literature review on vertical integration of retailers

26
Retailing “Importance of Vertical integration in Retailing” Submitted by: Nelum Shehzade Maryam Choudhary

Upload: nelum-shehzade

Post on 15-Nov-2014

117 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

Retailing

“Importance of Vertical integration in Retailing”

Submitted by:

Nelum ShehzadeMaryam Choudhary

Page 2: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

Vertical Integration:

The degree to which a firm owns its upstream suppliers and its downstream buyers is referred to as vertical integration. It is also referred to as an approach for increasing or decreasing the level of control which a firm has over its inputs and distribution of outputs. [1]Vertical integration is of two types: backward integration and forward integration. A firm’s control of its inputs or supplies is known as: backward integration. A firm’s control of its distribution is known as: forward integration.The strategic reasons for opting for a vertical integration strategy have changed over the years. During the 19th century, firms used vertical integration to achieve economies of scale. During the middle of the 20th century, vertical integration was used to assure a steady supply of vital inputs. In some cases, the theory of transaction cost economics was applied to backward integration or forward integration, as a means to total cost reduction. That is, it was cheaper for a firm to perform the role of suppliers and distributors than to spend time and money to interact with such parties. Subsequently, in the late 20th century, competition intensified in most industries. Corporate restructuring resulted in vertical disintegration by reducing the levels of vertical integration in large corporations.

Drivers of Vertical Integration:Multiple factors contribute to the establishment and continued existence of large integrated firms despite inherent inefficiencies. These can be described in terms of reduced costs, weak supply networks, increased market power, and government policy. These factors are important during the early stages of an industry.

Cost reductions:Integrated firms have a cost advantage over smaller firms by avoiding transaction costs in imperfect markets, particularly during early stages of market development. Transaction cost includes ‘the cost of measuring output in all of its dimensions and the consequence of not measuring it perfectly’. Costs like writing, monitoring and enforcing contracts with supply chain and other partners. Such costs further intensify under conditions of specialized assets, complexity, uncertainty, and information asymmetry and these costs are applied to the transactions with suppliers and customers. This is the reason why larger firms can become suppliers to global firms.Integrated firms avoid the high transaction costs often linked with the activities that require highly specialized assets. Specialized assets make each party vulnerable and costs like writing, monitoring and enforcing contracts take place. And when a company decides to outsource then a supplier would be reluctant to invest in the equipment that cannot be used for any other purpose or for any other customer and highly asset specific in that conditions firms become there own suppliers. Vertically integrated firms also benefits from reduced costs through economies of scale, improved capacity utilization, decreased labor costs, lower raw material procurement costs etc. the highly integrated Ford motor company utilized economies of scale to provide better value at lower prices to achieve market dominance. And large integrated textile firms in America in 1800’s were better able to obtain stable supplies of reliable yarn then smaller scattered firms.

Page 3: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

Offensive Market Power:Since large integrated firms have increased access to resources like finances, human and technology and they have more bargaining power, therefore, they are better positioned to develop markets for the new products Highly integrated firm Bird’s Eye pioneered the frozen food industry by developing a raw material supply network, introducing new harvesting and freezing technologies, building product awareness and establishing specialized warehousing, transportation and retail equipments for handling frozen foods.

Government policy:Large integrated firms influence and benefits from government policies. In the early stages of industrial development capital, labor and product markets as well as regulatory environment are poorly developed and hence governments have greater control over the allocation of resources. Larger firms in such emerging markets benefits from government policies and gradually become more vertically integrated and horizontally diversified. Large vertically integrated firms are likely to emerge in high scale economy industries, in situations where premium products are being pioneered.

Because it can have a significant impact on a business unit’s position in its industry with respect to cost, differentiation, and other strategic issues, the vertical scope of the firm is an important consideration in corporate strategy.

LITERATURE REVIEW AND THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK:

Vertical integration is a corporate strategy that has been misunderstood. [2] .It has long been a key force in the development of high productivity and managerial sophistication in U.S. business (Chandler, 1977). Vertically integrated corporations have been key engines of change in the past and have enhanced shareholder wealth (Lubatkin, 1982). Oftentimes researchers did not recognize that vertical integration could be an effective strategy, provided it was used prudently, because they often took an overly aggregated view of it. Vertical integration can offer temporary state-of the-art advantages that must be weighed against the advantages of being flexible to exploit the next technological innovation. Firms that commit early to vertical integration, linking themselves in a highly inflexible fashion to a particular technology, risk being wrong, and the cost could be substantial. But if these pioneers are right, vertical integration can be a rationalizing device that form order in disordered environments, establishes industry standards, or lowers operating costs significantly. Then the harm of late entry can be substantial. Thus, firms should build pilot plants early to learn about suppliers and distributors before competitors can match these intelligence gains with their own experience.

An over view of the economy shows that industries operating in relatively stable environments with large capital investments continue to remain integrated, while firms with volatile markets in rapidly changing technological thresholds have moved away from it. [3].Mining

Page 4: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

and oil exploration are two industries which continue to operate on a highly integrated level.

A vertically integrated firm controls a number of different operations in the production and/or marketing of similar commodities on successive levels; and its management pursues a unified profit policy. Werner Z. Hirsch (1950). It should be pointed out, however, that vertical integration may take place in the direction to the ultimate consumer, to the major raw materials, or in both directions simultaneously. Backward vertical integration exists if the unit which initiated the vertical integration is closer to the ultimate consumer than any other unit. On the other hand, forward vertical integration exists, if the unit which initiated the vertical integration is further away from the ultimate consumer than any other unit.[4]. The fact is that there exist very few examples of such purely vertical integration. A very important reason for the lack of large purely vertically integrated firms seems to be the fact that a substantial volume has to be handled by the firm before vertical integration can be introduced profitably. Large production or marketing volume is usually associated with multiple plants (horizontal integration), or multiple commodities (complementarity), or both.The process in which several steps in the production and/or distribution of a product or service are controlled by a single company or entity, in order to increase that company's or entity's power in the marketplace.

By their ‘make or buy’ decisions firms decide their degree of vertical integration.[5]. This analyze the vertical integration strategy from a long-term profit-maximization perspective, It arguments for a long-term analysis rest on two premises: (a) strategy, by definition, relates to the future, which is almost always different from the present; and (b) strategic decisions imply resource commitments, few of which can be revoked without incurring some costs. A far-sighted firm, therefore, will base its vertical integration decision not only on the current technological conditions, but also on the anticipated

Page 5: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

changes in these conditions. The focus of the paper is, in short, why certain investments in the long run would be more attractive to integrated firms than to independent suppliers.And the result shows that to analyze the vertical integration strategy from a technological and competitive perspective. Two main results are that:1. Especially if the degree of competition is high, integration is affected negatively by the frequency of technological change;2. The optimal level of integration depends negatively on the degree of competition in the industry.

Page 6: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

The findings suggest that firms should scan outsiders frequently to assess whether some activities could be done by others more cheaply than in-house. Broad integration will likely have to give way to narrower breadths of integration as industries mature, lest vertical integration strategies create exit barriers and cash traps instead of guaranteed sources of resources and markets. Vertical integration is not a costless strategy.[6] Although it apparently can provide benefits through pioneering, industry rationalization and the creation of entry barriers, results suggest vertical integration should be adjusted to changing conditions.

Theoretical studies show that firms’ propensity to vertically integrate might be affected by transaction costs; imperfect competition and imperfect information [7].(Perry (1989) & Stigler (1951) provides very early work on vertical integration, deliberated on the theory using arguments rooted in his interpretation of Adam Smith’s theorem that ‘the division of labor is limited by the extent of the market’. In the same study, Stigler also provides several testable implications and evidence of the theory. Notably, however, Stigler makes no direct reference to the transaction cost motive for vertical integration. Levy (1984) re-examines Stigler’s work and clearly links Stigler’s hypotheses to the transaction cost theory. Since then, the transaction costs hypothesis has become the subject of many (if not most) empirical tests on the theory of vertical integration where it appears to have received strong support (e.g. Kirkvliet, 1991; Lieberman, 1991; Caves and Bradburd, 1988). Unfortunately, empirical tests on this subject have relied primarily on firm and industry data from the developed countries. To the authors’ knowledge no empirical evidence on this subject has been published using data from developing economies. This is the case despite a strong possibility that part of the measurement methodology adopted by previous empirical studies might not be applicable in a developing country like Malaysia. The empirical test results appear to lend support to the general hypothesis that transaction costs can increase the propensity for vertical integration. The test was conducted by running both the fixed-effects and random-effectsRegression models using data from Malaysian manufacturing.

An advantage of the vertically integrated organisational marketing system is that it forces senior managers to embrace cultural differences and produce a culturally sensitive leadership style.[8]. This should result in best practice being achieved that ultimately results in products and services that meet customer expectations. Staff in the collectivist oriented vertically integrated organisational marketing system will be able to formulate and implement marketing strategies, and can develop a hybrid organisational culture that draws on the best characteristics from staff in partnership member organisations.

The plant level studies has pointed to a variety of factors being related to integration, including asset specificity, supply uncertainty, market power, incomplete contracting, transaction costs, and regulation.[9]. Despite this, there is little systematic micro-level evidence on the ways production in vertically integrated firms differs from that of unintegrated producers in the same (narrowly defined) industries. This applies not only to

Page 7: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

differences in hard-to-measure attributes like capital specificity, contracting environments, and transaction costs, but even to more basic features like scale, factor intensity, and productivity.

Thornton’s strategy of vertical integration provides a number of differentiating characteristics while at the same time avoiding the consequences of market power and value appropriation in product and supply markets.[10] The company under review in the article gains benefits from the integration of activities and is able to access customer feedback to assist the processes of product and service innovation. Overall the company’s in-house strategy is consistent with the competitive, technological and supple context in which it operates. Within retailing more choice is apparent, however the occasional loss of franchised outlets and questions of sustainability and quality have determined the decision to follow a retail strategy largely based on shop ownership.The problems of focus and investment may present particular difficulties for the vertically integrated organization when seeking to address the longer term changes that occur in competitive environments.

Partnership arrangements such as vertically integrated organizational marketing systems provide staff in a retailing organization with a means for working closely with staff in supplier organizations and the manufacturer. This type of partnership arrangement, which is common practice in Japan and South Korea, provides organizations with a marketing oriented focus; a commitment to customer relationship management; and places decision-making within a strategic marketing framework. It also embraces developments in technology utilization such as the internet and supports the development of joint project units.

As the rivalry among retailing companies increases, it is likely that staff in retailing organizations will both embrace and adopt the strategic marketing approach, and use scenario planning to aid the decision-making process.[11]. By working closely with marketing strategists based in the manufacturer and linking with staff in the suppler organizations, it is vertically integrated organizational marketing systems possible to utilize the organizational learning approach that ensures that all staff in the partnership arrangement are marketing oriented and that the marketing intelligence activity becomes more research focused. The advantage of staff adopting a pro-active approach to research is that it will allow marketing trends to be identified and training support systems to be put in place. This will ensure that the right level of managerial skills and technical marketing skills are available when required. An advantage of the vertically integrated organizational marketing system is that it forces senior managers to embrace cultural differences and produce a culturally sensitive leadership style.

The case of Bread Markets, is a pioneering study of changes in the market structure of grocery retailing, Mueller and Garoian compared the earnings of grocery chains from 1950 to 1958 with those of three supplier industries, baking, dairy, and meat packing and found a gradual deterioration in the latter industries' earnings relative to those of grocery chains to examine some of the consequences of oligopolistic competition and vertical integration in bread markets.[12]

Page 8: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

Empirical evidence is drawn from a recent study of the baking industry. Attention is focused on the changing market structure and the associated changes in market conduct and behavior. The central objective is to determine whether changes in selling costs and prices support the hypothesis stated earlier-that increased vertical integration by chains has increased competition and improved performance in the food industry.

Fashion apparel makers have used vertical integration to their advantage in this volatile and highly competitive environment. It gives them superior capability to respond quickly to competitors and to disrupt the status quo. More specifically, these firms have used vertical integration to escalate competition within the arena of timing and know-how.[13].And in so doing, they have been able to achieve superior customer satisfaction. By linking design and production closely to retailing through integration, they are better able to manage flexible production to meet emand volatility. The operational flexibility of the integrated firms matches the flexibility required by their competitive environment (Volberda 1996). Integration of manufacturing and retailing provides the controllability that is needed to achieve the overall operational flexibility of quick response.

E. Avenel & S. Caprice , analyze product line differentiation between retailers competing on a vertically differentiated market. It include the analysis the vertical relations between retailers and manufacturers.[14] This feature proves to be crucial for the determination of product line differentiation. In particular, it find an equilibrium in which product lines are partially differentiated, which is a new result. Analysis suggests that exclusive dealing should be banned per se, while a rule of reason approach should be adopted toward vertical integration. This is related to the fact that integration doesn’t necessarily imply foreclosure.

Most of the firms dislike to rely on there competitors for supplies therefore recent corporate restructuring indicates that this reluctance can make vertical integration unprofitable.[15]. For instance the desire to sell to competing downstream firms motivated AT&T’s separation from lucent technologies, Pepsi Co; spin-off of the Tricon restaurants in addition to these spin-offs, firm’s reluctance to purchase from competitors may be one of the reason that some business-to-business are jointly owned by parties most likely to use the exchange.Incomplete contracts explain how vertically integrated firm could favor its own downstream unit over competing downstream unit however profit maximizing firms do not have an incentive to do anything including exploit contractual incompleteness that reduce profits. Thus contractual incompleteness cannot explain why a vertically integrated supplier would favor its own downstream unit when such favoritism reduces the integrated firm’s profits.

We’ll see a case of a person named Carlos he had dreamed about vertically integrating his mango and pineapple fruit plantation and export business into further processing of pre-cut fruit. His business sold fresh fruit to brokers in various Caribbean countries and the United States. Moving into the pre-cut fruit market would require all of the company’s capital and management expertise. It offered a great deal of potential because

Page 9: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

of the added value but there were risks involved in such a venture. As CEO of Telesignos, he was constantly looking for new business opportunities. Vertical integration into production of pre-cut fruit would permit Telesignos to capitalize on its potential growth opportunities. [16].However, forward vertical integration required high capital investment, fruit processing skills, a favorable image, and access to new markets. The shareholders of Telesignos could provide the money to build a fresh fruit processing facility. Carlos had gathered a great deal of information about the fresh pineapple (fruit) industry. There were many things to consider before becoming vertically integrated like Production and Technology, Market Environment and Opportunities, etc

The variables identified by Casson are used to project the extent of backward and forward VI at the manufacturer level and the extent of backward integration at the retail level.[17] Backward VI by retailers into the wholesaling function is significant. Retailer Vertical Integration: Backward VI by retailers will decrease slightly. Factors that will discourage vertical integration include the increasing number of products included in retail stores, The minimum number of stores required to enter a new market, the increasing size of food retailing firms, and the future growth of retail food sales. These factors will interact with the increasing concentration of food retailers, the importance of quality control among generic brands, and the existence of past VI by retailers. The management expertise required for undertaking VI will be fully employed when managing new superstores that have more products and which may also be involved with managing the firm as it merges horizontally with other retailers. The net effect will be a slight decrease in VI.

In Agricultural production: (backward integration).Vertical integration will increase slightly in the crop portion of agriculture. Causes of VI increases in the crop category include the perish ability of vegetables, the concentration and capital intensity of processed manufacturers and the discontent among farmers with respect to prices received (Marion, p. 169), the concentration at the manufacturer (processor) level, continuous flow economies, and the variability in supply due to weather.

The economic forces which led to massive vertical integration in the commercial broiler industry describes the importance of vertical integration. [18].There are some of the long-run social, political and economic implications of this particular example of vertical integration in agriculture. vertical integration means any arrangement by which a decision-maker in one stage of production acquires control of inputs, processes, or output levels in a vertically separated stage. Vertical integration embraces control by acquisition of facilities used in the separate stage, by contracting these facilities, or by an informal understanding kept effective by mutual benefits.[19]. Decision-integration is much more important than ownership integration in agriculture. In the decisions type of integration, ownership is not necessarily passed from one decision-making firm to another. The essential element is that decisions (especially output decisions) of two or more units are coordinated through contracts or agreements. [20].

Page 10: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

To study the Forces Leading to Vertical Integration assumption of a hypothetical broiler industry without vertical integration, and subject this industry to realistic conditions, and isolate some economic forces leading to vertical integration. The development partially follows suggestions by other authors and particularly by Collins, Kohls, and Trif0n. His findings are that Vertical integration and horizontal amalgamation may eliminate the traditional social-political role of “farmer” in the broiler industry. Vertical structuring does not eliminate an important social problem associated with periodic over-expansion of the broiler industry. Vertically integrated broiler firms may extend their activities into other sectors of animal agriculture, but none of the sectors inherently have advantages of vertical integration comparable to those in the broiler industry.

Economedies shows that the vertically integrated firm will always have an incentive to impose costs on its down stream rivals throught non price dis-crimination[21]

The dangers of vertical integration in the presence of environmental instability have recently been the subject of much attention in the policy literature (Hayes and Abernathy, 1980; Porter, 1980: 309-315; Marrigan, 1983a,b). The argument made by these researchers is essentially that irreversible investments are vulnerable, if there is uncertainty about their future value.[22]In order to clarify this some careful theoretical reasoning is necessary. According to the standard analysis of Williamson (1975), uncertainty will, in general, lead to more vertical integration. The basic argument is that an independent supplier will demand a reasonably complete long-term contract before committing to investments in an idiosyncratic asset. As the number of contingencies in the contract goes up, it becomes more expensive to write, monitor and enforce so that vertical integration becomes more attractive. The predicted positive relationship between general uncertainty and vertical integration has been demonstrated conclusively by h'lasten . For a particular type of uncertainty, the possibility of technological obsolescence, the relationship does, however, reverse. In this case more uncertainty does not increase the number of contingencies in a hypothetical contract with an independent supplier; it only makes the single contingency more likely. Furthermore, as the likelihood of obsolescence goes up, the expected profitability of the investment goes down, and with it the incentive to bargain and hence the gains from vertical integration.

In particular instances, it is obvious that vertical integration does contribute to functional efficiency. A unified control over a sequence of operations may promote efficiency of physical processes by eliminating unnecessary handling, by making the flow of goods more regular,or by adapting quality more closely to use.[23]. Unity of control may promote efficiency in business operations by eliminating unnecessary sales effort or may facilitate more exact planning which can reduce inventories and minimize idle time.

The vertical integration in general does not entail a reduction in output and an increase in price in the product market if the assumed condition is met.[24].The condition is that vertical integration does not affect the production function of the firm in question, so that vertical integration neither causes economies nor diseconomies of scale. Economies of scale following vertical integration favor an increase in output and a reduction in price in

Page 11: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

the product market. Diseconomies of scale following vertical integration, on the other hand, have an opposite effect on output and price in the product market.

Firms vertically integrate to create specific investment between stages of the value chain, to internally exploit their pool of knowledge and capacities, and to guarantee quality of inputs and services employed. On the other hand, firms avoid high levels of vertical integration in the presence of high demand changes in order to stay flexible. Finally, providers or clients with market power do not seem to affect vertical boundaries in any consistent way.[25].

A New Look at Vertical Integration

The old concept of vertical integration as being 100 percent owned operations that are physically interconnected to supply 100percent of a firm's needs is outmoded. Under appropriate circumstances, quality control and access to stable supplies can be obtained through quasi-integration arrangements. Firms could contract for R&D services, for example, to utilize the technology of genetic engineering in product development, or they could form joint ventures to obtain this capability. Firms could have components engineered to their tight and highly specific instructions by outsiders, as do Japanese automobile manufacturers, for example. And if their bargaining power is sufficient, firms can use a kanban or "just in time" system of inventory controls that shifts the burden of holding costs to their suppliers.If firms prefer not to use outsiders as extensions of their corporate entity, a variety of other vertical arrangements are possible. Some firms may conclude that they need not undertake certain activities at all. In other situations, firms may find that they can enjoy the integration economies, uncertainty reduction, competitive intelligence, and other benefits that internal vertical linkages may provide through outsiders. The key in using vertical integration is recognizing which activities to perform in-house, how to relate these activities to each other, how much of its needs the firm should satisfy in-house, how much ownership equity needs to be risked in doing so, and when these dimensions should be adjusted to accommodate new competitive conditions. Briefly, the concept of vertical integration should be expanded to include a variety of arrangements by which the firm can use outsiders, as well as its own business units to counterfeit an optimal vertical system for supplying goods, services, and capabilities.

VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND LOCAL VIEWPOINT:

Chenab Ltd:Chenab Ltd., Faisalabad, Pakistan is a US$83 Million textile company with annual sales in excess of US$85 Million and a market presence of over 28 years. With vertically integrated manufacturing facilities of Ginning, spinning, weaving and processing they are by all means, the largest textile company in the region with a capacity to process 4.5 to 5 million meters per month of finished fabric. 12 years ago, was established a dedicated

Page 12: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

apparel garment division. This division has now grown exponentially and in the process of becoming one of the major backbones of the company. Why do companies like Tommy Hilfiger, JC Penny, Wal Mart, Sears, Kellwood, QVC, Federate, Ikea, GDC, L.A Intimate, VF, Roman’s Lerner, and Lane Bryant prefer to buy from Chenab Ltd. The fashion industry in the world is very dynamic and highly competitive. At Chenab, they keep a constant watch on the pulse of the global fashion industry. This proactive approach germinates commitment towards innovation and continuous product development. This exceptional team consists of a unique mix of individuals from different fields such as textiles, designing and marketing. Chenab combine these expertise to produce a creative value chain, whereby an idea generated by technical personal. This value is further enhanced by marketing personal that creates technical viability into fashion and so the journey of thought to fabric is completed and today’s idea becomes tomorrow’s fashion. This value addition is finally materialized edge in the fashion world by providing them with unique products to work with.

Their Technical Assets have a state of the art processing & Dying. All dyes and chemicals are European origin. They have in house quality control and assurance lab which is fully equipped with latest testing machines and tools. This lab is comparable to any other textile lab in the world. Made up divisions have been equipped with all the required modern machinery i.e. quilting, embroidery, e-cording, Stitching, Pleating, Button Holing, Button Fixing, Safety over lock, Steam press, Cutting and Packing machines. Some of products are Comforters, Quilt Cover, Flat Sheet, Fitted Sheet, Curtain, Shower curtain, Valance, Pouf Valance, Bed Skirts, Sofa cover, Table Cloth, Cot Bumper, Pillow Cover, Sham, Napkin, Oven Gloves, Bed Spread and a lot more.

Usually, textiles manufacturing companies consider themselves to be in the business of selling fabric. But the basic business policy of Chenab Ltd is to develop long-term business relationships with customer and the only way to achieve this is to ensure customer satisfaction. Hence they provide unmatched customer service along with timely deliveries. ChenOne (Changing lifestyles) the fashion brand of Chenab Ltd was launched in 1997 in Pakistan & Middle East. ChenOne has established itself for ladies, gents & kids garment as well as home linen. In few years the brand has taken the market by storm and is already a preferred choice of the fashion conscious people. The total number of outlets has gradually grown. And they are performing all these activities because they are highly integrated to provide consistent products to the customers.

Being a vertically integrated manufacturing facility gives Chenab an edge unparalleled by any other company in this region. Being a proactive company, they continuously invest in the development of new products and new ideas. Their own Ginning, Spinning & weaving plants allow them to create an array of weaves with different types of yarn/fibers. They own there own outlets around the country by the name of ChenOne as mentioned above as well therefore they are doing both backward and forward integration at the same time and benefiting from them.

Case about Two Large Integrated Players of Foot Wear Industry in Pakistan:

Page 13: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

(And how they decided to de-integrate certain activities)

Pakistan has the footwear market of more then 150 million pair/year. There are three different classes of suppliers to this market i.e. the informal sector, the small manufacturers and the large integrated units. The informal sector consists of over 17000 units, each with an average of two employees. These firms generally pay no taxes, and mainly sell non-branded shoes through cobbler shops. In addition there are about 500 small manufacturers who distribute through wholesalers or their own outlets. And there are two large integrated manufacturers, with almost 20% market share and sell through there own national distribution network. But recently they have started outsourcing there certain activities we’ll further see why this is happening to the two large integrated players.

Early vertical integration:Bata (Pakistan) was established in Batapur (near Lahore) in 1942 as a branch of Bata of British India in Batanagar, as a part of Bata international headquartered in Toronto, Canada. Bata Pakistan becomes an independent firm after partition. Service Industries was established in Gujarat in 1954. Bata is twice the size than Servis with the share like 10% versus 6% respectively. Both were vertically integrated firms, with company owned leather tanneries, shoe manufacturing, and retail network. Both made strong brand image by providing consistent shoe quality at affordable prices and through extensive advertising. Smaller non integrated manufacturers were unable to compete with Bata had Servis. To produce reliable shoes, access to high quality leather is required which involves quality leather tanning which require imported chemicals, and expensive equipments. There were only 5 tanneries in Pakistan in 1947, thus small manufacturers does not had any access to quality leather. Initially Servis followed the strategy to open the outlet right next to Bata’s therefore in 2002 Servis had 260 stores while Bata had 350 and planned to grow by about 30% in next few years. Small manufacturers without access to such retail networks had to depend on the wholesalers who often defaulted or delayed payments also low cost capital and imported technology available were lacking for them.

Gradual de-integration:In 1980’s leather and footwear industry expanded and markets became more efficient. Smaller manufacturers who do not had access to quality raw materials, low cost capital, imported technology and distribution networks gained access to that, and developed specialized expertise. Therefore Bata and Servis faced who were facing competition from these smaller firms as well as imported footwear started developing supply networks to remain competitive. During 1981 to 1992 the no of tanneries tripled (from 180 to 509), making quality finished leather widely available to footwear manufacturers. As a result of the changed economics of vertical integration during the eighties, both Bata and Servis started a process of de-integration in the late 1990s. Bata diversified out of leather tanning in 1996 and embarked on a program to increase outsourcing to specialized vendors and there labor force decreased by 20%. In 1965, the marketing and distribution division of Servis was formed into a separate company: Service Sales Corporation (SSC).

Page 14: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

In 1998, SSC became an autonomous body and by 2002, SSC had increased the value of products being produced from outside the Servis group to 30%

Outsourcing at Servis & Bata:In 2002, both Servis and Bata carried about 1500 SKUs each, grouped broadly into 6 categories. Each of these 6 categories is characterized by different production technologies, and market characteristics. The outsourcing decision for each product category by Servis and Bata also varies depending on scale economies, transactional costs and proprietary knowledge. (Shown in the fig below)The combination of low scale economies, low transaction costs, and minimal proprietary knowledge has resulted in Women Sandals & Slippers being one of the first choices for outsourcing by both Bata & Servis. Men Moccasins have production characteristics similar to Women Sandals & Slippers. However the large lot size allows for assembly line manufacturing, resulting in higher scale economies. Also the longer product life cycle of Men Moccasins result in more strict quality requirements thus outsourcing was a viable option. All others are produced in-house.

Summarising the findings and importance of Vertical integration in retailing from the literature review:

Page 15: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

Reduce transportation costs if common ownership results in closer geographic proximity.1

Improve supply chain coordination.2 . Provide more opportunities to differentiate by means of increased control over

inputs.3 . Capture upstream or down stream profit margins.4. Increase entry barriers to potential competitors.5. Facilitate investment in highly specialised assets in which upstream or down

stream players may be reluctant to invest.6. Lead to expansion of core competencies. Minimization of risks factors. 7 Monopoly .8. Branding benefits Flexibility 9. Economies of scale and Economies of scope.10

Vertical integration could be the possible best solution in the emerging economies but in developed economies it does not always work because of the competition and many other factors as we have seen in the case of Bata and Servis that they were highly integrated but when faced competition they also had to outsource some of there activities. The findings suggest that firms should scan outsiders frequently to assess whether some activities could be done by others more cheaply than in-house. Broad integration will likely have to give way to narrower breadths of integration as industries mature, in case vertical integration strategies create exit barriers and cash traps instead of guaranteed sources of resources and markets. Vertical integration is not a costless strategy. Although it apparently can provide benefits through pioneering, industry rationalization and the creation of entry barriers, results suggest vertical integration should be adjusted to changing conditions.

Notes1. Integration in practice-the broiler case (W.R.henryand robertraunikar 1960) 2. Impacts of Vertical Integration on Output Price and Industry Structure J. A. Seagraves; C. E. Bishop3. Vertical Integration and the Monopoly Problem (Corwin D. Edwards1953)4. Technical Change, Competition and Vertical Integration (Srinivasan Balakrishnan; Birger Wernerfelt (Jul. -

Aug., 1986)5. Vertical Integration and Production: Some Plant-Level Evidence . Ali Hortaçsu , Chad Syverson 20076. Technical Change, Competition and Vertical Integration (Srinivasan Balakrishnan; Birger Wernerfelt (Jul. -

Aug., 1986)7. The effects of vertical integration on price and output .S. y. wu’8. Vertical Integration and the Monopoly Problem (Corwin D. Edwards1953)9. Vertical Integration and internet strategies in the apparel industry. Robert . H. Gertner & Robert. S . Stillman.10. Vertical Integration and the Monopoly Problem (Corwin D. Edwards1953)

References[1] Toward a Definition of Integration , Werner Z. Hirsch

Page 16: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

[2] Formulating Vertical Integration strategies: Kathryn Rudie Harrigan

[3] The evolution of vertically integrated organizations: the role of historical context.Ashay Desai & Ananda Mukherji

[4 ] Technical Change, Competition and Vertical Integration Srinivasan Balakrishnan; Birger Wernerfelt (Jul. - Aug., 1986)

[ 5] Matching Vertical Integration Strategies to Competitive Conditions:Kathryn Rudie Harrigan

[6 ] Toward a Definition of Integration , Werner Z. Hirsch

[7 ] Vertical Integration, Foreign Multinationals and Stigler’s Hypotheses: An Empirical Test Using Malaysian Data*Nor Ghani Md. Nor, Ahmad Zainuddin Abdullah and Khalil Md. Nor

[8 ] Vertically integrated organisational marketing systems: a partnership approach for retailing organizations . Peter R.J. Trim

[ 9] Vertical Integration and Production: Some Plant-Level Evidence . Ali Hortaçsu , Chad Syverson 2007

[10 ] Thornton’s: the vertically integrated retailer, questioning the strategy (David Fennings)

[ 11] Vertically integrated organisational marketing systems. Peter R.J. Trim and Yang-Im Lee

[12 ] Some Consequences of Bilateral Oligopoly and Vertical Integration in BreadMarkets. Richard G. Walsh; Bert M. Evans; Eleanor M. Birch

[13 ] Vertical Integration and Rapid Response in Fashion Apparel James Richardson

[14 ] Vertical integration, exclusive dealing and product line differentiation in retailing E. Avenel & S. Caprice

Page 17: Literature review on Vertical Integration of Retailers

[ 15] Vertical enclosure: vertical integration and the reluctance to purchase from a competitor .D. Lee Heavner

[16] Vertical Integration in Ecuador: The Case of Fresh-Cut PineapplesCarlos F. Piana, Allen M. Featherstone, and Michael A. Boland

[17] Vertical Integration in Agricultural and Food Marketing Richard L. Kilmer (Dec., 1986)

[18 ] Integration in practice-the broiler case: W. R. Henryand Robertraunikar .

[19] Impacts of Vertical Integration on Output Price and Industry StructureJ. A. Seagraves; C. E. Bishop

[20 ] Vertically integrated organisational marketing systems: a partnership approach for retailing organizations. Peter R.J. Trim, Yang-Im Lee

[21 ] Regulation, Vertical Integration and Sabotage: Randolph Beard, David.L.Keserman, John .W. Mayo

[22 ] Technical Change, Competition and Vertical Integration Srinivasan Balakrishnan; Birger Wernerfelt (Jul. - Aug., 1986)

[23 ] Vertical Integration and the Monopoly Problem (Corwin D. Edwards1953)

[24 ] The effects of vertical integration on price and output . S. Y. Wu’

[25 ] Explaining Vertical Integration Strategies: Market Power, Transactional Attributes and Capabilities . Isabel Díez-Vial