expected returns to stock investments by angel investors ... · expected returns to stock...

50
WORKING PAPER SERIES FEDERAL RESERVE BANK o f ATLANTA Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in Groups Ramon P. DeGennaro and Gerald P. Dwyer Working Paper 2010-14 August 2010

Upload: dohanh

Post on 05-Aug-2018

227 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

WORKING PAPER SERIESFED

ERAL

RES

ERVE

BAN

K of A

TLAN

TA

Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in Groups Ramon P. DeGennaro and Gerald P. Dwyer Working Paper 2010-14 August 2010

Page 2: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

The authors thank the Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation for providing the data and Rob Wiltbank for help in clarifying some of the data’s features. The authors are grateful for helpful comments from Stephen M. Miller, Bruce Mizrach, and Paul Thistle as well as from participants in Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Conferences on Entrepreneurial Finance; the European Financial Management Association’s Symposium on Entrepreneurial Finance and Venture Capital Markets; conferences organized by the Association for Private Enterprise Education and the Society for Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics; and the College of Charleston and the University of Nevada at Las Vegas. DeGennaro thanks the University of Tennessee College of Business and the university’s Scholarly Activities Research Incentive Fund for support. Dwyer thanks the Spanish Ministry of Education and Culture for support of project SEJ2007-67448/ECON. The views expressed here are the authors’ and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta or the Federal Reserve System. Any remaining errors are the authors’ responsibility. Please address questions regarding content to Please address questions regarding content to Ramon DeGennaro, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996, [email protected], 865-974-1726, 865-974-1716 (fax), or Gerald Dwyer, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta and the University of Carlos III, Madrid, Research Department, 1000 Peachtree Street, N.E., Atlanta, GA 30309-4470, [email protected], 404-498-7095, 404-498-8810 (fax). Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta working papers, including revised versions, are available on the Atlanta Fed’s Web site at frbatlanta.org/pubs/WP/. Use the WebScriber Service at frbatlanta.org to receive e-mail notifications about new papers.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA WORKING PAPER SERIES

Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in Groups Ramon P. DeGennaro and Gerald P. Dwyer Working Paper 2010-14 August 2010

Abstract: Angel investors invest billions of dollars in thousands of entrepreneurial projects annually, far more than the number of firms that obtain venture capital. Previous research has calculated realized internal rates of return on angel investments, but empirical estimates of expected returns have not yet been produced. Although calculations of realized returns are a valuable contribution, expected returns, rather than realized returns, drive investment decisions. We use a new data set and statistical framework to produce the first empirical estimates of expected returns on angel investments. We also allow for the time value of money, which previous research has typically ignored. Our sample of 588 investments spans the 1972–2007 period and contains 419 exited investments. We conduct extensive tests to explore potential bias in the data set and conclude that the evidence in favor of bias is tenuous at best. Our results suggest that angel investors in groups can expect to earn returns that are on the order of returns on venture capital investments. Estimated net returns are about 70 percent in excess of the riskless rate per year for an average holding period of 3.67 years. This estimate is reasonable compared to Cochrane’s (2005) estimate of 59 percent per year for venture capital investments, which tend to be in lower-variance, later-stage projects. Returns have a large variance and are heavily skewed, with many losses and occasional extraordinarily high returns. JEL classification: G24, G20 Key words: angel investor, expected return, private equity

Page 3: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

1

Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in Groups

I. Introduction

An angel investor can be defined as a person who provides funds to a private business

which does not have publicly traded stock and is owned and is operated by people who are not

relatives or friends of the investor. Acting as informal venture capitalists, angels invest billions

of dollars in thousands of fledgling companies annually. What returns can these angels expect to

receive on their investments? Although previous work has explored realized returns, this paper is

the first to obtain estimates of expected returns on angel investments in a form comparable to

reported expected returns on stock or venture capital.

Until recently, research on the returns to investments by angel investors and angel groups

has been limited because suitably large data sets simply have not been available. For example,

Goldfarb, Hoberg, Kirsch and Triantis (2009) have just 32 angel-only investments in their study

of private equity, and not all of them are exited investments. The Angel Investor Performance

Project recently has produced an informative database on angel investments. In contrast to

Goldfarb, Hoberg, Kirsch and Triantis (2009), these data have 588 investments of which 419 are

exited investments.

We use these data to explore the expected returns on angel investments. Our paper is

similar in spirit to Cochrane (2005), who estimates the returns on venture capital investments,

and to Barnhart and Dwyer (2009), who estimate the returns on traded stock in new industries. It

differs from Wiltbank (2005) and Wiltbank et al. (2008) because we estimate expected returns

rather than realized returns. Thus, our paper combines these strands of the literature by

estimating expected returns on angel investments. The distinction between realized internal rates

Page 4: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

2

of return and expected returns is critical. Realized internal rates of return do not drive financial

decisions. Expected returns drive financial decisions.

II. Prior Literature

Angel investors and their investments are not well documented. This is partly because

individual investments tend to be informal, so there is little or no documentation or data. Also,

practitioners and academics have not reached a consensus concerning even the definition of an

angel investor. Shane (2008, 2009) provides a wealth of institutional details along with a good

review of angel investors and their investments. Shane shows how the lack of consensus leads to

divergent conclusions about the size and nature of the angel market. Our definition is: An angel

investor is a person who provides funds to a private business which does not have publicly traded

stock and is owned and is operated by people who are not relatives or friends of the investor.

This definition is the same as Shane’s (2009, p. 14) except that it explicitly limits angel investors

to investors in firms that do not have publicly traded stock.1

Wiltbank et al. (2008) report that angel investors invest their capital directly in early-

stage ventures, in many more businesses than do formal venture capital firms and usually in

much smaller dollar amounts. They also note that angel investors are often the first outsiders to

supply equity capital to entrepreneurs trying to build a business, even before formal venture

capital is obtained. Formal venture capitalists invested less than two percent of the total capital in

seed-stage companies during the last ten years.

Wiltbank and Boeker (2007a) also report an important trend: individual investors

increasingly are forming angel investor groups. Wiltbank and Boeker list several advantages to

group membership and investment including shared expertise and diversification. According to

1 Otherwise Warren Buffett would be an angel investor in Goldman Sachs, which is not the sort of investment generally considered to be an angel investment. We thank Stephen Miller for noting this.

Page 5: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

3

the Angel Capital Education Foundation, about 10,000 accredited angel investors belonged to

265 angel groups as of 2007.

Shane (2005) reports information gleaned from four focus groups of angel investors.

These angel investors are diverse in their backgrounds, their motivations for investing and in

their investment approaches. Not surprisingly, their investments also are diverse.

Mason and Harrison (2002) and Wiltbank (2005) are among the first to explore the

returns on angel investments. Mason and Harrison’s data are for the U.K. and Wiltbank’s data

are for the U.S. Their results are broadly consistent: returns less than the investment predominate

with a few spectacular returns of 100 percent net of investment or even much more. Compared to

U.K. returns, U.S. returns are more extreme with more returns less than the investment and more

net returns above 100 percent.

Much of the research on angel investors examines management strategies. For example,

Wiltbank et al. (2008) examine 121 angel investors who made 1,038 new venture investments.

They distinguish between prediction and control strategies. Investors who use prediction

strategies attempt to predict events and position themselves to capitalize on them. In contrast,

investors who use control strategies focus on the subset of events that they believe they can

control and optimize accordingly. Sarasvathy (2001) suggests that investors have no reason to

predict events to the extent that they can control them. Wiltbank et al. (2008) report that angels

who use prediction strategies tend to make significantly larger venture investments. Angels who

use control strategies have fewer failures.

Goldfarb et al. (2009) study data from the failed law firm of Brobeck, Phleger &

Harrison. The data contain 182 deals involving a first issue of equity made from 1993 to 2002.

Of the 182 deals, there are just 32 angel-only deals. Goldfarb et al. report four main results. First,

Page 6: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

4

if the capital requirements are small, then the deal can be angel-only, venture capital-only, or

mixed. Larger deals include venture capital participation. Second, in first-round financing,

called Series A deals, angels almost always take preferred shares. In these data, deals with angel

investors have weaker control rights even after controlling for size, age and other variables that

might affect risk preferences. Third, among smaller deals, angel-only deals fail the least often.

This could be due to what Goldfarb et al. call “inactive” firms, firms that have not officially

failed but which have no positive value. Fourth, large deals with only venture capital tend to be

more successful than large mixed deals. Goldfarb et al. speculate that some deals require a

sufficiently large amount of funds that venture capital cannot be excluded even if such funding

seemingly lowers the probability of success.

Goldfarb et al.’s study requires a major qualification: They treat angel groups as venture

capital firms. They say that there are “a small number” of such deals. They add that their results

are robust to the classification of investor classes. Still, their conclusions may not apply to angel

groups.

Moskowitz and Vissing-Jorgensen (2002) study the returns on private equity investment.

They report that private-equity returns are no larger and may very well be smaller than returns on

public equity portfolios. This is true despite the greater concentration of risk and higher variance

of private-equity returns. This suggests a private-equity premium puzzle with private equity

paying too little, which is the opposite of the public-equity premium puzzle. For an investor with

a relative risk-aversion coefficient of two, private equity held in such concentrated amounts must

return ten percent more than public equity portfolios to offer fair compensation for the level of

risk borne. Moskowitz and Vissing-Jorgensen report that the shortfall is about $460,000 during

the working life of an entrepreneur. They suggest six possible reasons why entrepreneurs might

Page 7: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

5

accept this apparent reduction in their wealth. These are optimal contracting and moral hazard,

higher risk tolerance, other pecuniary benefits, nonpecuniary benefits, skewness preference and

over-optimism.

Our paper is similar in spirit to Cochrane’s paper (2005), which examines the distribution

of returns on venture capital investments from 1987 through June 2000. He finds that his sample

of venture capital investments has expected proportional returns on the order of 59 percent per

year. He concludes that venture capital investments and the smallest NASDAQ stocks have

roughly similar returns and return volatilities during his sample period. Barnhart and Dwyer

(2009) show that expected returns to investors in stocks in new industries are positive and

approximate those of market returns. Ex post returns reflect infrequent but very large gains and

frequent but smaller losses, and the payoffs are broadly consistent with a log-normal distribution

of expected returns.

III. Data

This paper uses data from the Angel Investor Performance Project (AIPP).2 Wiltbank and

Boeker (2007a) report that these data contain survey responses from 86 angel groups totaling 539

investors who had made 3097 investments. Exits had been achieved for 1137 of those

investments. Not all of these investors provided data for the variables used in our analysis. We

find 588 useable investments in the data. Of these, 419 have exited. Wiltbank and Boeker discuss

non-response bias and other possible problems with survey data but provide evidence that the

AIPP data are relatively free of such problems. They conjecture that the most likely source of

bias is that respondents might report good investment outcomes and neglect poor outcomes.

Although the response rate by groups is 31 percent, the average response rate of members of

2 Information and the underlying data are available at http://www.kauffman.org/aipp.

Page 8: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

6

those groups is only 13 percent. With such a low response rate, the concern is that responders

may not be representative. For example, responders may be those with higher returns. Wiltbank

and Boeker, however, report that the distribution of reported returns is similar for groups with

response rates of 60 to 100 percent as for groups with a much lower response rates. If the

distribution of returns is the same across these groups, then this provides little evidence of

correlation of return with reporting frequency.

The potential for sample-selection bias compared to other samples remains, though. The

AIPP angels are not representative of angels in general because all of the AIPP angels are

members of angel groups and are accredited investors. The restriction of any conclusions to

angel groups when the data cover only angel groups is inevitable. In addition, AIPP investments

are all equity, whereas Shane (2009, p.80) finds that 40 percent of the dollar value of angel

investments is debt. Debt investments by angel investors may generate lower expected returns

than the AIPP data represent. We attack the issue of selection bias along two lines. First, we

compare the return multiples from the AIPP to other reported measures. For the most part, the

AIPP numbers are similar to those reported by other researchers. Second, we compare other

AIPP variables such as the proportion of IPOs, buyouts and failures to other datasets. We find

only relatively small deviations between the AIPP and other reported values.

Because these tests are lengthy, we provide details in Appendix I and a brief summary in

the text. There is some evidence of selection bias, but the evidence is far from overwhelming.

The most convincing evidence of bias is the high percentage of AIPP investments that result in

an IPO, which may inflate the reported performance of the angel groups that participated in the

AIPP.3 However, implied internal rates of return and return multiples are comparable with

3 A recent paper by Ball, Chiu and Smith (2008) identifies forces that drive the choice between venture capital exits by IPO or by acquisition. Such forces could drive angel exits, too, and these could account for the differences

Page 9: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

7

figures from other sources, especially on a value-weighted basis. In addition, the data survive

several checks designed to detect bias. For example, we might expect larger deals to be less

prone to bias because survey respondents are more likely to remember those deals correctly. We

find, though, that multiples from deals larger than the median do not differ statistically from

those smaller than the median. Deals with more than one angel group member might be more

likely to be reported accurately, yet we find no evidence from the number of co-investors that the

annual return multiple is biased upward.

The financial variables in the AIPP are the key for our purposes. Because the AIPP

reports information about initial investments, intermediate cash flows and exit values, we are

able to compute both total returns and internal rates of return. From these, we can then estimate

expected returns.

Figure 1 diagrams cash flows between the angel investor and the entrepreneur in these

data. Flows above the horizontal time line are cash flows from the entrepreneur to the angel

investor. Flows below the line are cash flows from the angel investor to the entrepreneur.

Investments in the project made after the initial investment are called follow-on investments. The

AIPP calls the first of these follow1invest and the second follow2invest. In both cases the data

contain the dollar amount and date of these investments. The AIPP sums any subsequent

investments and reports the total as followxinvest. For these, the dollar amount is available but

not the year of the investment. These three cash flows are reported 117, 24 and eight times,

respectively. For exited projects, these cash flows occur 106, 19 and seven times, and all

reported values are positive. Midcash is the total dollar amount of any cash flows from the

project to the angel investor before the exit date. The AIPP does not report the year of these cash

flows. Midcash is positive for 78 investments, and all of these are exited investments.

between the exit proportions of Band of Angels and the AIPP dataset. We have no way to control for these factors.

Page 10: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

8

Most previous work on angel investments uses base multiples, defined as total cash flows

to the investor divided by total investments. This has the advantage of simplicity but ignores the

opportunity cost of the timing of cash flows. We use present values for all computations. We do

this by discounting these cash flows from the year in which they occur to the year of the initial

investment at the risk free rate. This means that all expected returns are excess returns: returns in

excess of the risk free rate.

Using the risk free rate may seem strange given that angel investments are risky. Our use

of the risk-free rate does not mean that our calculations assume that the investor would invest in

a risk-free asset if the angel investment were not available. The purpose of discounting is to

bring all cash flows to a common date. Appendix II contains the details of the present value

calculations.

IV. Issues in Estimating Expected Returns

The purpose of our paper is to estimate the expected returns on angel investments. This is not

as simple as it might seem because the observed returns on angel investments are influenced by

choices that investors make. What sorts of the choices are they?

A. The Investor’s Exit Rule

We assume that investors maximize their expected utility of consumption, which is

increasing in the payoff from the investment. We assume that the investment lasts a finite period.

The investor’s choice is an application of investment theory tracing to Frank Knight and

Irving Fisher. The expected present value of utility of the cash flows is

( ) [ ]0

E E ( )T

T t

t

U e u S T e u I t dtδ δ− −

=

= −⎡ ⎤⎣ ⎦ ∫ (1)

where E denotes expected value, [ ].te uδ−

is the investor’s utility function for each period

discounted t periods by the discount rate δ, S(T) is the value of the investor’s payoff at T, I(t) is

Page 11: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

9

the value of the investment at t, the date when the investment begins is t=0 and T is the project’s

termination date. The investor chooses I(t) and T to maximize this expected present value. For

simplicity, we set I(t) to a constant I determined at the start of the project, in which case equation

(1) is

( )E TU e u S T u Iδ− ⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤⎣ ⎦⎣ ⎦= − (2)

Making I(t) variable would complicate the algebra without adding any insights. Maximizing

equation (2) with respect to T implies that the partial derivative is set to zero, which implies after

some rearrangement that

( )( )

( )E

.E

du S T dS TdS T dT

⎡ ⎤⎡ ⎤⎣ ⎦⎢ ⎥⎢ ⎥⎣ ⎦ = (3)

This states that the expected increase in the utility of the value of the project relative to

the expected utility of the value of the project equals the discount rate at the end of the project. If

the utility of the value of the investment is increasing at a decreasing rate

( ( ) ( )22 / 0d u S T dS T <⎡ ⎤⎣ ⎦ ) and the value of the investment as a function of time is decreasing at

a decreasing rate ( ( ) / 0dS T dT < ), then this solution for the stopping time is a maximum.

Researchers commonly suppose that marginal utility is decreasing in wealth. Even so, it is

possible and even plausible that the value of the investment increases at an increasing rate before

it starts to increase at a decreasing rate, which could result in the expected increase in marginal

utility increasing for a time before it decreases.

Discounting the future value S(T) does not change the basic message. With the value S(T)

Page 12: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

10

discounted at the risk-free rate r with ( ) ( )rTS T e S T−= and ( ) ( )/u du S T dS T′ = ⎡ ⎤⎣ ⎦ , equation

(3) evaluated at T is

( ) ( ) ( )1 .r T t dS Tu e rS T

u dTδ− ⎡ ⎤′

+ =⎢ ⎥⎣ ⎦

(4)

Although more complex than Equation (3), this represents exactly the same condition evaluated

at T.

The choice to exit with zero payoff is not necessarily included in this characterization of

the optimal exit time. That choice also will be made if it maximizes expected utility. Exiting the

project with a zero payoff can be included by generalizing the condition for exit to

( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

( )

1

0

r T t dS TuS T e rS Tu dT

S T

δ−⎛ ⎞⎡ ⎤′+ =⎜ ⎟⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟⎣ ⎦⎝ ⎠

(5)

which includes the prior solution for a positive ending value as a special case.

The overall implication is that the exit decision is exogenous. The entrepreneur maintains

his investment in the project until it no longer earns the opportunity cost of the investment.

Although the form of the exit may vary, the timing of the exit is exogenous.

B. Computing Expected Returns

Though the computation of internal rates of return from actual investments is

straightforward, the calculations are more subtle and complex in the context of expected returns

with different project lives. Average internal rates of return per year are average returns per

project lasting T years. This is given by [ ]E E ( 1) / ( ) 1.R S t S t= + − For angel investments in Wiltbank

and Boeker’s (2007b) data, average internal rates of return are on the order of 27 percent

Page 13: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

11

annually. Expected returns may well be similar to these actual returns, although this is not

inevitable.

A large proportion of angel investments return nothing (see DeGennaro, 2010). Standard

Brownian motion for the value of equity is inappropriate for angel investments because the value

of the equity can never be zero if it can be represented as a logarithm. To circumvent this

complication we start the analysis from standard Brownian motion for the value of the firm’s

assets A(t), rather than the equity. The firm’s assets consist of debt D and equity S. For analytical

purposes, we assume that the firm ceases operations if the value of the firm’s assets is less than

the value of the debt. This guarantees that the value of assets is non-negative and except for a set

of measure zero, positive. The associated diffusion equation and conditions are

( ) / ( ) ( ), ( ) ( ) ( ), ( ) ( ),dA t A t dt dB t A t D t S t A t D tμ σ= + = + ≥ (6)

where μ is the expected return on the assets, σ is the underlying return volatility and B(t) is a

standard Wiener process. Ito’s lemma implies that

( )2ln ( ) 0.5 ( ), ( ) ( ),d A t dt dB t A t D tμ σ σ= − + ≥ (7) This can be written in terms of the ratio of the value of equity to debt, f,

( ) ( )2ln ( ) 1 0.5 ( ), ( ) ( ),d S t f dt dB t A t D tμ σ σ+ = − + ≥ (8) which can be rewritten as

( ) ( )2ln ( ) 0.5 ln 1 ( ) ( ), ( ) ( ),d S t dt d f t dB t A t D tμ σ σ= − − + + ≥ (9)

If we assume that the ratio of the value of debt to equity primarily is a drift term such as

( )ln 1 ( ) fd f t dtμ+ = and that the mean equity return is ,s fμ μ μ= − then the evolution of the value

of owner’s equity is given by

( )2ln ( ) 0.5 ( ), ( ) ( ).sd S t dt dB t A t D tμ σ σ= − + ≥ (10)

Page 14: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

12

These equations indicate that the expected return for firms that end with a positive value

is ( )2exp 0.5α σ+ , where α is the log return for firms that end with positive value. If firms that

are terminated with a value of zero have the same variance of returns as other firms but a

different ex post realization,4 then an estimate of the expected return is

( )2exp 0.5 ,s pμ α σ= + (11) where p is the probability that a firm will end with a positive return.

Maximum likelihood is a natural estimator of the expected return. Campbell, Lo and

MacKinlay (1996), Gourieroux and Jasiak (2001), and Tsay (2002) provide the maximum

likelihood estimators of these parameters, which are

1

1 T

tt

rT

α∧

=

= ∑

2 2

1

1 [ ]T

tt

rT

σ α∧ ∧

=

= −∑ (12)

21( )2sμ α σ

∧ ∧ ∧

= +

where 1

ln ,N

t t ii

r S T T=

= Δ =∑ and t = 1, ..., T. The index t spans all project-years, so that an

observation is the log return for a year for a project.5 Barnhart and Dwyer (2009) provide details.

One benchmark for the return is the average annual return on stocks, which is consistent

with using each year of a project as an observation. If one is interested in comparing the expected

return in a typical angel investment for a year to stock returns, the returns should be weighted by

the number of years that the investment is ongoing. One ten-year project earning 10 percent

annually is equivalent to 10 one-year projects earning 10 percent. This is in contrast to

computations by Wiltbank and Boeker (2007b), for example, who weight each investment the

4 We offer empirical support for this assumption in the section that reports estimated expected returns.

Page 15: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

13

same regardless of duration.

V. A First Look at the Data

Table 1 presents summary statistics on the underlying data used in this paper. We use 588

observations from the AIPP data set that report the dollar amount and year of the initial

investment in each project. Of these 588 investments, a total of 419 are exited and 169 are not

exited as of the end of the data in 2007. If the project is exited, then the observation contains the

year of exit and exit cash. Investments made in the project after the initial investment are called

follow-on investments.6 The data contain the dollar amount and date of up to two such

investments. The AIPP also reports the total dollar amounts of any subsequent angel investments

but does not report the year or years of those investments. There are eight projects with more

than two investments. We know that any additional investment occurs after the second

investment and before the project is exited or else before the end of the dataset in 2007. The data

also include the dollar amount of any cash flows from the project to the angel investor before the

exit date but provide no information on the date. Such cash flows are reported 78 times. We

know that these mid-cash payments occur between the year of the initial investment and the year

of exit or the end of the dataset in 2007 but not the exact date.7

The maximum invested in projects by a single investor never is more than $5.1 million

and the mean is only about $147 thousand. Even this number is misleadingly large: the median

amount invested is only about $49 thousand. These are quite small investments by venture

5 This is different than Wiltbank and Boeker (2007b), who average net arithmetic returns across projects. 6 The AIPP calls the first of these follow-on investments follow1invest and the second follow2invest. There also is a followxinvest for the sum of any additional investments. 7 Projects with follow-on investments or mid-cash flows tend to be a bit longer than those without them. Investments with mid-cash payment last an average of 4.7 years compared to 3.3 years for those with no mid-cash payments (t-statistic = 3.6). Projects with one follow-on investment last 4.2 years versus 3.4 years for those without (t-statistic = 3.1).

Page 16: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

14

capital standards. Cochrane (2005) reports an average of $6.7 million per round in his sample of

venture capital investments.

The total cash received by investors from exited projects ranges from zero to $33 million

and also is heavily skewed to the right, with a mean of $490 thousand and a median of only $42

thousand. Total investments and cash received take no account of the timing of the cash flows

and neither does the base multiple commonly used by practitioners. Because of its wide use, we

include the base multiple in Table 1 even though it takes no account of the time value of money.

The base multiple computed as the present value of receipts relative to the present value of

investment, or PV base multiple, shows the ratio of receipts relative to investment with both

valued at a common date. The median PV base multiple is less than one, indicating that more

than half the projects return less than their investment. However, the mean PV base multiple is

7.37, well above one. The maximum PV base multiple is 1,333, which is extraordinary.

The net returns and log returns tell a similar story of frequent low returns and infrequent

high returns. The net return is the internal rate of return on the project, with all funds discounted

back to the investment date at the risk-free rate. The mean net return of the 408 completed

projects with a duration of a year or more is 29 percent, but the median is -2 percent with a range

from 0 to 3,241 percent. The log returns, which necessarily exclude the completed projects with

zero payoff, have a positive median which is less than the mean, but not by as large a value as

the net returns.

Aspects of the investments themselves are interesting. The data indicate that investors

spend a fair amount of time on due diligence before investing. There is positive skew in these

numbers, as there is for payoffs. The mean number of hours of due diligence is 65.4, with a

median of only15 and a reported range from zero to 5,000 hours. Surprisingly, the data provide

Page 17: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

15

no support for the notion that angel investors tend to invest more time on due diligence as

investment amounts increase. The correlation of due diligence and the initial investment is only

0.04 with a p-value of 0.68 and the correlation of due diligence and total investment it is only

0.03 with a p-value 0.71. What does attract an angel investor’s attention is the percentage of his

wealth that he invests in angel investments. The correlation between the amount of due diligence

and the percentage of an angel’s wealth invested is 0.15 (p-value 0.09). Angel investors

apparently take extra care to evaluate projects if they are likely to be disproportionately invested

in startup and early-stage companies relative to the rest of the market portfolio.

For projects that include stage information, almost half are startups. Seed and startup

companies are more than three-quarters of all projects. Turn-around firms and late-stage

companies are the smallest proportion of the investments. The data also indicate that investors

are engaged with the firms in most instances, with over three quarters of investors interacting

with the firm once a quarter or more and 23 percent of investors interacting with the firm weekly

or daily.

These data also support the conventional wisdom that members of angel investor groups

are seasoned investors with extensive business experience. Angel investors who reported

participating in AIPP projects have been making angel investments for an average of about 11.3

years. This masks a broad range of experience as angels, though. The angel investors in the data

have as few as one year’s experience to as many as 49 years’ experience as angels. They average

16.2 angel investments each and on average have exited from about 7.1 investments.

Angel investors clearly do not completely diversify away the firm-specific risk in these

investments. The mean percentage of wealth invested in angel investments is 13 percent, with a

median of 10 percent, reflecting a positive skew. The range of the percent of wealth invested is

Page 18: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

16

from one to 85 percent. Some angel investors need not be concerned with the idiosyncratic risk

of these investments; others are not likely to ignore the idiosyncratic risk of their angel

investments.

These angel investors are highly educated. Almost 70 percent of those who reported their

academic degrees have advanced degrees. Of the 132 angels who reported their academic

degrees (not including one “Other”), 40 had bachelors degrees, 67 had masters degrees, 10 held

law degrees and 15 had earned a Ph.D.

How do these angel investors exit from their investments? Table 2 gives the answer. Of

the 408 exited projects that last at least one year, 114 have the unhappy result that the firm ceases

operation. Selling the firm is by far the most common way that angels earn a return; in 180 cases

another company buys the firm and in an additional 20 cases other investors buy the firm. About

a quarter as many firms – 56 in all – exited by means of an initial public offering (IPO). The

fraction of IPOs for these exited firms lasting at least one year is about 13.5 percent, which is

relatively high compared to other estimates of the fraction of angel investments that culminate in

IPOs. We investigate this in the appendix. Here, we note that 13 of these IPOs have investments

in the same company in the same year and exits in the same year. Thirteen members of a group

saw a deal, bought in at the same time and later reported the deal to AIPP. If this single deal had

exited some other way, then the IPO percentage would drop to just over 10 percent of the exited

projects and a little more than seven percent of the full sample.

Table 2 also shows the net annual returns by type of exit. Not surprisingly, investments in

firms that cease operating have the lowest net return. These firms lose about 93 percent of their

value annually. Firms that have an IPO or are bought by another operating firm have the highest

average returns, about 94 percent annually.

Page 19: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

17

Table 3 shows the net returns and log returns by industry. We aggregate the data into the

categories listed in Table 3. Some of the “industries” listed in Table 3 such as “Business products

and services” are in the original data and some such as “Internet” are an aggregation of various

industries provided on the questionnaires. About half of the exited projects have industry missing

and the industry with the highest net return is “Missing”, so not too much should be made of this

information. Nonetheless, the distribution of investments is interesting. The largest industries in

terms of completed projects are software, consumer products and services and business products

and services. Business products and services is the industry with the highest mean return and IT

services is the industry with the lowest mean return.

Figure 2 shows the log returns for the projects by duration. The underlying data are

investments and payoffs, which we have reduced to a common date by the risk-free rate. Figure 2

shows the average log return in excess of the risk-free rate for each exited project by the

durations of the projects in years. The range of the log returns decreases as the duration of

projects increases, which suggests that the standard deviation decreases. Table 4 shows that the

standard deviation does indeed decrease as the duration of projects increases. This is not an

artifact of the existence of fewer projects for longer durations. The number of projects with

positive payoffs and durations of one to five years is 58, 49, 49, 51 and 33. Actually, the decline

in standard deviation is predictable. The annual return for T years can be interpreted as the mean

annual return for T years. If the standard deviation of the annual return is constant each year,

then the standard deviation of the annualized T-period return is the annual standard deviation

divided by T years.

Does the standard deviation diminish in this fashion? Table 4 suggests a qualified yes.

Table 4 shows that the one-year projects’ standard deviation is outsized relative to other years.

Page 20: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

18

The standard deviations for project longer than one year ranges from 0.11 to 0.80, which is quite

a range but far below the standard deviation for one-year projects. As expected, the underlying

annual standard deviations do not tend to decline with duration.

VI. Expected Returns

Table 5 presents the estimates of expected return. The first estimate is for firms that last

at least one year. Our estimate of the net return in excess of the riskless rate is 69.9 percent per

year. This may seem extraordinarily high if compared to returns on stock that have averaged on

the order of 11 or 12 percent per year in recent decades before the recent financial crisis. A more

appropriate comparison, though, is Cochrane’s (2005) estimate of 59 percent for venture capital.

Venture capitalists typically invest after angel investors, when risks tend to be lower. Expected

returns would be correspondingly lower.

The AIPP reports the duration of projects which last less than a year as having lasted zero

years. The second estimated expected return in Table 5 includes these firms using an estimate of

half of a year as the projects’ durations. As might be expected, this estimate of 71.4 percent is

little different than the expected return based on firms that lasted a year or longer. This is

because each observation is weighted by its duration, and six projects that last on average half a

year can have little effect given the size of the dataset and the duration of some of the projects.

Our model assumes that projects resulting in payoffs of zero have the same variance as

projects that result in nonzero payoffs. How reasonable is this assumption? Two parameters

identify a normal distribution. The mean and variance of the lognormal distribution imply a

unique associated truncated normal distribution and we can compute the implied fraction of

observations at the boundary of zero.8 We use the data for projects that last a year or longer. The

8 Stephen Miller suggested this in a seminar at UNLV.

Page 21: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

19

lognormal distribution for project-years with a positive ending value has a mean of 0.128 and a

variance of 1.010. The associated truncated normal distribution has a mean of 1.893 and a

variance of 3.651. This distribution has 16.1 percent of its mass at zero. Compared to the actual

value of project-years with zero payoffs of 10.2 percent (10.6 percent including projects that last

less than one year), an estimate of 16.1 percent would not dramatically affect our estimate of the

expected return from these investments. We conclude that the assumption that the variances are

the same for projects paying zero and projects paying nonzero amounts does not distort our

estimate.

VII. Conclusion

Angel investors collectively make extremely large investments in start-up firms. In many

cases they are the first outsiders to provide equity to new businesses. Research on angel

investments has lagged though, because large data sets have been unavailable or proprietary. The

Angel Investor Performance Project now offers the opportunity to conduct research that

previously has been impossible.

Previous research has calculated realized internal rates of return on angel investments.

Although this is an important contribution, internal rates of return are subject to misinterpretation

due to nonlinearities and statistical biases. Perhaps more important though, realized internal rates

of return do not drive financial decisions. Expected returns drive financial decisions.

Our results suggest that angel investors earn returns that are similar, at least in broad

measure, to the returns on venture capital investments and on new industries. We estimate an

expected return of about 70 percent per year in excess of the riskless rate. This compares to

Cochrane’s (2005) estimate of 59 percent per year for venture capital.

Page 22: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

20

References

Ball, Eric R., Chiu, Hsin-Hui and Smith, Richard L., Exit Choices of Venture-Backed Firms: IPO v. Acquisition (November 13, 2008). Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1301288.

Barnhart, Cora, and Gerald P. Dwyer. 2009. “Returns to Investors in Stock in New Industries.”

Unpublished paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. Campbell, John Y., Andrew W. Lo and A. Craig MacKinlay. 1996. The Econometrics of

Financial Markets. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Cochrane, John H. 2005. “The Risk and Return of Venture Capital.” Journal of Financial

Economics 75 (January), pp. 3-52. Cumming, Douglas J., and Uwe Walz. “Private Equity Returns and Disclosure Around the

World,” forthcoming, Journal of International Business Studies. DeGennaro, Ramon P. "Angel Investors and their Investments." Working paper, 2010. Goldfarb, Brent, Gerard Hoberg, David Kirsch, and Alexander Triantis. “Does Angel

Participation Matter? An Analysis of Early Venture Financing.” University of Maryland Working Paper. 2009.

Gourieroux, Christian, and Joann Jasiak. 2001. Financial Econometrics. Princeton: Princeton

University Press. Hamilton, Barton H. "Does Entrepreneurship Pay? An Empirical Analysis of the Returns to Self-

Employment." Journal of Political Economy, June 2000, 108(3), pp. 604-31 Malkiel, Burton and Atanu Saha. “Hedge Funds: Risk and Return,” Financial Analysts Journal,

Vol. 61, No. 6, November/December 2005. Mason, C. M. and Harrison, R. T. (1996). Informal Venture Capital: A Study of the Investment

Process, the Post-Investment Experience and Investment Performance. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 8: 105-125.

Mason, C. M. and Harrison, R. T. (2002). “Is It Worth It? The Rates of Return from Informal

Venture Capital Investments.” Journal of Business Venturing, 17, pp. 211–236. Moskowitz, Tobias J. and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen. “The Returns to Entrepreneurial

Investment: A Private Equity Premium Puzzle?” The American Economic Review 92, No. 4 (Sept. 2002), 745-778.

Phalippou, Ludovic and Oliver Gottschalg. “The Performance of Private Equity Funds.” The

Review of Financial Studies / v 22 no. 4, 2009, 1747-1776.

Page 23: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

21

Preston, Susan L. Angel Financing for Entrepreneurs: Early-Stage Funding for Long-Term Success. Jossey-Bass, 2007.

Puri, Manju and Rebecca Zarutskie. On the Lifecycle Dynamics of Venture-Capital- and Non-

Venture-Capital-Financed Firms. Working paper, June 2009. Reynolds, Paul D. (2007). Entrepreneurship in the United States: The Future is Now. Boston,

Kluwer Academic. Sarasvathy, S. D. 2001. “Causation and Effectuation: Toward a Theoretical Shift from Economic

Inevitability to Entrepreneurial Contingency.” Academy of Management Review 26, 243-263.

Shane, Scott A. “Angel Investing: A Report Prepared for the Federal Reserve Banks of Atlanta,

Cleveland, Kansas City, Philadelphia and Richmond.” (October 1, 2005). Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1142687.

Shane, Scott A. “Angel Groups: An Examination of the Angel Capital Association Survey.”

(January 1, 2008). Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1142645. Shane, Scott A. Fool's Gold? The Truth Behind Angel Investing in America. Oxford University

Press, 2009. New York. Tsay, Ruey. 2002. Analysis of Financial Time Series. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Wilson, Fred. (November 29, 2007). “Failure Rates In Early Stage Venture Deals.”

Downloaded from http://unionsquareventures.com/2007/11/failure-rates-i.php. Wiltbank, Robert. 2005. “Investment Practices and Outcomes of Information Angel Investors.”

Venture Capital 7 (October), pp. 343-57. Wiltbank, Robert and Warren Boeker. 2007a. “Returns to Angel Investors in Groups. Ewing

Marion Kauffman Foundation and Angel Capital Education Foundation. November 2007.” 16 pages.

Wiltbank, Robert, and Warren Boeker. 2007b. “Angel Investor Performance Project: Data

Overview.” 2007 Kauffman Symposium on Entrepreneurship and Innovation Data. Wiltbank, Robert, Stuart Read, Nicholas Dew and Saras D. Sarasvathy. “Prediction and Control

Under Uncertainty: Outcomes in Angel Investing.” Forthcoming, Journal of Business Venturing, 2008.

Page 24: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

22

Table 1 Sample Statistics

Number of

observationsMean Median Standard

Deviation Minimum Maximum

All projects Total investment 588 146,895 48,868 398,958 1,000 5,100,000 PV total investment 588 144,875 47,575 389,932 1,000 5,096,457 Years held so far 588 3.189 3 3.08 0 35

Exited projects Total investment 419 169,089 50,000 454,515 1,000 5,100,000 Total cash out 419 490,022 42,052 2,196,936 0 33,000,000 Base multiple 419 11.95 1.00 87.89 0 1,332.80 Years held 419 3.61 3 3.24 0 35 PV total investment 419 166,407 50,000 443,895 1,000 5,096,546 PV cash out 419 394,205 38,113 166,4952 0 21,876,92 PV base multiple 419 7.37 0.94 41.91 0 1,332.80 Net return 408 0.2938 -0.0176 2.2992 0 32.4112 Log return 291 0.2474 0.2154 0.7870 -2.3223 3.5089

Non-exited projects

Total investment 169 91,869 26,000 194,588 5,000 1,692,000 PV total investment 169 91,493 26,000 192,289 5,000 1,677,931 Years held so far 169 2.14 1 2.34 0 13

Characteristics of investments

Diligence (hours) 232 65.18 15 346.03 0 5,000 Stage of project at investment: percent of all projects

275

100.00

Seed 80 29.09 Startup 124 45.09 Early 51 18.55 Late 11 4.0 Turn around 9 3.27

Page 25: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

23

Interaction of investor with firm (percent)

Number of observations

Mean Median Standard Deviation

Minimum Maximum

242 100.0% Daily 33 11.83 Weekly 31 11.11 Monthly 44 15.77 Quarterly 71 25.45 Annually 17 6.09 Rarely or non 46 16.49

Characteristics of investors

Years investing 295 11.31 8 10.03 1 49 Number of projects invested in

338 16.17 9 19.49 1 63

Number of projects exited from

362 7.08 2 13.19 0 42

Percent of wealth in angel investments

237 13.05 10 15.22 1 85

Percent with degrees

Bachelor’s 40 30.30 JD 10 7.58 Master’s 67 50.76 Ph.D. 15 11.36

Total investment Total dollar amount invested in a project. PV total investment Total dollar amount invested in a project discounted at the riskless rate. Years Held Years between the angel investor’s initial investment in the venture and exit from the venture. Years held so far Years held for exited projects; the number of years since initial investment in the venture and the survey date for nonexited. Total cash out Total dollar amount paid to an investor by a project. PV total cash out Total dollar amount paid to an investor in a project discounted at the riskless rate. Base multiple Total cash out divided by Total investment. PV base multiple PV total cash out divided by PV total investment. Net return (PV Base multiple)(1/YearsHeld)-1. Log return ln(PV base multiple) /YearsHeld. Years Invested Years that the angel investor has been investing. Years Worked Large Angel investor’s years of work experience in firms with more than 500 employees. Total Investments Total number of angel investments that the respondent has made. Total Exits Total number of angel investment exits that the respondent has experienced. Diligence Number of hours of due diligence the angel investor group conducted prior to making the

investment.

Page 26: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

24

This table presents summary statistics for our data for all projects, both exited and non-exited. It presents summary data on the stage at which investments are made, interaction of the investor with the firm, and selected characteristics of the investors. There are 588 observations, of which 419 are exited. Of those 419 observations, 11 observations have durations listed in the data as 0 years, for which net returns and log returns cannot be calculated. In addition, 117 projects have durations of a year or more but have payoffs of zero. For these observations, the log return cannot be calculated.

Page 27: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

25

Table 2 Average Net Returns by Type of Exit

Exit Type Number Average Net Return Ceased operating 114 -0.930 Bought by another operating firm

180 0.8412

Bought by investors 20 0.4467 Initial public offering 56 0.9434 Other 9 0.0302 Missing 30 0.4445 Total

408

Net return (PV Base multiple)(1/YearsHeld)-1. Seventeen projects with durations less than a year are excluded from the averages. This table shows the net return rather than the log return in order to include firms with payoffs of zero. The category “Missing” are firms with computable payoffs and the type of exit is missing in the data.

Page 28: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

26

Table 3 Returns by Industry

Average Net Return

Industry Number of

Observations Mean Median Standard

Deviation Minimum Maximum

All 408 0.294 -0.018 2.299 -1.000 32.411 Biotechnology 8 -0.067 -0.506 1.131 -1.000 1.941 Business products and services 25 1.808 -0.080 6.945 -1.000 32.411 Communications 4 -0.326 -0.604 0.841 -1.000 0.902 Consumer products and services 21 -0.732 -1.000 0.497 -1.000 0.306 Electronics hardware 17 -0.107 -0.003 0.847 -1.000 1.845 Financial services 5 0.030 0.094 0.661 -1.000 0.830 Healthcare services 8 -0.152 -0.019 0.804 -1.000 1.242 IT services 7 -0.452 -1.000 0.744 -1.000 0.862 Internet 12 0.749 -1.000 0.591 -1.000 0.694 Media and Entertainment 17 0.069 -0.096 1.495 -1.000 5.609 Medical devices and equipment 9 -0.333 0.102 0.640 -1.000 0.265 Software 45 -0.117 -0.820 1.499 -1.000 7.575 Other 21 0.273 0.266 0.813 -1.000 2.824 Missing 209 0.518 0.168 1.803 -1.000 18.390

Page 29: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

27

Log Return including only observations with nonzero payoff

Industry Number of Observations Mean Median

Standard Deviation Minimum Maximum

All 291 0.247 0.215 0.787 -2.322 3.509 Biotechnology 4 0.549 0.565 0.451 -0.013 1.079 Business products and services 13 0.916 0.428 1.149 -0.083 3.509 Communications 3 -0.406 -0.840 0.913 -1.020 0.643 Consumer products and services 5 0.112 0.050 0.138 -0.035 0.267 Electronics hardware 12 0.080 0.082 0.600 -0.959 1.046 Financial services 4 0.224 0.149 0.268 -0.006 0.604 Healthcare services 5 0.255 0.224 0.339 -0.049 0.807 IT services 3 0.200 -0.0004 0.370 -0.023 0.620 Internet 2 0.400 0.400 0.180 0.273 0.527 Media and Entertainment 14 -0.042 -0.059 0.688 -1.023 1.889 Medical devices and equipment 5 0.181 0.217 0.064 0.098 0.235 Software 25 0.029 0.241 1.029 -2.213 2.149 Other 19 0.219 0.256 0.550 -1.542 1.341 The mean returns are proportional returns in the first part of the table and log returns in the second part. Hence, there are 408 observations in the first part of the table and 291 observations in the second part after excluding 117 projects with returns of zero. The returns are returns per project, not for project-years as are the returns in Table 5. The industries are our consolidation of the “industries” provided in the survey, which included most of these industries but include for example, “Local bank in Texas”.

Page 30: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

28

Table 4

Standard Deviation of Log Returns by Year

Duration Number of observations

Mean Median Standard deviation

Minimum Maximum Underlying annual standard deviation

1 58 0.929 1.338 1.156 -2.322 3.509 1.156 2 49 -0.145 -0.035 0.799 -1.542 1.889 1.129 3 49 0.340 0.484 0.497 -1.717 1.355 0.861 4 51 0.177 0.215 0.275 -0.596 0.842 0.550 5 33 -0.131 -0.285 0.319 -0.357 1.115 0.713 6 15 0.125 0.224 0.714 -2.213 1.045 1.749 7 13 -0.146 0.017 0.572 -2.017 0.326 1.513 8 9 0.198 0.159 0.195 -0.130 0.475 0.552 9 3 0.376 0.240 0.263 0.208 0.679 0.788 10 1 0.024 0.024 11 4 0.252 0.288 0.110 0.098 0.334 0.364 13 1 0.090 0.090 17 1 0.083 0.083 25 1 -0.031 -0.031 25 2 0.136 0.136 0.141 0.036 0.236 0.704 33 1 0.057 0.057 Total 291

All 291 projects that have positive exit values are included in this table. The standard deviation cannot be estimated in the usual manner when there is only one observation and there is no information in the minimum and maximum. The standard deviation multiplied by the square root of the duration provides an estimate by year of the underlying annual standard deviation of the returns.

Page 31: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

29

Table 5

Estimates of Expected Gross Returns

Number of project-years

Firms closed with zero payoff

Fraction of firms closed per project-years

Expected return conditional on positive payoff

Expected return

Projects that Last One Year or Longer 1,144 117 0.102 1.893 1.699

All Projects 1,147 122 0.106 1.918 1.714

The first estimate of the expected return uses all projects that last a year or longer. The second estimate includes projects coded as lasting zero years. We interpret zero years as a duration between zero and one year; we use one-half year as a point estimate of the projects’ durations. The three extra project-years are six half-year projects, of which five fail. In the estimates, each project is weighted by the number of years' duration. As a result, the six projects that are coded as 0 years in the data and given a duration of 0.5 years in the second line of the table add three project-years. The expected return is ( )( )2exp 1/ 2p α σ+ where p is the fraction of project-years that resulted in a project exiting with a positive return,

α is the mean log return and σ is the standard deviation of the log return.

Page 32: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

30

Figure 1

Flows above the horizontal time line represent cash flows from the project (the entrepreneur) to the angel investor. Flows below the line represent cash flows from the angel investor to the project (the entrepreneur). The 419 exited observations in the AIPP data set contain the dollar amount, year of the initial investment, exit year and exit cash, if any. Investments in the project made after the initial investment are called follow-on investments. The AIPP calls the first of these follow1invest and the second follow2invest. In both cases the data contain the dollar amount and date of these investments. The AIPP sums any subsequent investments and reports the total as followxinvest. For these the dollar amount is available but not the year of the investment(s). These three cash flows are reported 117, 24 and eight times, respectively, and all reported values are positive. For exited projects, these cash flows occur 106, 19 and seven times, and all reported values are positive. Midcash is the total dollar amount of any cash flows from the project to the angel investor before the exit date. The AIPP does not report the year of these cash flows. Midcash is reported 90 times, of which 78 are positive, and all are in the exited dataset.

Potential cash flows from angel investments

Exitmidcash exitcash

time

Initial investments followon1 followon2 followonx

Page 33: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

31

Figure 2

Log Returns per Project by Duration

Duration The log return for each project is on the vertical axis and the duration of the project on the horizontal axis. Dots sometimes overlap and therefore may represent more than one observation.

Page 34: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

32

Appendix I: Are the Data Biased? Researchers who study stock returns for publicly traded companies are fortunate in that

returns data are plentiful. This is not so for angel investments. As is true for other private

investments, transactions data are at best difficult to find and potentially unreliable if indeed they

can be found. In this section we identify potential problems with the AIPP data, compare values

for available returns and other characteristics with other data sources, and speculate on the effect

of any biases that may be embedded in the data.

The first problem that users of survey data face is nonresponse bias. Not all people asked

to complete a survey do so, and those who complete the survey may differ systematically from

those who do not. Wiltbank and Boeker (2007a) report that the response rate of the AIPP is

uncorrelated with the return measure, called the base multiple. This argues against the claim that

the data are biased and that angels tend to report only good outcomes. Shane (2009), though,

remains cautious. Referring to the AIPP, he says, "...we need to treat studies of the performance

of angel investments with extreme caution." One reason for this is that the survey is of angel

groups, not the universe of angel investors. Members of angel groups are not representative of

angels in general; Shane reports that members of groups tend to be more successful than

individual angels. In addition to selection bias, he notes that a sample of exited investments

probably overweights established angels because younger groups tend to have fewer exits.

Malkiel and Saha (2005), who study hedge fund returns using the TASS database (1995-

2003), face two additional problems related to selection bias. The first is backfill bias (sometimes

called incubation bias) and the second is survivorship bias. The idea behind backfill bias is that

selection bias is compounded when those who report the data backfill the data on these funds that

Page 35: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

33

have done well. This is because hedge funds that have survived tend to have had good results in

the years before the recording period, too. In the case of TASS, there is a related bias: Some

funds may have reported data to another service previously. When those funds start reporting to

TASS they might not report all of the data that they gave to the previous service. Malkiel and

Saha say that the difference between backfilled returns and contemporaneous returns is over 500

basis points, which is statistically significant. Neither of these additional sources of bias is likely

to apply to the AIPP, though. The AIPP base multiples that we use are total returns on individual

investments, not annual returns on funds. As such, they are not subject to backfill bias.

Survivorship bias arises because returns in the database for any period are those of

surviving funds. Funds that fail do not report data. This biases reported returns up. Malkiel and

Saha are able to obtain the previous returns from some defunct funds and find that the difference

between surviving funds and defunct funds is over 830 basis points, which is statistically

significant. The AIPP may well be subject to survivorship bias. If so, then the return multiples

are probably too high. To check this, we next compare failure rates in the AIPP dataset with

venture capital failure rates, as well as comparing AIPP return multiples and implied internal

rates of return to those reported by other sources.

How do AIPP failure rates compare to failure rates on venture capital investments?

Our first bias check in the AIPP data set compares angel investment failure rates with

those of venture capital. Angel investments are riskier than venture capital investments, so AIPP

failure rates should be higher. Puri and Zarutskie (2009) use the Longitudinal Business Database,

which tracks all U.S. employer business establishments, which they match to Venture Source and

Page 36: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

34

VentureXpert. They define failure as leaving the database without experiencing a firm sale or

IPO. Their data begin in 1981. After five years, the failure rate of VC-financed firms is 20

percent and after 10 years it is 28.4 percent. These data are right-censored, though. For firms that

received venture capital financing before 1998, the figure is closer to 40 percent.9 The annual

failure rates at that point suggest that the total failure rate increases only slightly over the next

few years. They also report results for a “one-to-one matched sample.” These failure rates are

higher, 31 percent after five years and 36.4 percent after 10 years. Again, the evidence suggests

that the cumulative failure rate increases only slightly beyond ten years. These figures are much

lower than AIPP failure rates, especially given that the mean AIPP project lasts less than five

years. Complete failures (returning nothing) comprise 29.6 percent of the AIPP sample and 51.8

percent return less than the invested capital after adjusting for the time value of money (50.4

percent without the adjustment).

Anecdotal evidence from practitioners also supports the conjecture that AIPP failure rates

are higher than on venture capital. Fred Wilson, managing partner of the venture capital firm

Union Square Ventures, provides anecdotal evidence of even lower failure rates than Puri and

Zarutskie’s (2009) report for venture capital. Wilson (2007) defines failure as a project that

returns less than its required investment and refers to an informal “1/3” rule: “1/3 of the

investments will fail, 1/3 will under-perform expectations, and 1/3 will meet expectations.” He

also states that 20 percent failures, 45 percent under-performing, and 35 percent successes is

closer to what a “good early stage investor’s track record” should be. These failure rates are far

below those of angel investments in the AIPP data set.

Phalippou and Gottschalg (2009) use the Thomson Venture Economics cash flow data set

9 9 We thank Rebecca Zarutskie for this information

Page 37: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

35

and the VentureXpert data set to study private equity (not venture capital). Private equity

investors provide these data voluntarily. The VentureXpert data have a success rate of 45

percent. The cash flow data set has success rates of 50 percent. These cash flow figures are net of

the S&P500 return and net of fees. Phalippou and Gottschalg conclude that the cash flow data set

is biased high. The bias in failure rates, though, is probably only about five percentage points.

These private equity failure rates are comparable to those in the AIPP data set. Phalippou and

Gottschalg say that their private equity sample has poor performance relative to other assets of

similar risk, though. If so, then the failure rates of these other asset classes are likely lower than

our sample of (presumably riskier) angel investments.

In short, AIPP failures rates are higher than reported venture capital failure rates and

much higher than anecdotal evidence of those rates. Private equity failure rates are roughly

comparable. Based on failure rates, we conclude that there is little or no evidence of bias in the

AIPP sample of angel investments.

What do others say are the returns on angel investments?

Ideally, we could compare our estimates of expected returns to what other researchers

have reported. Unfortunately, this is not possible. To our knowledge, our paper is the first to

provide estimates of expected returns derived from reported transactions prices. The few

available estimates of expected returns come from surveys, and most focus on investment

multiples or internal rates of return. Still, we can compare some of those values to those from our

data. If the AIPP data are comparable to what others report, then we can probably conclude that

any bias is small – or at least, no worse than any bias in the other data sources.

Page 38: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

36

We begin with base multiples and IRRs. The equally weighted average of the base

multiples in our sample of 419 exited projects is 11.95. The average investment period is 3.62

years. This implies an IRR of 98.4 percent for the exited projects -- again, equally weighted.

How does this compare to what others have reported? Shane (2009, p. 193) says that, "Given the

failure rate of angel investments, successful angels target a thirty times multiple on their invested

capital in five years.” A multiple of 30 over a five-year period implies an IRR of 97.4 percent,

which is remarkably close to the 98.4 percent IRR in our data. This does beg the questions of

whether or not the survey respondents are answering a question that makes the two figures

comparable, and whether the AIPP respondents are “successful angels” or whether they are more

or less “successful.” There is no way to know. Another question is whether respondents who said

they expect an implied IRR of 97.4 percent meant that they expect individual investments to earn

an average of 97.4 percent, or whether they meant that they expect the total return on all of their

investments to be 97.4 percent. Put differently, did they report an equally weighted average or

did they report a value-weighted average? The close correspondence between the AIPP’s implied

IRR of 98.4 percent and the “successful angels’” implied IRR of 97.4 percent suggests that they

reported an equally weighted average.

Still, computing the comparable value-weighted average from the AIPP data is

worthwhile. The value-weighted base multiple of the full sample of 419 exited investments is

2.90, which is a bit less than a quarter of the equally weighted average. The value-weighted

average for the years the investments were held is 3.67 (obtained by computing the total amount

invested in each project, dividing by the total invested in all projects, multiplying each quotient

by the years held, then summing the 419 results). The implied IRR in this case is only 33.7

percent, which is probably not too different from the expected returns on other risky equity

Page 39: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

37

portfolios during the sample period. This is especially true given that these 419 investments have

all exited and probably will have done better than the nonexited investments in the AIPP, which

would reduce the implied IRR in the full sample. Based on these calculations derived from base

multiples, we conclude that if the AIPP data are biased at all, then the bias is likely to be small.

What other numbers in the AIPP dataset can we compare?

Preston (2007, page 92) gives IRRs and multiples for private equity. We reproduce Table

5.1 below:

Table 5.1, "Rates of Return for Private Equity Investments."

IRR (percent) Return on Investment Implied Holding Period Seed 60+/year 10x 4.9 yrs Start-up 50 8x 5.1 Early Stage 40 5x 4.8 Second Stage 30 4x 5.3 Near Exit 25/year 3x 4.9 Preston does not provide holding periods, so we have computed the implied holding

periods from the IRRs and multiples. Caveats are in order. First, Preston’s table is for private

equity. This would include investments by individual angel investors and venture capitalists as

well as angel groups such as those in the AIPP. Including individual angel investors would tend

to reduce the average returns and venture capitalists, who tend to invest in later-stage companies,

would probably do likewise. Second, we do not know whether the figures are equally weighted

or value-weighted. Given these caveats, how do these data compare to those from the AIPP?

First, we can see that the average holding periods are all longer than the AIPP data (3.62

years in Table 1). However, the AIPP values are not necessarily comparable to Preston’s

numbers. All of the holding periods used in the calculation of the AIPP holding period are for

exited investments. Because most investments in the AIPP data are relatively recent, the

Page 40: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

38

nonexited investments in the sample probably will run longer. If Preston’s figures refer to

investments over a period long enough to permit a stable proportion of investments to have

exited, then the holding periods would indeed be higher than the AIPP figure. Our take is that

Preston’s reported holding periods are at least roughly comparable to those in the AIPP. Second,

the AIPP’s weighted-average IRR is about 33.7 percent, which corresponds to Preston’s figures

for Early Stage or Second Stage investments. But Preston’s figures are for private equity. Early

Stage or perhaps Start-up investments are a better match for AIPP data because successful angel

groups tend to focus on start-ups and early-stage companies. The AIPP’s equally weighted

average of 98.4 percent would correspond to Seed funding, and although this is half-again as

large as the 60 percent minimum that Preston reports, it is probably not too far out of line given

that she reports a lower bound and may include investments by those who tend to earn less than

angel groups.

Reynolds (2007) reports the results of a survey of informal investors, which he defines as

friends, family members and individuals in the personal social networks of the entrepreneurs.

These informal investors report expected return multiples that vary by the size of the investment.

His Table 8.13 gives the percentage of survey respondents who claim to expect multiples within

selected ranges. We can gauge the mean response by multiplying the midpoint of the range by

the percentage of respondents who select that range. For investments comparable to the median

AIPP investment, informal investors expect a multiple of 6.94 and for the mean the figure is

6.78. These figures are subject to limitations. First, we do not know the expected duration of the

investments. Second, the figures might be biased low because the highest range a survey

respondent could choose was bounded at 20. Third, there is no way of knowing whether the

survey respondents provided an equally weighted expectation or a value-weighted expectation.

Page 41: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

39

Given these caveats, we can say that these multiples are a little lower than the equally weighted

averages in the AIPP data and much higher than the value-weighted average. We conclude that

Reynolds’ results do not suggest that the AIPP data are biased, or at least that they are not biased

relative to his. This is especially persuasive given that at least most of Reynolds’ informal

investors are not members of groups and we know that such investors tend to earn less than angel

groups.

Additional information about expected returns can be gleaned from the information that

angel groups provide to prospective entrepreneurs. For example, the website of Maine Angels, an

angel group in Portland, ME (visited December 11, 2008), says that it typically funds between

$100,000 and $2 million, and that, "Candidate companies should also have a high potential for

growth and profitability, can provide at least 35% of annual return of investment within five to

seven years and have a strategically planned and viable exit." All of the AIPP data are from a

period before 2008, so to the extent that expectations shifted between the time of the investments

in the AIPP projects and the end of 2008, these data may not be comparable. Still, the mean

investment in the AIPP data is $169,089 (median $50,000), and 80 percent of the investments

range from about $15,000 to about $300,000. Given that these figures are in nominal dollars, the

AIPP data, being earlier, should be smaller, though not by enough to make these investment sizes

comparable. A better explanation for the size disparity could be that the Maine Angels’ website

may refer to the total investment by the entire group. The AIPP data are investments made by

individual investors (though the individuals are members of a group). In short, the (individual)

AIPP investments are smaller than the average Maine Angel group investment, and the value-

weighted AIPP investment tends to return a bit less than the lower bound of Maine Angel’s

Page 42: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

40

expected amount (33.7 percent vs. 35 percent). Based on this, there is no evidence that the

returns on the AIPP data are biased high.

We can also compare the AIPP data on IPOs to those reported by other data sources.

IPOs are the gold standard for angel investments, providing the extraordinarily high returns that

catch the public’s eye. Band of Angels is perhaps the most famous angel group in the United

States. According to Band of Angels’ website (visited March 1, 2009), Band of Angels has had

nine IPOs out of 209 investments (both exited and nonexited). This is only 4.3 percent. In

contrast, the AIPP data have 56 IPOs out of 588 investments (419 exited plus 169 nonexited), or

9.5 percent. On the one hand, this is twice as high, but on the other hand, it is at least within an

order of magnitude.

In addition, the comparison is not quite as apt as it seems. Band of Angels’ figures are for

the entire group, while the AIPP data are for individual members within groups. For example,

suppose that one member of each of 10 different AIPP groups invests in each of 10 projects and

one of these has a successful IPO. The IPO rate for the groups is 10 percent. However, if two

members of one group invest in the successful IPO and only one in the other investments, then

the group success rate is still 10 percent (1/10) while the AIPP success rate almost doubles to 18

percent (2/11). Band of Angels, which reports figures for the entire group, would report a 10

percent success rate regardless of the number of individual angels who invest in each project.

This proves to be important because many angels in the AIPP data did invest in the same

IPO. In fact, 13 of the 56 IPO investments are the same deal. All 13 observations are from

members in the same angel group who invested in the same company in the same initial year and

exited in the same exit year. All earned the same base multiple. Thirteen members of a group

saw a deal, bought in at the same time and later reported the deal to AIPP. If we suppose that this

Page 43: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

41

single deal had exited some other way then the IPO percentage drops from 9.5 percent to just 7.3

percent. If we treat the 13 observations as a single successful IPO (as Band of Angels would do),

then the rate is 7.5 percent. These figures are still higher than Band of Angels IPO rate of 4.3%,

but they are considerably closer.

Moreover, the fraction of buyouts – probably the second most profitable type of angel

exit – is almost exactly the same. Band of Angels has had 45 “profitable acquisitions,” or 21.5

percent of its investments exit via buyout while the corresponding AIPP figure is 22.4 percent

(132/588; 73 additional sales resulted in a loss). This comparison is also not quite as apt as it

may seem, for the same reasons as for IPOs.

What does this tell us? It seems surprising that the investors in the AIPP would have a

higher figure than Band of Angels, and this stands as the strongest evidence that the returns in

the AIPP data are biased high. The comparable fraction of exits through buyouts, though, casts

some doubt on the conclusion that the returns are biased high.

Goldfarb, Hoberg, Kirsch and Triantis (2009, hereafter, Goldfarb et al.) use the records of

a failed law firm (Brobeck, Phleger & Harrison; hereafter, Brobeck). Unfortunately, their results

are not directly comparable to the AIPP because Goldfarb et al. include angel groups with

venture capital firms. Goldfarb et al. say that they conduct robustness checks and their main

results are not sensitive to the way that they classify investments as venture capital, angel,

founder or family. Still, this means that we cannot directly compare specific figures from

Goldfarb et al.'s angel data with the AIPP data because the AIPP is from groups and Goldfarb et

al. bury their groups with venture deals. But neither can we compare the AIPP data with

Goldfarb et al.’s venture capital results because those figures are dominated by venture capital

deals. We can argue that Goldfarb et al.’s angels, who are not members of groups, should be less

Page 44: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

42

successful than the investors in the AIPP (Shane, 2009). They probably conduct less due

diligence and have lower returns than the investments in the AIPP data. This is especially true if

some of Brobeck’s deals are loans rather than equity, because the AIPP data are all equity deals.

Finally, although Goldfarb et al. say that Brobeck entered deals of high quality, it took positions

in some of these deals and in the end, Brobeck did fail. Perhaps the deals were not as high

quality as it believed.

What do Goldfarb et al.’s data say? In addition to the classification issues noted above,

comparisons are problematic because Goldfarb et al. have only 32 angel investments. Here are

the outcomes for angel-only events from Goldfarb et al. and the corresponding figures from the

AIPP:

Investment status Goldfarb et al. AIPP IPO 3.1% (1/32) 9.5% (56/588) Acquisition 18.8% (6/32) 31.5% (185/588)* Failure 28.1% (9/32) 25.3% (149/588)** Non-exited 50.0% (of which 25% are active 28.7% (169/588) and 25% are inactive and very * Including 20 cases possibly failures) (16/32) that were "Bought by

Investors” would imply 34.9%. ** Including 73 exits at a loss would imply 37.8%.

The AIPP numbers do not sum to 100 percent because the AIPP data have categories

such as "Other." We include investments with missing exit information as being failures. These

numbers imply the following percentages for exited investments:

Investment status Goldfarb et al. AIPP IPO 6.2% 13.4% Acquisition 37.6% 44.1%* Failure 56.2% 35.5%** * 48.9% including "Bought by Investors." ** 53.0 including 73 exits at a loss.

Page 45: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

43

Because all of the Brobeck et al. deals are from 1993-2002 we compute similar numbers

from 1993-2002 below.

Goldfarb et al. AIPP

IPO 3.1% 12.3% (43/351) Acquisition 18.8% 41.9% (147/351)* Failure 28.1% 33.0% (116/351)** Non-exited 50.0% (of which 25% are active 8.0% (28/351) and 25% are inactive and very * Including 10 cases possibly failures) (16/32) that were "Bought by

Investors" would imply 44.7%. ** Including 58 exits at a loss would imply 49.6%.

As expected, the 32 angel investments from Brobeck et al. had a substantially lower

percentage of IPOs and acquisitions. However, they also had a lower percentage of failures. The

Brobeck data have much a lower percentage of exited projects. One interpretation of this

comparison is that the proportion of IPOs and acquisitions in the AIPP dataset are too high.

Another interpretation is that Goldfarb’s sample comprises only 32 deals and that the differences

are simply due to chance. The 3.1% IPO rate represents, after all, just one deal. Still other

interpretations are that the inferior results trace to Brobeck’s angels not being members of angel

groups, or possibly that they took debt instead of equity, or the deals were bad and contributed to

the firm’s failure. If any of these is true, then the superior performance of the AIPP investors is

unsurprising.

We can also check whether the AIPP data are comparable to other data along dimensions

other than returns. For example, Goldfarb et al. (2009) says that about 18.8 percent of angels in

angel-only deals had previously invested in the same company while Mason and Harrison (1996)

report 25 percent. The percentage of investments with follow-on funding in the AIPP, which is

Page 46: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

44

19.9 percent (117/588 deals), is comparable to these two figures. In addition, Cochran (2005)

reports that venture capital investments that receive follow-on funding tend to have done well. If

the AIPP data are biased, then we would expect them to have a higher proportion of follow-on

investments. However, they do not. Unless the deals in Goldfarb et al. or Mason and Harrison are

a biased standard, this stands as evidence that the AIPP data are relatively free of bias.

The number of coinvestors provides another avenue by which to gain insight.

Investments made with a coinvestor are probably less prone to bias because the survey

respondent is more likely to be caught reporting biased results. There is, after all, at least one

other person who knows about the project (even if he invests different amounts or at different

times). In our data this comparison is problematic because there are many missing values for

coinvestors. Still, it is worth doing. We find that t-tests show that the base multiple is

significantly different between investments with coinvestors and those without (t-ratio = 2.76),

and the point estimate suggests that base multiples are higher for deals without coinvestors. This

is indeed what we would expect if the data are biased. For annual multiples, though, the t-ratio

falls to 1.40. Regression analysis tells the same story. When we regress the base multiple on the

number of coinvestors, we obtain a significantly negative coefficient (-0.82, t-ratio = -1.98). This

is consistent with selection bias in the data, which is being mitigated on deals with many

coinvestors because the survey respondents are more likely to be caught reporting false data. Yet

this evidence of bias also vanishes with annual multiples; the estimated coefficient of -0.70 is not

close to being statistically significant (t-ratio = -0.94). This suggests that the regression is simply

measuring the relation between the number of coinvestors and the duration of projects rather than

the relation between the number of coinvestors and the total return multiple. Deals with more

coinvestors do, in fact, tend to be shorter. The correlation coefficient between the number of

Page 47: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

45

coinvestors and project duration is -0.24 with a p-value of 0.004.

We also have deal size. It seems reasonable that larger deals are more likely to be

remembered correctly. This alone would not eliminate intentional bias, but it would tend to

eliminate unconscious bias. People may still lie, but they are less likely to remember only the

good deals if the deals are large. Goldfarb, Hoberg, Kirsch and Triantis (2009) suggest that more

sophisticated investors are more likely to do larger deals, too. Arguably, these sophisticated

investors are less biased, or perhaps more likely to fear posting inflated results on the AIPP

surveys but smaller figures on, say, their tax returns. To check this, we compare multiples on

investments that are larger than the median with multiples on investments that are smaller than

the median. T-tests for both base multiples and annual multiples find no statistical significance.

The results show no evidence of bias.

Summary

What then, does the evidence say regarding bias in the AIPP data? Based on the high

percentage of investments that resulted in an IPO, we conclude that the data may contain some

biases that inflate the reported performance of the angel groups that participated in the AIPP. The

IPO comparison is not particularly apt, though, and the disparity in IPO rates in the AIPP dataset

is substantially increased by one deal that attracted 13 individual angel investments. In addition,

the evidence of bias is hardly overwhelming. First, the fraction of profitable sales is almost

exactly the same as Band of Angels. Second, failure rates are substantially higher than the

Brobeck data in Goldfarb et al. (2009), tilting the evidence of bias the other way. Third, implied

internal rates of return and return multiples -- which are, after all, the fundamental input to our

estimation procedure -- are comparable to figures from other sources, especially on a value-

Page 48: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

46

weighted basis. Finally, the data survive several checks designed to detect bias. The percentage

of follow-on investments in the AIPP data, which are correlated with higher returns at least on

venture deals, is comparable to figures that other researchers report. Multiples from deals that are

larger than the median do not differ statistically from those that are smaller than the median, and

although some tests using the number of coinvestors support the claim that base multiples are

biased high, there is no evidence of bias in annual multiples. The reason that base multiples

without coinvestors are higher than deals with coinvestors is that deals with coinvestors tend to

be shorter. The correlation coefficient between the number of coinvestors and project duration is

-0.24, with a p-value of 0.004.

Even if the AIPP data are free of bias, this does not mean that they are representative of

angel investments in general. This is because the angel groups which participated in the study are

not a random sample of all angel investors. Aside from the advantages that members of groups

enjoy, the types of investments differ. For example, Shane (2009) reports that many angel

investments are debt, whereas all of the deals in the AIPP are equity. Angel investors who are

members of groups tend to fare much better than those who are not.

Page 49: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

47

Appendix II: Data

Calculations of present values of the first two follow-on investments:

Because the AIPP data contain only the year of a cash flow, we assume that the cash flow

occurs at midyear and therefore treat a year as covering the period from July 1 - June 30. We use

end-of-month quotes from CRSP. This means that we use monthly 30-day (approximately) bill

rates from the previous months (June 30 - May 31). For example, if the initial investment is

made in year 2000 and the project exits in year 2001 then we use Treasury bill rates from June

30, 2000 - May 31, 2001. We adjust these rates for the actual number of days in the month and

sum the monthly rates over the period from the initial investment through the year of the follow-

on investment (or through the project’s exit) to compute the continuously compounded interest

factor for the entire period.

If the initial investment year is the same as the exit year then we use rates from the

middle of the year (March 31 - August 31), covering the period from April 1 - September

30. This also applies for later cash flows. For example, if the initial investment year is 2000 and

the follow-on investment is also year 2000 then we use rates from March 31 - August 31.

Calculation of present values of follow-on investments after the first two:

The AIPP does not report the year of follow-on investments after the first two. Instead,

the AIPP sums all remaining follow-on investments and reports this as a single number. The year

is not reported. This occurs eight times in the 588 observations and seven times in the 419 exited

investments. We assume that these follow-on investments occur midway between the second

follow-on investment and the exit year. In one of these eight cases the exit year is not reported

and in another the project has not yet exited. To handle these two cases we first calculate the

Page 50: Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors ... · Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors in ... Expected Returns to Stock Investments by Angel Investors

48

average time between the second follow-on investment and the exit. This is about 2.5 years. We

therefore add 2.5 years to the second follow-on investment in these two cases to obtain an

estimate of the year of these follow-on investments.

Calculation of present values of midcash payments:

The AIPP does not report the year of midcash payments. We assume that midcash

payments occur halfway between the beginning and end of the investment.