 - - Tomado - - 0.011 0.9159 Tomado (trend) - - 0.065 0.7988 * The OLS analysis is based on AR(1) The point estimates in the mean and variance regression for AR(1) and AR(2) are

statistically significant for cocoa price in Bolapapu and sugar price in Sidondo2. The

slope in the mean equation estimates for the first and the second order autoregressive

indicates serially correlated prices. The coefficients on the lag variance are positive

and significant, indicating that residuals of current and previous periods are strongly

correlated. It shows the presence of conditional heteroscedasticity in error terms of

the mean equation.

107

Page 118: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table 6.26 Estimation of ARCH model for cocoa

Mean equation: Dependent variable is cocoa weekly prices

Independent variable

Palu Palu1 Bolapapu Bolapapu Rahmat

Constant 1.026 (0.521)

4.033 (1.145)

0.612 (0.326)

0.782 (0.221)

0.640 (0.419)

Lag (t-1) price

0.892 (0.551)

0.587 (0.117)

0.934 (0.035)***

1.218 (0.131)***

0.931 (0.045)

Lag (t-2) price

- - - -0.302 (0.122)**

-

Time trend - -0.004 (0.148)

- - -

Variance equation: Dependent variable is conditional variance in cocoa price Constant 0.005

(0.001) 0.003

(0.001) 0.003

(0.001) 0.0006

(0.0009) 0.005

(0.001) Lag (t-1) variance

0.076 (0.206)

0.312 (0.258)

0.561 (0.247)**

1.149 (0.124)***

0.279 (0.233)

Lag (t-2) variance

- - - 0.210 (0.125)**

-

1 Time trend is included in the equation * statistically significant at 90% level; ** statistically significant at 95% level *** statistically significant at 99% level

Table 6.27 Estimation of ARCH model for sugar

Mean equation: Dependent variable is sugar weekly prices Independent variable Sidondo2 Sidondo2

Constant 2.1743 (0.6442)*** 1.875 (0.614)** Lag (t-1) price 0.7455 (0.07511)*** 0.467 (0.154)** Lag (t-2) price - 0.313 (0.149)**

Variance equation: Dependent variable is conditional variance in cocoa price Constant 0.002 (0.0006)*** 0.0018 (0.006)*** Lag (t-1) variance 0.516 (0.2657)** 0.6787 (0.2449)* * statistically significant at 90% level; ** statistically significant at 95% level *** statistically significant at 99% level

6.6 Summary This chapter describes the following aspects of market performance: (1) communities

access to agricultural markets; (2) gross marketing margin and risk analysis; and (3)

108

Page 119: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

patterns of seasonal and spatial price variability of agricultural commodities in

relation to the degree of market access.

Road and market place are infrastructures in the villages which are used as proxy of

degree to market access. With regard to the two infrastructures, all villages can be

arranged into 3 groups, 1) not accessible by car and do not have market-low access;

2) accessible by car and do not have market-medium access; and 3) accessible by car

and the have market-good access. The fourth group is central market.

Gross marketing margin is measured by the difference between retail price paid by

final consumers and price received by farmer producers. Based on average price in

October 2003, gross margin of cocoa, rice in rural area and rice in central market are

21.43%, 22.91%, and 34.92%, respectively. The gross marketing margin shows

another concept of farmer share, that is the portion of the price paid by the consumer

that belongs to the farmer producers. Farmer share of cocoa, rice in rural and central

markets are 78.57%, 77.09% and 65.08%. The average gross marketing margin in

2003 for cocoa and cimandi rice are 16.90% and 17.88%.

Farmers are price takers who have limited control over price. If prices decrease

below the variable costs, it will hurt the farmer producers. The possible declines of

some commodities prices to cover per unit cost of production are more than 90% for

cocoa and coffee and up to more 60% for rice. Therefore it can be concluded that

there is no short-run downside risk faced by the farmers in the research area. The

short run down side risk for tree crops is low basically because most costs incurred

are fixed such as planting of trees and opportunity cost of land.

One of the shortcomings of the gross margin analysis is leaving the remuneration of

fixed factors such as family labour and land. In the long run, however, all costs

incurred in the production (variable and fixed) must be covered.

Seasonal variability of urea seems to be stabile almost the year with the seasonal

spread between the peak and the trough in the research area is less than 25%. The

price movement in cocoa shows that the time of peaks and troughs in all villages are

109

Page 120: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

relatively similar. However, seasonal spread is different between villages. The

biggest amplitude in 2003 was found in Rahmat and Sintuwu, whereas the price

during the peak was double than price in the trough. Price of coffee shows a seasonal

variability as indicated by the higher price in the lack season. Bolapapu has the

biggest amplitude with the price in the lack season reaches more than double

compared to the price after harvest. The biggest seasonal spread for two varieties of

rice, cimandi and IR 66 super is found in Pandere with the price during the lean

season was 50 % higher than the price after harvest season. The prices in Pandere in

some weeks were relatively higher compared to the price in Palu. In this season the

reversal flow from Palu to the village might occur and prices in the village became

higher compared to prices in Palu. The biggest seasonal spread of sugar occurred in

Sidondo II with the differential price between the lowest and the highest reached up

to 40%. However the highest price was Rp 6000/kg occurred in Tomado, a remote

village. Since the lowest price in Tomado Rp 5167/kg, the seasonal spread between

the peak and the trough was 20%. The lower value of seasonal spread in Tomado

occurred because the lowest price in this village is already higher compared to the

lowest price in other villages. The biggest seasonal spread of cooking oil is found in

Bolapapu. The price during the peak was 100 % higher than the trough. The smallest

amplitude occurred in Palu with the differential price between the peak and the trough

was around 10%.

In relation to the degree of access to market, cocoa prices are high in villages with

good access to market. With rising distance from Palu central market, the cocoa

prices are getting lower. The lowest prices received by farmers in remote village.

Starting from the lowest access to market, average prices of cocoa are (in Rp/kg)

10.063, 10.757, 11610 and 13.200, respectively. Under the assumption of

homogeneity of variances, the ANOVA results that the average prices between

groups are significantly different at one percent significance level.

Coefficient of Variation (CV) is calculated to observe the variability in the prices.

Variability of cocoa shows that remote villages have higher variability of prices. The

110

Page 121: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

values of CV arise from 18,73% in central market, 21,73% in villages with good

access to market, 22,54% in villages with low access to market and the highest is

28,45% in the remote area. The lowest producer price level and the highest

variability of IR 66 super are found in remote area.

Flow of food items which are not produced in the villages such as sugar, generally

moves from central market to rural area. Therefore, it can be expected that the prices

in villages will be higher compared to central market. Referring to the equation

presented in the methodology, variability of consumer price is expected will be higher

in central market and decrease according to distance to this market.

The average price of sugar in remote area is the highest and the lowest is in central

market. Under condition of equal variance not assumed, the differences of average

price between groups are highly significant at one percent significance level. The

variability of sugar prices in remote village is the lowest.

Another approach to observe variability is using time series analysis. Before

estimating the variables using econometric ARCH model, a diagnostic testing

(Dickey Fuller - DF test) is used to test whether the natural logarithm of prices of

cocoa, rice and sugar are stationary.

The DF test shows that the natural logarithm of cocoa prices in all villages are

stationary. When time variable is included in the analysis, only in the natural

logarithm of FOB the test is statistically significant. Therefore it can be concluded

that the natural logarithm of FOB prices is stationary around deterministic trend.

Almost all natural logarithm of rice prices is stationary except in Maranata. First

differences of the natural logarithm of thre Maranata prices series remove the non-

stationary problem. Natural logarithm of sugar prices are stationary.

Diagnostic test for ARCH (autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity) effects in

the autoregressive AR(1), AR(2), with or without trend variable are conducted

Under the hypothesis of H0 = no ARCH effects and H1=ARCH(p) disturbance, the

tests suggest that not all series are subject to ARCH. The two varieties of rice in all

111

Page 122: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

areas show the conditional variances are homoscedastic. The same results are found

for sugar, except in Sidondo2. The cocoa price series in Palu, Bolapapu and Rahmat

shows that the model follows an ARCH form, which means that the conditional error

variance is given by an ARCH(1) process or conditional variances are

heterokedastic.

In the presence of ARCH effect, the analysis is continued to estimate the ARCH

model. The point estimates in the mean and variance regression for AR(1) and AR(2)

are statistically significant for cocoa price in Bolapapu and sugar price in Sidondo2.

The slope in the mean equation estimates for the first and the second order

autoregressive indicates serially correlated prices. The coefficients on the lag

variance are positive and significant, indicating that residuals of current and previous

periods are strongly correlated. It shows the presence of conditional

heteroscedasticity in error terms of the mean equation.

112

Page 123: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

7. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS This chapter summarizes the findings in the relation with the research questions as

presented in the previous chapters and attempts to answer question on the policy

implications of the findings.

7.1 Major results

7.1.1 Agricultural market structure The agricultural market structure is explained either by flow of marketing channel,

market concentration or barrier to market entry. Due to some limitations of data,

structures of coffee, maize and fertilizer markets are described in term of flow of

marketing channel. Agricultural commodities markets are organized differently

depend on the characteristics of the commodity.

Cocoa beans are sold from the farmer producer to village or sub-district assemblers.

The Sub-district assemblers handle higher volume of cocoa than that by village

assemblers because they operate in some villages within a sub-district. The village

assemblers limit their procurement only in villages where they live. Market

destination (final consumers) of the beans is export market in Palu. Therefore, the

cocoa beans are then transported from the assemblers to wholesaler/municipal

assemblers in Palu before being exported.

Cocoa market is dominated by few large traders (sub-district assemblers) and exhibits

an oligopsonist market with regard to the farmer producers as indicated by Gini

coefficient and the concentration ratio (CR4). The Gini coefficient is of 0,78. The

Lorenz curve shows that the largest 20% of the traders account for about 80% of the

volume of cocoa traded in the research area. The concentration ratio of CR4 is 82 %.

It means that that the largest four of the traders in the sample accumulated market

share of 82% compared to all market participants in the cocoa market.

Different from cocoa which can be sold directly after drying without any further

process, rice should be milled, either manually or mechanically to remove its husks.

To meet the demand of local and urban consumers for this dominant staple food,

113

Page 124: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

there are two different markets for rice, local and urban markets. Therefore, rice is

traded not only in the local market but also transported to the urban market. After

milling, the farmer can sell their rice to local retailer or assembler.

Wholesaler/municipal assembler in Palu or other urban areas are the market

destination of the village and sub-district assemblers.

Rice market in the research area is composed of many traders and few of which are

large traders. Small retailers are operated in local market. For the rice traders in the

sample (village and sub-district assemblers and local village retailer), the CR4 is 86 %

and the Gini coefficient is 0,80. It is indicating an oligopsonist market with regard to

the farmer producers. The largest four rice traders accumulated 86% from total

market share of rice traders in the sample. The Lorenz curve shows that the largest

20% of the traders account for about 90% of the volume of rice traded in the research

area. The rest of the traders account for the remaining rice traded.

The cocoa and rice market shows an indication of an un-equal distribution and

concentrated market. This condition implies of less competitiion due to oligopsonist

nature. Technically speaking, it may lead to inefficiency. However, one should be

careful in interpreting this relationship. Other factors such as barrier to market entry

should be considered before making any judgment about the market condition.

Inequality also shows some extent economies of scale (as part of barrier to market

entry) where big traders are more efficient in term of costs occurred in trading

activities compared to the small ones. Transaction costs occurred in the trading

activities such as searching information and negotiation process which have fixed

cost character, give more advantages towards the big traders. Per-unit basis operation

at a large volume will be less expensive.

Compared to cocoa market which grow rapidly in the research area, markets for

coffee and maize are relatively thin. Market destination of coffee and maize are

limited either to the local consumers or to particular industry in Palu such as food

processing industry (coffee powder) or poultry. There are limited number of traders

engaged in the coffee and maize business in the research area. All maize traders in the

114

Page 125: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

research area are village assemblers who tend to limit their procurement operations of

the dried kernel maize to their own village.

Market for fertilizer is not well developed yet. Fertilizer retailers sell only in 2 out of

8 survey villages. Farmers occasionally purchase urea and other agricultural inputs by

cash in Palu when they sell their produce in this central market. For the fertilizer

traders marketing system of fertilizer can be described as a sort of vertical integration.

Retailers who operate in villages perform as rice miller too. The marketing system is

by giving loan to the farmers in kind of fertilizers, mainly urea and the payment will

be made during the harvest, directly after the milling process. Therefore, it provides a

controllable flow between input and output received.

The barrier to market entry can be defined as a potential factor that prevents the new

entrants from entering the market. Technically speaking, market licensing

requirement is one potential factor to market entry. Most traders reported that it is

relatively easy to be involved in agricultural trading as indicated by limited barrier to

market entry. The market license should be held only by big traders whose asset is

more than IDR 200 million.

7.1.2 Agricultural market conduct There are 36 selected traders in the research area involved in trading agricultural

commodities. In general the traders are relatively young with average age of 40 years

and educated. On average, 41.7 %, 30.5% and 27.8% of traders educated at primary,

secondary, and high school, respectively. One third of the traders come from family

with trading background and this gives an additional advantage as they receive

assistance from their parents such as equipments, working capital and knowledge of

entrepreneurships. More than half traders have employees who come from their

relatives. Big traders hire temporary employees during harvest season when huge

amount of produce should be handled.

Own capital is a main source of working capital. Only 25% from all traders have

storage facility which has multiple functions. Although telephone is important tool of

115

Page 126: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

communication particularly to search market information, only 8% of total traders use

it. Due to that fact, face-to-face communication is the most important source of

market information. Motorcycle is a transportation facility owned and commonly

used by almost all traders to collect and sell their stocks particularly to transport one

or two sack of their commodities.

No traders are member and involved in formal and informal organizations. Most

traders (69%) are local people, therefore relation with people surrounding their

environment is easier to be managed which in turn influence their success in

conducting their business.

For quantity inspection, weighing is done in the first process, and then it is followed

by simple quality inspection trough visual observation. Price paid by each trader is

determined independently. Cash is well known as payment method to farmers. Theo

other methods, credit and in kind (barter) can be done when long relationships

between trader and farmers are closely tied because for all these contractual

agreements, no written contract is provided. Thus close relation and trust between the

two participants are required precondition.

Traders tend not to specialize on one crop of five commodities surveyed, and not

fully specialized in marketing function performs in the marketing chain. For example,

one trader can perform as village assembler, owns milling machine, and at the same

time he/she retail rice in local market. Apart of trading, most traders have other

activities either in agricultural activity or non-farm enterprise.

More than two third of traders have regular suppliers and next buyers. New entrants

have difficulties of searching new supplier. The problem in searching new buyers is

more pronounced in food crops compared to cash crop.

Most traders collect their supplies within village where they reside. Only 14% travel

more than 10 km to purchase their supplies and this is conducted by large traders who

operate in various villages. Majority of traders travel more than 15 km to sell their

stock. None of traders in the villages are being a member of trade association such as

116

Page 127: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

ASKINDO = Asosiasi Kakao Indonesia, The Indonesian Cocoa Association). The

association consists only cocoa exporters as their member.

7.1.3 Agricultural market performance

Generally, farmers and traders in the research area differ in their access to market.

Degree of access to market is distinguished based on two criteria, 1) accessibility by

car, which connected those villages to the provincial capital city, Palu and 2) market

site operated in the villages. With regard to the two infrastructures, all villages can be

arranged into 3 groups, 1) low access - not accessible by car and do not have market;

2) medium - accessible by car and do not have market; and 3) high - accessible by car

and the have market. Central market is the fourth group.

Gross marketing margin is measured by the difference between retail price paid by

final consumers and price received by farmer producers. Based on average price in

October 2003, gross margin of cocoa, rice in rural area and rice in central market are

21.43%, 22.91%, and 34.92%, respectively. The gross marketing margin shows

another concept of farmer share, that is the portion of the price paid by the consumer

that belongs to the farmer producers. Farmer share of cocoa, rice in rural and central

markets are 78.57%, 77.09% and 65.08%. The average gross marketing margin in

2003 for cocoa and cimandi rice are 16.90% and 17.88%.

Farmers are price takers who have limited control over price. If prices decrease

below the variable costs, it will hurt the farmer producers. Since farmers face risk

that prices may lower than expected, calculation of the probability that price is below

break event point is important. The possible declines of some commodities prices to

cover per unit variable cost of production are more than 90% for cocoa and coffee

and up to more 60% for rice. Therefore it can be concluded that there is no short-run

faced by the farmers in the research area. The short run down side risk for tree crops

is low basically because most costs incurred are fixed such as planting of trees and

opportunity cost of land.

117

Page 128: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

One of the shortcomings of the gross margin analysis is leaving the remuneration of

fixed factors such as family labour and land. In the long run, however, all costs

incurred in the production (variable and fixed) must be covered.

Agricultural price commodities are seasonally volatile due to due to seasonal

characteristic of production and consumption patterns. Seasonal variability of urea

seems to be stabile almost the year with the seasonal spread between the peak and the

trough in the research area is less than 25%. The price movement in cocoa shows that

the time of peaks and troughs in all villages are relatively similar. However, seasonal

spread is different between villages. The biggest amplitude in 2003 was found in

Rahmat and Sintuwu, whereas the price during the peak was double than price in the

trough. Price of coffee shows a seasonal variability as indicated by the higher price

in the lack season. Bolapapu has the biggest amplitude with the price in the lack

season reaches more than double compared to the price after harvest. The biggest

seasonal spread for two varieties of rice, cimandi and IR 66 super is found in Pandere

with the price during the lean season was 50 % higher than the price after harvest

season. The prices in Pandere in some weeks were relatively higher compared to the

price in Palu. In this season the reversal flow from Palu to the village might occur and

prices in the village became higher compared to prices in Palu. The biggest seasonal

spread of sugar occurred in Sidondo II with the differential price between the lowest

and the highest reached up to 40%. However the highest price was Rp 6000/kg

occurred in Tomado, a remote village. Since the lowest price in Tomado Rp 5167/kg,

the seasonal spread between the peak and the trough was 20%. The lower value of

seasonal spread in Tomado occurred because the lowest price in this village is already

higher compared to the lowest price in other villages. The biggest seasonal spread of

cooking oil is found in Bolapapu. The price during the peak was 100 % higher than

the trough. The smallest amplitude occurred in Palu with the differential price

between the peak and the trough was around 10%.

In relation to the degree of access to market, cocoa prices are high in villages with

good access to market. With rising distance from Palu central market, the cocoa

118

Page 129: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

prices are getting lower. The lowest prices received by farmers in remote village.

Starting from the lowest access to market, average prices of cocoa are (in Rp/kg)

10.063, 10.757, 11610 and 13.200, respectively. Under the assumption of

homogeneity of variances, the ANOVA results that the average prices between

groups are significantly different at one percent significance level.

Coefficient of Variation (CV) is calculated to observe the variability in the prices.

Variability of cocoa shows that remote villages have higher variability of prices. The

values of CV arise from 18,73% in central market, 21,73% in villages with good

access to market, 22,54% in villages with low access to market and the highest is

28,45% in the remote area.

The lowest producer price of IR 66 super is found in the remote area. Villages with

good access to market receive higher producer prices. The highest variability is found

in the remote village.

In contrast to commodity prices, prices for basic food items in villages are relatively

higher. Food items that are not produced in the villages are transported from central

market to these areas, therefore prices for consumer goods are higher here. Referring

to the equation presented in the methodology, variability of consumer price is

expected will be higher in central market and decrease according to distance to this

market.

The average price of sugar in remote area is the highest and the lowest is in central

market. Under condition of equal variance not assumed, the differences of average

price between groups are highly significant at one percent significance level. The

variability of sugar prices in remote village is the lowest.

Another approach to observe variability is using time series analysis. Before

estimating the variables using econometric ARCH model, a diagnostic testing

(Dickey Fuller - DF test) is used to test whether the natural logarithm of prices of

cocoa, rice and sugar are stationary.

119

Page 130: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

The DF test shows that the natural logarithm of cocoa prices in all villages are

stationary. When time variable is included in the analysis, only in the natural

logarithm of FOB the test is statistically significant. Therefore it can be concluded

that the natural logarithm of FOB prices is stationary around deterministic trend.

Almost all natural logarithm of rice prices is stationary except in Maranata. First

differences of the natural logarithm of thre Maranata prices series remove the non-

stationary problem. Natural logarithm of sugar prices is stationary.

Diagnostic test for ARCH (autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity) effects in

the autoregressive process AR(1), AR(2), with or without trend variable are

conducted. Under the hypothesis of H0 = no ARCH effects and H1=ARCH(p)

disturbance, the tests suggest that not all series are subject to ARCH. The two

varieties of rice in all areas show that the conditional variances are homoscedastic.

The same results are found for sugar, except in Sidondo2. The cocoa price series in

Palu, Bolapapu and Rahmat shows that the model follows an ARCH form, which

means that the conditional error variance is given by an ARCH(1) process or

conditional variances are heterokedastic.

In the presence of ARCH effect, the analysis is continued to estimate the ARCH

model. The point estimates in the mean and variance regression for AR(1) and AR(2)

are statistically significant for cocoa price in Bolapapu and sugar price in Sidondo2.

The slope in the mean equation estimates for the first and the second order

autoregressive indicates serially correlated prices. The coefficients on the lag

variance are positive and significant, indicating that residuals of current and previous

periods are strongly correlated. It shows the presence of conditional

heteroscedasticity in error terms of the mean equation.

7.2 Policy Implications

Analysis of agricultural markets and the way prices behave provide valuable insight

into the observation whether markets work efficiently and give benefit in particular to

all participants in the markets and in general for the whole society. According to the

120

Page 131: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

findings and the results of some statistical and econometrical measurements, there are

some policy implications might be applicable to improve market performance and its

welfare impacts.

1) Farmers in the remote area receive low agricultural prices and pay higher basic

food prices compared to other villages that have better access to markets. The

variability in the producer prices exhibits a similar phenomenon, where the remote

area has higher variability. Based on those phenomena, intervention of government is

required to reduce the price levels and the variability. Development of infrastructure

such as road is necessary to support the flow of either commodities from producer

area to consumers in the urban market or basic food product from urban market to the

villages.

2) The downside risk analysis shows that there is no downside risk in the short run

faced by the farmer producers. The possible decline of prices to cover per unit

variable cost of production are quite high. On average, cocoa, coffee and rice prices

can drop by more than 60% from the average prices. Since only variable cost is

included in the calculation of downside risk, the possible declining of prices are quite

high. However, one should be careful to interpret this result. There are also fixed

costs occurred in the production process, but they are not covered by the analysis.

In the long run production process, the two costs should be covered. Therefore, for

further research it is necessary to cover not only variable but also fixed costs in the

analysis.

3. Due to some limitations in applying structure-conduct-performance (SCP)

paradigm to analyse market condition, the further research on alternative approaches

of market analysis such as transaction costs theory can be considered.

121

Page 132: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

REFERENCES

Abott, John. 1993. “Marketing, the rural poor and sustainability” In: Abott, J.C. (ed) Agricultural and Food Marketing in Developing Countries: Selected readings. CTA. The Netherlands.

Ahmed, Raisuddin. 1988. “Pricing Principles and Public Intervention in Domestic Markets” In: Mellor, J.W. and R. Ahmed. 1988. Agricultural Price Policy for Developing Countries. Johns Hopkins University Press. Baltimore.

Ahmed, Raisuddin and Narendra Rustagi. 1987. Marketing and Price Incentives in African and Asia Countries: A Comparison. In: Elz, Dieter (Ed). In Agricultural Marketing Strategy and Pricing Policy. International Bank for Reconstruction and Development. Washington DC.

Akiyama, Takamasa., and Akihiko Nishio. 1996. “Indonesia´s Cocoa Boom: Hands-Off Policy Encourages Smallholder Dynamism”. Policy Research Working Paper 1580. The World Bank.

Alderman , H., and G. Shively. 1996. “ Economic Reform and Food Prices: Evidence from Market in Ghana”. World Development 24.

Anderson, J.R., J. Dillon, J.B. Hardaker. 1977. Agricultural Decision Analysis. The Iowa State University Press. Ames. Iowa.

Anderson, J.R., and J. Dillon. 1992. Risk Analysis in Dry Land Farming System.FAO. Rome.

Aradhyula, S.V, and M.T. Holt. “GARCH Time Series Model: An Application to Retail Livestock Prices”. Western Journal of Agricultural Economics 13.

Bain, Joseph S, 1956. Industrial organization. John Wiley and Son, New York.

Badiane, O., F. Goletti, M. Kherallah, 1997. Agricultural Input and Output: Marketing Reform in African Countries. Final Donor Report. IFPRI: Washington D.C.

Barret, C. 1996. “Urban Bias in Price Risk: The Geography of Food Price Distributions in Low-Income Economies”. The Journal of Development Studies 32.

Baulch, Bob. 1997. “Transfer Costs, Spatial Arbitrage, and Testing for Food Market Integration”. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79.

Bernard, Russel H. 2000. Social Research Methods. Qualitative and Quantitative Approaches. Sage Publications. London.

Binswanger, H.P., and M. Rosenzweig. 1986. “Behavioral and Material Determinants of Production Relations in Agriculture”. The Journal of Development Studies 22.

122

Page 133: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Black, Thomas R. 1999. Doing Quantitative Reseach in the Social Sciences. An Integrated Approach to Research Design, Measurement and Statistics. Sage Publications. London.

Central Sulawesi Bureau for Statistics. 2003. Gross Regional Domestic Product Statistics. http://sulteng.bps.go.id/pdrb.htm

Colman, D., and T. Young. 1997. Principles of Agricultural Economics Markets and Prices in Less Developed Countries. Cambridge University Press. UK.

Crawford, I.M. 1997. Agricultural and Food Marketing Management. FAO. Rome

Dessalegn, G., T.S. Jayne, and J.D. Shaffer, 1998, Market Structure, Conduct and Performance: Constraints on Reform of Ethiopian Grain Market. Working Paper 8. Grain Market Research Project. Addis Abeba.

Ellis, F. 1992. Agricultural Policies in Developing Countries. Cambridge University Press. Cambridge.

Engle, R. 1982. “Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity with Estimates of the Variance of United Kingdom Inflations. Econometrica 50 No 4 (July 1982): 987-1008.

Fafchamps, M. 1992. Cash Crop Production, Food Price Volatility, and Rural Market Integration in the Third World. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 74 (1): 90-99.

Fergusson, R. and Glenys J. Fergusson. 1994. Industrial Economics: Issues and Perspectives . The Macmillan Press. Hampsire.

Gujarati, D. 2003. Basic Econometrics 4th Edition. Mc Graw-Hill. New York.

Green, William H. 2000. Econometric Analysis. 4th Edition. Prentice Hall. New Jersey.

Hardaker, J.B., R.B.M. Huirne, and J.R. Anderson. 1997. Coping with Risk in Agriculture. CAB International. Oxon.

Harris-White, B. 1993. “There is Method in My Madness: or is it Vice Versa? Measuring Agricultural Market Performance” In: Abott, J.C. (ed) Agricultural and Food Marketing in Developing Countries: Selected readings. CTA. The Netherlands.

Holt, M. T. , and S.V. Aradhyula. 1990. “Price Risk in Supply Equation: Model: An Application of GARCH Time Series Models to the US Broiler Market”. Southern Economic Journal 57.

Jabbar, M.A, Tambi and Mullins. 1997. A Methodology for characterizing dairy marketing systems. ILRI. Nairobi.

Janssen, W.G and Aad van Tilburg. 1997. “Marketing Analysis for Agricultural Development: Suggestion for a New Research Agenda” In: Wierenga, Berend ,

123

Page 134: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

et al. Agricultural Marketing and Consumer Behaviour in a Changing World. Kluwer Academic Publishers. London.

Kahlon, A.S., and George M.V. 1985. Agricultural Marketing and Price Policies. Alllied Publ. Private. New Delhi.

Kohls, R.L. and N.U. Uhl. 1990. Marketing of Agricultural Product, 7th edn. Macmillan, New ork.

Kotler, P. 1994. Marketing Management: Analysis, Planning and Control, 8 edn. Prentice-Hall.nglewood Cliffs, NJ.

Makridakis, S., S.C. Wheelwright, R.J. Hyndman. 1998. Forecasting: Method and Applications. John Wiley and Sons. New York.

McNew, K. 1996. Spatial Market Integration: Definition, Theory and Evidence. Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 25 (April 1996): 1-11.

Mellor, John. 1969. “Agricultural Price Policy in the Context of Economic Development”. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 5.

Mendoza, M.S and M.W. Rosegrant. 1995. “ Pricing Conduct of Spatially Differentiated Markets”, In: Scott, Gregory J.(Ed). Prices, products and people: Analyzing Agricultural Market in Developing Countries. Boulder. London.

Mendoza, M.S and M.W. Rosegrant. 1995. “ Pricing behaviour in Philippine corn markets : Implications for Market Efficiency . Research report 102. International Food Policy Research Institute. Washington D.C.

Mendoza, M., and C. Randrianarisoa. 1998. Structure and Behavior of Traders and Market Performance. In Structure and Conduct of Major Agricultural Input and Output Markets and Respons to Reforms by Rural Households in Madagascar. Final Donor Report to USAID. IFPRI-FOFIFA. Washington DC.

Menezes, C., C. Geiss, and J. Tressler. 1980. “ Increasing Downside Risk”. American Economic Review 70.

Minten, Bart. 1999. Infrastructure, Market Access, and Agricultural Prices. MSSD Discussion Paper No 26. IFPRI. Washington DC.

Park, A., H. Jin, S. Rozelle, and J. Huang. 2002. Market Emergence and Transition: Arbitrage, Transaction costs, and Autarky in China’s Grain Market. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 84 (Februry 2002): 67-82.

Pepall, Lynne, D.J. Richards, and G. Norman. 2002. Industrial Organization: Contemporary Theory and Practice. South Western. Ohio.

Pomeroy, R.S., and A.C. Trinidad, 1995. “ Industrial organization and Market Analysis”, In: Scott, Gregory J. (Ed). 1995. Prices, products and people: Analyzing Agricultural Market in Developing Countries. Boulder. London.

Ritson, C. 1997. Agro-food marketing. CAB International. Oxon.

124

Page 135: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Rhodes, V.J and J.L Dauve. 1998. 5th Edition. The Agricultural Marketing System. Holcomb Hathaway. Arizona.

Robison, Lindon J., and Beverly Fleisher. 1984. Decision Analysis in Agricultural Setting: An Introduction. Agricultural Economocs Report. Michigan State University.

Sahn, D., and C. Delgado. 1989. “The Nature and Implication for Market Interventions of Seasonal Food Price Variability.” Seasonal Variability in Third World Agriculture: The Consequences for Food Security. D. Sahn, ed. The Johns Hopkins University Press. Baltimore

Scott, Gregory J.(Ed). 1995. Prices, products and people: Analyzing Agricultural Market in Developing Countries. Boulder. London

Schwarze, Stefan. 2004. Determinants of Income Generating Activities of Rural Households - A Quantitative Study in the Vicinity of the Lore Lindu National Park in Central Sulawesi/Indonesia. Ph.D thesis, Institute of Rural Development, University of Goettingen, Germany.

Sexton, R. J., C. King and H. F. Carman. 1991. Market Integration, Efficiency of Arbitrage, and Imperfect Competition: Methodology and Application to US Celery. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 73 (August): 568-580.

Shively, G. E. 1996. “Food Price Variability and Economic Reform: An ARCH Approach for Ghana”. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 78 (February): 126-136.

Stiglitz, J.E. 1997. Principles of Microeconomics. Norton. New York

Wanwali, Sudhir. 1992. Rural Infrastructure, the Settlemet System and Development of the Regional Economy in Southern India. Research Report 91. IFPRI. Washington DC.

Timmer, P. 1986. Getting Prices Right: The Scope and Limits of Agricultural Price Policy. Cornell University Press. New York.

Tomek, W.G., and K.L. Robinson. 2003. Agricultural Product Prices. Cornell University Press. Itacha.

Waldman, Don E., and E. J. Jensen. 1998. Industrial Organization: Theory and Practice. Addison-Wesley. Massachusetts.

Williamson, O.E. 1975. Market and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York. Free Press.

Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. 2003. Introductory Econometrics-A Modern Approach. Thomson South Western. Ohio. USA.

World Bank. 2005. Data and Statistics on Indonesia. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTINDONESIA/Resources/Country-Data/National_Inc_Accts.pdf

125

Page 136: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Zeller, Manfred and B. Minten (Ed). 2000. Beyond Market Liberalization. Ashgate Publishing. England.

Zeller, Manfred, S. Schwarze, T. van Rheenen. 2002. Statistical Sampling Frame and Methods Used for the Selection of Villages and Households in the Scope of the Research Programme on Stability of Rain Forest Margins in Indonesia. STORMA Discussion Paper Series No. 1. Bogor, Indonesia.

126

Page 137: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

APPENDICES Table A1 Producer prices (Rp/kg), standard deviation and variability for different commodities in January–December 2003

Rice Village Cocoa CoffeeMembramo Cimandi IR 46 IR 66 IR 66 S Kepala

Mean 10115.38 4166.67 1739.74 SD 2880.2

526.81 280.78 Tomado

CV 28.47 12.64 16.14 Mean 11321.43 5172.79 2169.64 2000.00 2000.00SD 2747.11 1036.17 151.97 117.85 0.00

Sintuwu

CV 24.26 20.03 7.00 5.89 0.00 Mean 4158.33 2060 2048 1809.09 1900.00 1809.09 2130.56 SD 376.17 187.08 180.56 199.78 212.13 199.78 203.99

Berdikari

CV 9.05 9.08 8.82 11.04 11.16 11.04 9.57 Mean 10057.69 2379.81 2379.81 2179.09 2159.72 2379.81SD 2383.88 232.16 232.16 216.16 32.94 232.16

Sidondo II

CV 23.70 9.76 9.76 9.92 1.53 9.76Mean 12884.69 5322.45 2434.95 2294.64 2195.05 2198.98 2204.08 SD 2189.18 734.43 235.92 219.86 212.74 219.37 215.67

Maranata

CV 16.99 13.80 9.69 9.58 9.69 9.98 9.79 Mean 11330.00 4619.44 2541.67 2541.67 2377.78 2377.78 2377.78 2541.67SD 1927.95 947.66 361.5 361.5 334.44 334.44 334.44 361.5

Pandere

CV 17.02 20.51 14.22

14.22 14.07

14.07

14.07

14.22 Mean 11203.85 5080.77 2473.08

SD 2845.70 1593.62 175.86Bolapapu

CV 25.40 31.37 7.11Mean 10807.69 4921.87 SD 2740.68 978.23

Rahmat

CV 25.36 19.88 Mean 13200.58

SD 2474.30Palu

CV 18.74

127

Page 138: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table A2 Consumer prices (Rp/kg), standard deviation and variability for different commodities in January–December 2003

Rice Village Sugar Superveg oil

Medium veg oil Buri-buri Cimandi IR 46 IR 66 IR 66 S Kepala Mem-

bramo Mean 5833.33 4687.5 3974.36 2208.97 SD 331.13

470.93 255.18 312.85 Tomado

CV 5.68 10.05 6.42 14.16 Mean

4852.38 5557.74 4390.48 2631.71 2657.81 2716.35 2694.44 2552.42 2870.69 2937.50

SD 366.42 1417.70 487.03 296.46 294.51 195.44 222.89 335.45 256.57 161.05Sintuwu

CV 7.55 25.51 11.09 11.27 11.08 7.19 8.27 13.14 8.94 5.48Mean 4286.11 8025.00 7582.50 2378 2378 2102.27 2260.61 2112.50 2502.08 2373SD 433.69 811.14 1283.72 291.93 291.93 324.03 335.06 314.03 314.61 286.31

Berdikari

CV 10.12 10.11 16.93 12.28 12.28 15.41

14.82 14.87 12.57 12.07Mean 5067.31 5725.96 2702.87 2725.96 2519.23 2500 2725.96 2725.96SD 514.77 493.238 226.11 230.94 220.551 88.39 230.94 230.94

Sidondo II

CV 10.16 8.61 8.37

8.47 8.75 3.54 8.47 8.47Mean 4556.12 5380.61 4796.94 2443.88 2385.42 2327.81 2133.52 2595.66 SD 290.59 674.68 531.35 215.47 264.64 243.25 116.2 248.73

Maranata

CV 6.38 12.54 11.08 8.82 11.09 10.45 5.45 9.58 Mean 5041.00 6472.89 5687.50 2736.11 2561.11 2561.11 2566.67 2736.11 2736.11SD 538.87 404.31 647.80 373.31 346.06 346.06 347.07 373.31 373.31

Pandere

CV 10.69 6.25 11.39 13.64 13.51

13.51 13.52 13.64 13.64Mean 4975.00 4980.77 4825.48 2658.65SD

476.04 878.45 804.48

95.86Bolapapu

CV 9.57 17.64 16.67 3.61Mean 4630.77 4400 4172.6 2668.27 2696.08 2569.71 2572.12 2563.73 2824.52 2824.52SD 430.82 385.08 325.48 233.70 227.77 236.35 238.84 236.34 197.27 197.27

Rahmat

CV 9.30 8.75 7.80 8.76 8.45 9.20 9.29 9.22 6.98 6.98Mean

4588.10 5062.79 4779.07 2884.30 3020.35 2720.35 2584.88 2578.49 2919.19 2919.19

SD 352.14 412.32 433.46 195.09 224.40 228.23 249.11 250.03 197.80 197.80Palu

CV 7.68 8.14 9.07 6.76 7.43 8.39 9.64 9.70 6.78 6.78

128

Page 139: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

Table A3 Correlation between Cimandi rice and fertilizer in Bolapapu mean of

producer price of

cimandi rice

mean of consumer price of

cimandi rice

mean of consumer price of

urea

mean of consumer price of

NPK mean of consumer price of cimandi rice in bolapapu 2003

Pearson Correlation ,868(**) 1 ,932(**) ,242

Sig. (2-tailed) ,000 , ,000 ,448 N 12 12 12 12

** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).

129

Page 140: Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural ...webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/ebook/y/2005/anggraenie/anggraenie.pdfAnggraenie, Triana Market Structure and Price Variability of Agricultural

QUESTIONNAIRE ON PRICE SURVEY Village (ID) : _____________________ ( ) Enumerator : __________________________________________ Date of Survey (dd/mm/yy) : ___/___/___(please try to do price survey every Wednesday). Note : Buyer is trader who buy commodities and fertilizer´s seller is trader who sell fertilizers in this village. If no trader performs as previously mentioned, (it means that farmers have to sell their commodities and buy fertilizer outside their village), please note distance (km), time, and transportation used. 1. Producer price

Commodities Price (Rp/kg) Price (Rp/liter) Number of buyer Cocoa Coffee

Membrano Kepala Cimandi Buri-buri IR 46 IR 66

Rice

IR 66 Super 2. Consumer price for agricultural inputs

Agricultural inputs Price (Rp/kg) Price (Rp/sack) Number of seller Urea NPK KCL

3. Consumer price for basic food items

Food items Price (Rp/kg) Price (Rp/liter) Number of seller Membrano Kepala Cimandi Buri-buri IR 46 IR 66

Rice

IR 66 Super Sugar Cooking oil (super quality)

Cooking oil (medium quality)

130