lesson24 implicit differentiation slides

39
Lesson 24 (Sections 16.3, 16.7) Implicit Differentiation Math 20 November 16, 2007 Announcements I Problem Set 9 on the website. Due November 21. I There will be class November 21 and homework due November 28. I next OH: Monday 1-2pm, Tuesday 3-4pm I Midterm II: Thursday, 12/6, 7-8:30pm in Hall A. I Go Harvard! Beat Yale!

Upload: matthew-leingang

Post on 15-Jun-2015

920 views

Category:

Business


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Lesson 24 (Sections 16.3, 16.7)Implicit Differentiation

Math 20

November 16, 2007

Announcements

I Problem Set 9 on the website. Due November 21.

I There will be class November 21 and homework dueNovember 28.

I next OH: Monday 1-2pm, Tuesday 3-4pm

I Midterm II: Thursday, 12/6, 7-8:30pm in Hall A.

I Go Harvard! Beat Yale!

Page 2: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Outline

Cleanup on Leibniz Rule

Implicit Differentiation in two dimensionsThe Math 1a wayOld school Implicit DifferentationNew school Implicit DifferentationCompare

Application

More than two dimensions

The second derivative

Page 3: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Last Time: the Chain Rule

Theorem (The Chain Rule, General Version)

Suppose that u is a differentiable function of the n variablesx1, x2, . . . , xn, and each xi is a differentiable function of the mvariables t1, t2, . . . , tm. Then u is a function of t1, t2, . . . , tm and

∂u

∂ti=

∂u

∂x1

∂x1

∂ti+∂u

∂x2

∂x2

∂ti+ · · ·+ ∂u

∂xn

∂xn

∂ti

In summation notation

∂u

∂ti=

n∑j=1

∂u

∂xj

∂xj

∂ti

Page 4: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Last Time: the Chain Rule

Theorem (The Chain Rule, General Version)

Suppose that u is a differentiable function of the n variablesx1, x2, . . . , xn, and each xi is a differentiable function of the mvariables t1, t2, . . . , tm. Then u is a function of t1, t2, . . . , tm and

∂u

∂ti=

∂u

∂x1

∂x1

∂ti+∂u

∂x2

∂x2

∂ti+ · · ·+ ∂u

∂xn

∂xn

∂ti

In summation notation

∂u

∂ti=

n∑j=1

∂u

∂xj

∂xj

∂ti

Page 5: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Leibniz’s Formula for Integrals

FactSuppose that f (, t, x), a(t), and b(t) are differentiable functions,and let

F (t) =

∫ b(t)

a(t)f (t, x) dx

Then

F ′(t) = f (t, b(t))b′(t)− f (t, a(t))a′(t) +

∫ b(t)

a(t)

∂f (t, x)

∂tdx

Proof.Apply the chain rule to the function

H(t, u, v) =

∫ v

uf (t, x) dx

with u = a(t) and v = b(t).

Page 6: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Leibniz’s Formula for Integrals

FactSuppose that f (, t, x), a(t), and b(t) are differentiable functions,and let

F (t) =

∫ b(t)

a(t)f (t, x) dx

Then

F ′(t) = f (t, b(t))b′(t)− f (t, a(t))a′(t) +

∫ b(t)

a(t)

∂f (t, x)

∂tdx

Proof.Apply the chain rule to the function

H(t, u, v) =

∫ v

uf (t, x) dx

with u = a(t) and v = b(t).

Page 7: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Leibniz’s Formula for Integrals

FactSuppose that f (, t, x), a(t), and b(t) are differentiable functions,and let

F (t) =

∫ b(t)

a(t)f (t, x) dx

Then

F ′(t) = f (t, b(t))b′(t)− f (t, a(t))a′(t) +

∫ b(t)

a(t)

∂f (t, x)

∂tdx

Proof.Apply the chain rule to the function

H(t, u, v) =

∫ v

uf (t, x) dx

with u = a(t) and v = b(t).

Page 8: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Tree Diagram

H

t u

t

v

t

Page 9: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

More about the proof

H(t, u, v) =

∫ v

uf (t, x) dx

Then by the Fundamental Theorem of Calculus (see Section 10.1)

∂H

∂v= f (t, v)

∂H

∂u= −f (t, u)

Also,∂H

∂t=

∫ v

u

∂f

∂x(t, x) dx

since t and x are independent variables.

Page 10: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

More about the proof

H(t, u, v) =

∫ v

uf (t, x) dx

Then by the Fundamental Theorem of Calculus (see Section 10.1)

∂H

∂v= f (t, v)

∂H

∂u= −f (t, u)

Also,∂H

∂t=

∫ v

u

∂f

∂x(t, x) dx

since t and x are independent variables.

Page 11: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

More about the proof

H(t, u, v) =

∫ v

uf (t, x) dx

Then by the Fundamental Theorem of Calculus (see Section 10.1)

∂H

∂v= f (t, v)

∂H

∂u= −f (t, u)

Also,∂H

∂t=

∫ v

u

∂f

∂x(t, x) dx

since t and x are independent variables.

Page 12: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Since F (t) = H(t, a(t), b(t)),

dF

dt=∂H

∂t+∂H

∂u

du

dt+∂H

∂v

dv

dt

=

∫ b(t)

a(t)

∂f

∂x(t, x) + f (t, b(t))b′(t)− f (t, a(t))a′(t)

Page 13: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Application

Example (Example 16.8 with better notation)

Let the profit of a firm be π(t). The present value of the futureprofit π(τ) where τ > t is

π(τ)e−r(τ−t),

where r is the discount rate. On a time interval [0,T ], the presentvalue of all future profit is

V (t) =

∫ T

tπ(τ)e−r(τ−t) dt.

Find V ′(t).

Answer.

V ′(t) = rV (t)− π(t)

Page 14: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Application

Example (Example 16.8 with better notation)

Let the profit of a firm be π(t). The present value of the futureprofit π(τ) where τ > t is

π(τ)e−r(τ−t),

where r is the discount rate. On a time interval [0,T ], the presentvalue of all future profit is

V (t) =

∫ T

tπ(τ)e−r(τ−t) dt.

Find V ′(t).

Answer.

V ′(t) = rV (t)− π(t)

Page 15: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

SolutionSince the upper limit is a constant, the only boundary term comesfrom the lower limit:

V ′(t) = −π(t)e−r(t−t) +

∫ T

t

∂tπ(τ)e−rτert dτ

= −π(t) + r

∫ T

tπ(τ)e−rτert dτ

= rV (t)− π(t).

This means that

r =π(t) + V ′(t)

V (t)

So if the fraction on the right is less than the rate of return foranother, “safer” investment like bonds, it would be worth more tosell the business and buy the bonds.

Page 16: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Outline

Cleanup on Leibniz Rule

Implicit Differentiation in two dimensionsThe Math 1a wayOld school Implicit DifferentationNew school Implicit DifferentationCompare

Application

More than two dimensions

The second derivative

Page 17: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

An example

Consider theutility function

u(x , y) = −1

x−1

y

What is theslope of thetangent linealong theindifferencecurveu(x , y) = −1?

1 2 3 4

1

2

3

4

Page 18: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

The Math 1a way

Solve for y in terms of x and differentiate:

1

x+

1

y= 1 =⇒ y =

1

1− 1/x

So

dy

dx=

−1

(1− 1/x)2

(1

x2

)=

−1

x2(1− 1/x)2=

−1

(x − 1)2

Page 19: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Old school Implicit Differentation

Differentiate the equation remembering that y is presumed to be afunction of x :

− 1

x2− 1

y2

dy

dx= 0

Sody

dx= −y2

x2= −

(y

x

)2

Page 20: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

New school Implicit Differentation

This is a formalized version of old school: If

F (x , y) = c

Then by differentiating the equation and treating y as a functionof x , we get

∂F

∂x+∂F

∂y

(dy

dx

)F

= 0

So (dy

dx

)F

= −∂F/∂x

∂F/∂x

The (·)F notation reminds us that y is not explicitly a function ofx , but if F is held constant we can treat it implicitly so.

Page 21: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Tree diagram

F

x y

x

∂F

∂x+∂F

∂y

(dy

dx

)F

= 0

Page 22: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

The big idea

FactAlong the level curve F (x , y) = c, the slope of the tangent line isgiven by

dy

dx=

(dy

dx

)F

= −∂F/∂x

∂F/∂x= −F ′1(x , y)

F ′2(x , y)

Page 23: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Compare

I Explicitly solving for y is tedious, and sometimes impossible.

I Either implicit method brings out more clearly the important

fact that (in our example)(

dydx

)u

depends only on the ratio

y/x.

I Old-school implicit differentiation is familiar but (IMO)contrived.

I New-school implicit differentiation is systematic andgeneralizable.

Page 24: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Outline

Cleanup on Leibniz Rule

Implicit Differentiation in two dimensionsThe Math 1a wayOld school Implicit DifferentationNew school Implicit DifferentationCompare

Application

More than two dimensions

The second derivative

Page 25: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Application

If u(x , y) is a utility function of two goods, then u(x , y) = c is aindifference curve, and the slope represents the marginal rate ofsubstitution:

Ryx = −(

dy

dx

)u

=u′xu′y

=MUx

MUy

Page 26: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Outline

Cleanup on Leibniz Rule

Implicit Differentiation in two dimensionsThe Math 1a wayOld school Implicit DifferentationNew school Implicit DifferentationCompare

Application

More than two dimensions

The second derivative

Page 27: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

More than two dimensions

The basic idea is to close your eyes and use the chain rule:

Example

Suppose a surface is given by F (x , y , z) = c . If this defines z as afunction of x and y , find z ′x and z ′y .

SolutionSetting F (x , y , z) = c and remembering z is implicitly a functionof x and y, we get

∂F

∂x+∂F

∂z

(∂z

∂x

)F

= 0 =⇒(∂z

∂x

)F

= −F ′xF ′z

∂F

∂y+∂F

∂z

(∂z

∂y

)F

= 0 =⇒(∂z

∂y

)F

= −F ′yF ′z

Page 28: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

More than two dimensions

The basic idea is to close your eyes and use the chain rule:

Example

Suppose a surface is given by F (x , y , z) = c . If this defines z as afunction of x and y , find z ′x and z ′y .

SolutionSetting F (x , y , z) = c and remembering z is implicitly a functionof x and y, we get

∂F

∂x+∂F

∂z

(∂z

∂x

)F

= 0 =⇒(∂z

∂x

)F

= −F ′xF ′z

∂F

∂y+∂F

∂z

(∂z

∂y

)F

= 0 =⇒(∂z

∂y

)F

= −F ′yF ′z

Page 29: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Tree diagram

F

x y z

x

∂F

∂x+∂F

∂z

(∂z

∂x

)F

= 0 =⇒(∂z

∂x

)F

= −F ′xF ′z

Page 30: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Example

Suppose production is given by a Cobb-Douglas function

P(A,K , L) = AK aLb

where K is capital, L is labor, and A is technology. Compute thechanges in technology or capital needed to sustain production iflabor decreases.

Solution

(∂K

∂L

)P

= −P ′LP ′K

= −AK abLb−1

AaK a−1Lb= −b

a· K

L(∂A

∂L

)P

= −P ′LP ′A

= −AK abLb−1

K aLb= −bA

L

So if labor decreases by 1 unit we need either ba ·

KL more capital or

bAL more tech to sustain production.

Page 31: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Example

Suppose production is given by a Cobb-Douglas function

P(A,K , L) = AK aLb

where K is capital, L is labor, and A is technology. Compute thechanges in technology or capital needed to sustain production iflabor decreases.

Solution

(∂K

∂L

)P

= −P ′LP ′K

= −AK abLb−1

AaK a−1Lb= −b

a· K

L(∂A

∂L

)P

= −P ′LP ′A

= −AK abLb−1

K aLb= −bA

L

So if labor decreases by 1 unit we need either ba ·

KL more capital or

bAL more tech to sustain production.

Page 32: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Outline

Cleanup on Leibniz Rule

Implicit Differentiation in two dimensionsThe Math 1a wayOld school Implicit DifferentationNew school Implicit DifferentationCompare

Application

More than two dimensions

The second derivative

Page 33: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

The second derivative: Derivation

What is the concavity of an indifference curve? We know(dy

dx

)F

= −F ′xF ′y

= −G

H

Then

y ′′ = −HG ′ − GH ′

H2

Now

G ′ =d

dx

∂F

∂x=∂2F

∂x2+

∂2F

∂y ∂x

dy

dx

=∂2F

∂x2− ∂2F

∂y ∂x

(∂F/∂x

∂F/∂y

)So

HG ′ =∂F

∂y

∂2F

∂x2− ∂2F

∂y ∂x

∂F

∂x= F ′y F ′′xx − F ′′yxF ′x

Page 34: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Also

H ′ =d

dx

∂F

∂y=

∂F

∂x ∂y+∂2F

∂y2

dy

dx

=∂2F

∂x ∂y− ∂2F

∂y2

(∂F/∂x

∂F/∂y

)So

GH ′ = F ′xF ′′xy −F ′′yy (F ′x)2

F ′y

=F ′xF ′′xy F ′y − F ′′yy (F ′x)2

F ′y

Page 35: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Putting this all together we get

y ′′ = −F ′y F ′′xx − F ′′yxF ′x −

(F ′xF ′′xy F ′y − F ′′yy (F ′x)2

F ′y

)(F ′y )2

= − 1

(F ′y )3

[F ′′xx(F ′y )2 − 2F ′′xy F ′xF ′y + F ′′yy (F ′x)2

]=

1

(F ′y )3

∣∣∣∣∣∣0 F ′x F ′y

F ′x F ′′xx F ′′xyF ′y F ′′xy F ′′yy

∣∣∣∣∣∣

Page 36: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Example

Along the indifference curve

1

x+

1

y= c

compute (y ′′)u. What does this say about ddx Ryx?

SolutionWe have u(x , y) = 1

x + 1y , so

(d2y

dx2

)u

=1

(−1/y2)3

∣∣∣∣∣∣0 −1/x2 −1/y2

−1/x2 2/x3 0−1/y2 0 −2/y3

∣∣∣∣∣∣

Page 37: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Example

Along the indifference curve

1

x+

1

y= c

compute (y ′′)u. What does this say about ddx Ryx?

SolutionWe have u(x , y) = 1

x + 1y , so

(d2y

dx2

)u

=1

(−1/y2)3

∣∣∣∣∣∣0 −1/x2 −1/y2

−1/x2 2/x3 0−1/y2 0 −2/y3

∣∣∣∣∣∣

Page 38: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Solution (continued)

(d2y

dx2

)u

=1

(−1/y2)3

∣∣∣∣∣∣0 −1/x2 −1/y2

−1/x2 2/x3 0−1/y2 0 −2/y3

∣∣∣∣∣∣= −y6

[−(−1

x2

)(−1

x2

)(2

y3

)−(−1

y2

)(2

x3

)(−1

y2

)]= 2y6

[1

x4y3+

1

y4x3

]= 2

(y

x

)3(

1

x+

1

y

)= 2c

(y

x

)3

This is positive, and since Ryx = −(

dydx

)u, we have

d

dxRyx = −2u

(y

x

)3< 0

So the MRS diminishes with increasing consumption of x.

Page 39: Lesson24    Implicit  Differentiation Slides

Bonus: Elasticity of substitutionSee Section 16.4

The elasticity of substitution is the elasticity of the MRS withrespect to the ratio y/x:

σyx = εRyx ,(y/x) =∂Ryx

∂(y/x)·

y/x

Ryx

In our case, Ryx = (y/x)2, so

σyx = 2 (y/x)y/x

(y/x)2= 2

which is why the function u(x , y) = 1x + 1

y is called a constantelasticity of substitution function.