Transcript
Page 1: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

DI

SC

US

SI

ON

P

AP

ER

S

ER

IE

S

Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der ArbeitInstitute for the Study of Labor

Female Labour Force Participation and ChildEducation in India: The Effect of the NationalRural Employment Guarantee Scheme

IZA DP No. 6593

May 2012

Farzana AfridiAbhiroop MukhopadhyaySoham Sahoo

Page 2: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National

Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme

Farzana Afridi Indian Statistical Institute

and IZA

Abhiroop Mukhopadhyay Indian Statistical Institute

and IZA

Soham Sahoo Indian Statistical Institute

Discussion Paper No. 6593 May 2012

IZA

P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn

Germany

Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180

E-mail: [email protected]

Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post Foundation. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author.

Page 3: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

IZA Discussion Paper No. 6593 May 2012

ABSTRACT

Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme

*

E-mail:

We study the impact of India’s National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme (NREGS) on children’s educational outcomes via women’s labour force participation. Using data from the Young Lives Study and taking advantage of the spatial and temporal variation in the intensity of implementation of the NREGS, we find that greater participation of mothers in the program is associated with better educational outcomes of their children. Father’s participation in the NREGS, on the other hand, has a negative effect on children’s education. Further, the estimated impact of mother’s program participation is over and above any income effect induced by the scheme and is robust to concerns about endogeneity of labour force participation and differences in economic trends between districts. We provide evidence which suggests that the mechanism through which children’s educational outcomes improve is empowerment of mothers resulting from better labour market opportunities for females. JEL Classification: I21, I38, J16 Keywords: labour, education, gender, bargaining Corresponding author: Farzana Afridi Indian Statistical Institute Planning Unit 7, S.J.S. Sansanwal Marg New Delhi 110016 India

[email protected]

* We are grateful to Young Lives, which commissioned this study. The paper is under review for Young Lives Working Paper series. The data are from Young Lives, an international study of childhood poverty, following the lives of 12,000 children in 4 countries (Ethiopia, India, Peru and Vietnam) over 15 years (www.younglives.org.uk). Young Lives is core-funded from 2001 to 2017 by UK aid from the Department for International Development (DFID), and co-funded by the Netherlands Ministry of Foreign Affairs from 2010 to 2014. Sub-studies are funded by the Bernard van Leer Foundation and the Oak Foundation. The views expressed here are those of the authors and are not necessarily those of, or endorsed by, Young Lives, the University of Oxford, DFID or other funders.

Page 4: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

2

1. Introduction

The World Development Report (2012), focusing on gender equality, finds that women in

the poorer regions of the world continue to suffer from disadvantages in the economic

sphere. Although, significant progress has been made in reducing gender disparities in

health and educational outcomes, economic opportunities continue to be limited for

women. The Report underlines the policy priorities of closing gender differences in

access to economic opportunities and earnings as well as increasing women‟s voices

within households as a means to reducing poverty in developing countries. In this paper

we study the impact of one such policy initiative in India – the National Rural

Employment Guarantee Scheme (NREGS) initiated in 2006. While the program‟s main

objective is to alleviate rural poverty by legally guaranteeing a minimum of 100 days of

annual employment to households, it also has the potential to empower rural women

through greater access to labour market opportunities.

From a gender perspective, there are two interesting features of this program.

First, the wage rate provided in this program is uniform across gender, and second, it

gives priority to female employment and targets at least one third of the beneficiaries to

be women. Thus, NREGS not only has the potential to raise female labour force

participation rates by bringing employment opportunities almost to their doorsteps, the

equal wage rates provided in NREGS program can potentially reduce any gender

disparity prevalent in the rural labour markets. We, therefore, hypothesize that the

introduction of this program should lead to greater labour force participation of women,

either on the extensive or intensive margin or both.

Page 5: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

3

A rise in women‟s labour force participation can potentially impact individual and

household behaviour on several fronts including marriage, fertility, and intra-household

distribution of resources. This paper analyzes the effect of the exogenous policy shock of

the implementation of the NREGS on children‟s well being. Specifically, we explore

whether an increase in participation of mothers in NREGS projects affects the

educational outcomes of their children differently from that of fathers‟ participation in the

program. If yes, we attempt to understand the mechanism through which this differential

effect can be explained.

While an increase in either fathers‟ or mothers‟ labour supply could improve their

children‟s outcomes purely due to an income effect, greater labour force participation of

mothers could impact children‟s education through two additional channels. First, women

(including mothers) are likely to have more alternative uses of their time than men –

market work, household chores and leisure. If children‟s time in doing household chores

substitutes for mother‟s time then an increase in NREGS participation of mothers may

lead to a decline in educational attainment of her children.1 Second, mother‟s say in

household resource allocation decisions may rise due to her higher earned income.

Research suggests that this is likely to have a positive effect on her children‟s schooling.

If an increase in women‟s earned income is likely to translate into greater weight being

attached to their preferences in resource allocation decisions of the household and

mothers prefer to invest more in their children‟s health and education (Blumberg 1988;

Thomas 1990; Hoddinott and Haddad 1995; Quisumbing and Maluccio 2003), relative to

1 If mother‟s and children‟s time on household chores are not substitutes and child care services

in the market are either unavailable or unaffordable, then it is more likely that children are in

school when mothers are at work. If children attend school more regulary due to mothers

working, then children‟s educational outcomes might improve.

Page 6: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

4

fathers, then we should see an improvement in child outcomes. Therefore, an increase in

mother‟s decision-making ability within the family can have a positive impact on her

children‟s welfare (Thomas 1990; Thomas et al. 2002). To sum, the net impact of a

change in mother‟s participation in the labour force on her children‟s schooling depends

on which of these two effects dominates – the substitution effect or the effect of greater

bargaining power, holding household income constant.2

There exists relatively little empirical research on the impact of parental labour

supply on children‟s time allocation, particularly in a developing country context.

Skoufias (1993) shows that an increase in female wages in rural India reduces the time in

school significantly for girls only. Similar results were found by Grootaert and Patrinos

(1999) in a cross-country study. However, Ilahi (1999) does not find any impact of

female wages on children‟s time use in Peru.

In contrast to the sparse literature on time allocation effects, there is considerable

empirical evidence suggesting that households‟ resource allocation decisions are made in

a „collective‟ (Chiappori, 1988) or bargaining framework (McElroy and Horney, 1981)

where the final allocation usually depends on the bargaining power or weights attached to

the preferences of the members of the household. The importance of labour income as a

determinant of women‟s bargaining power within the household has been highlighted

recently by Anderson and Eswaran (2010). Using data from Bangladesh, the authors

show that the effect of earned income on female autonomy is far greater than that of

unearned income. Also, women who work on the household farm have no more

autonomy than those who are housewives, while those who earn independent income

2 We are abstracting from any long term effects of changes in fertility due to increased labour

force participation of women since we are looking at these changes over 2 to 3 years only.

Page 7: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

5

have considerably greater autonomy. Luke and Munshi (2011) exploit data from tea

plantations in South India where women are employed in permanent wage labor, to find

that a relative increase in female income has a positive effect on their children‟s

education. Qian (2008) shows that a change in agricultural pricing policy in post Mao

China which increased female labour income increased educational attainment of all

children. However, when the policy increased male labour income, educational

attainment for girls decreased but had no effect on boys' educational attainment.

Using data from the Young Lives Study (YLS) in the state of Andhra Pradesh in

India and taking advantage of the spatial and temporal variation in the intensity of

implementation of the NREGS within districts, we find that greater participation of

mothers in the program, relative to fathers, is indeed associated with more time spent in

school of children within households. We find that this effect on the educational outcome

of children is over and above any income effect induced by the NREGS. Moreover, the

impact is largely present for the poorest households and limited to the time spent in

school by younger children and girls. We also find that for poorer households greater

participation of mothers in NREGS has led to higher grade attainment of children. Our

findings are robust to concerns about endogeneity of labour force participation and

differences in economic trends between districts.

YLS data on household members‟ say in decision-making and control of income

from various sources show that participation in the labour force by mothers significantly

increases the probability that they have a say or control over utilization of earnings from

those sources. This result, together with the negative impact of father‟s days of NREGS

work and our finding that girls tend to benefit more from an increase in mother‟s

Page 8: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

6

participation in the program, suggests that women‟s preferences are the primary drivers

of the improvements in educational outcomes of her children when her program

participation is higher. Hence our results can be explained within the framework of a

bargaining model of household resource allocation.

The findings of our study not only inform us about the impact of female labour

supply on intra-household outcomes but it also addresses a broader policy question of the

effect of public programmes on improving household outcomes in developing countries.

Specifically, our paper extends the current debate in India on the impact of NREGS on

poverty (Ravi and Engler, 2009; Uppal, 2009) and finds evidence, albeit through the

channel of women‟s program participation, that supports preliminary findings of positive

benefits of NREGS on households.

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 gives the background on the National

Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme and motivates the study. Section 3 describes the

data and methodology used in this paper. Section 4 discusses the results and Section 5

concludes.

2. Background

The National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (2005) of India provides a legal

guarantee for up to 100 days of annual employment at a predetermined wage rate to rural

households willing to supply manual labour on local public works. The act was

operationalised through the National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme (NREGS)

which began in 2006. The program was rolled out in three phases. Initially restricted to

Page 9: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

7

200 “poorest” districts of India (February 2006), it was extended to 130 more districts in

May 2007 and to all districts across the country by 1st April 2008.3

We analyse data on individuals‟ labour force participation from Young Lives

Study (YLS) - a panel study aimed at understanding the dynamics of childhood poverty.

In India, YLS collects child level longitudinal data from six districts in the state of

Andhra Pradesh. To date, there have been three rounds of YLS surveys in Andhra

Pradesh – 2002, 2007 and 2009-10. We use data from rounds 2 (2007) and 3 (2009-10) of

the YLS for reasons of comparability. The NREGS had been implemented in four out of

six YLS districts in Andhra Pradesh by 2007 (Phase 1 districts), and the remaining two

districts were covered by the program by 2009-10 (Phase 2 & 3 districts). 4

Using data on NREGS participation of individual household members and

comparing 2007 and 2009-10, we find that the overall female labour force participation in

the age group of 16 to 60 years has increased substantially from 59 to 72 per cent while

the same for males has fallen marginally from 92 to 89 per cent (Figure 1). This rise in

female labour force participation is largely driven by casual labour (public and private).

Figure 2 shows that in 2007, 28 per cent of the females in this age group were involved in

casual wage labour, but in 2009-10, this number has risen to 45 per cent. However, unlike

females, participation of males in the casual labour market has not increased in this

period; rather, it has remained almost the same. Further disaggregating the labour force

participation rates across asset quartiles of the households, from Table 1 we see that the

rise in female participation in casual labour market is more prominent for poorer

3 Budgeting for NREGS is based on the financial year starting from April and ending in March of

the next year. 4 Anantapur, Cuddapah, Karimnagar and Mahbubnagar implemented the NREGS by 2007.

Srikakulam and West Godavari were the two districts that came under NREGS by 2009-10.

Page 10: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

8

households. In the lowest asset quartile, female casual labour has increased by 18

percentage points, while in the upper most asset quartile, it has risen by only 5 percentage

points.5

With respect to participation in NREGS, the annual average number of days a

household worked in NREGS has increased from around 11 days to 40 days (Figure 3).

This rise is more prominent in the districts where NREGS was implemented after 2007

(Phase 2 & 3). Moreover, participation of women in NREGS has increased substantially

as compared to men: while in 2007, both men and women in a household worked for

around 5 days on an average, in 2009-10, women worked for 23 days while men worked

for 17 days. Again decomposing the figures across asset quartiles we see that poorer

households tended to work for more days in NREGS, particularly in 2009-10 (Table 2).

Besides, the rise in female participation in terms of number of days worked in NREGS is

also more noticeable in the poorer households.

The data from the YLS establish that casual labour force participation as well as

NREGS participation has increased substantially more for women than men between

2007 and 2009-10. However, it is not clear from these data whether these trends are

attributable to NREGS implementation per se since the YLS does not have information

which would enable us to calculate casual private labour force participation trends.

Using household level data from repeated cross-sections in the National Sample

Survey (NSS) for the years 1999-2000 (55th

round), 2004-05 (61st round), and 2009-10

(66th

round) we report, therefore, the trends in wage rates and labour force participation

5 Asset Quartiles are generated from an Asset Index which is constructed by Principal Component

Analysis of several binary variables indicating consumer durable ownership at the household

level. The assets which are considered are: television, radio, car, motorbike, bicycle, telephone,

mobile phone, refrigerator, fan, electric oven, table and chair, sofa and bedstead.

Page 11: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

9

rates in casual wage labour for public and private works in the state of Andhra Pradesh.6

Since the NSS data span pre and post NREGS implementation, any structural changes in

the labour market caused by NREGS should be reflected through a change in the trend

after 2004-05.

Figure 4 plots the trends in mean real wage rates for public casual wage labour by

gender for the "working" age group of 16 to 60 years in Andhra Pradesh. While both the

female and male public wage rates show an increase between 1999 and 2009-10, we see a

steeper rise after 2004-05. Wage rates for women have increased by more than 79 per

cent as compared to 58 per cent for men between 2004-05 and 2009-10. The male-female

wage ratio has, thus, fallen: from 1.5 in 1999-2000 to 1.3 in 2004-05 and further to 1.1 in

2009-10.7 Thus, post 2004, women may be less discriminated in terms of wages for

public casual work than before.

We investigate next whether there has been any accompanying increase in labour

force participation rates for 16-60 year old men and women in public casual labour.8

From Figure 5 we see that there has been a drastic rise in labour force participation in

public works, both for men and women. While participation somewhat declined between

6 In 2009-10, large parts of India suffered from drought and it can be contended that this weather

shock would have affected labour outcomes in the rural economy. As a robustness check,

therefore, we also looked at NSS data for 2007-08. Most results reported in this section go

through. We report results with 2009-10 data since by then NREGS had been universally

implemented in India. 7 For the country as a whole, the wage ratio, which rose from 1.1 in 1999-00 to 1.7 in 2004-05,

has dropped back to 1.1 in 2009-10, thus exhibiting a potential declining trend post 2004. 8 We take into account casual labour done both as the principal occupation as well as a subsidiary

occupation.

Page 12: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

10

1999-00 and 2004-05 it has risen sharply to 6.41 per cent for men and 6.49 per cent for

women in 2009-10 from almost no participation in 2004-05.9

The analysis for private casual labour force participation does not exhibit the

trends we observe for public casual labour and is more or less flat for both men and

women although wage rates for casual private works have increased for both genders,

possibly due to substitution of labour from private to public works (Imbert and Papp,

2011). These results are reported in the Appendix. To summarize, our analyses indicate

that the trends we observe in casual labour force participation of women in the YLS may

have been driven primarily by public works or specifically, the NREGS.

3. Data and Methodology

A. Data

In order to identify the effect of the NREGS on children‟s education via their mothers‟

participation in the labour force, we conduct our empirical analysis at the level of the

child using the two comparable waves of the YLS surveys - 2007 and 2009-10. The panel

data set we construct is restricted to children in the age group of 5 to 14 years in 2007, the

school going age group. In order to construct our data set we use the following exclusion

rules: first, we include only children living in rural areas in both periods. This rules out

children who may have migrated to urban areas. However these form less than 1 per cent

of our sample. Second, we exclude children for whom we cannot identify mothers in the

sample (5 per cent of the original sample). Third, for econometric reasons explained

9 These trends hold for the country as a whole, although the increases are smaller in magnitude.

The rise in female labour force participation rates in public works has been from 0.09 per cent in

1999-00 to 0.21 per cent in 2004-05 and then to 2.74 per cent in 2009-10. A similar trend is

visible for men.

Page 13: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

11

below, we restrict our attention to children present in both rounds of the survey; we thus

drop 2.9 per cent of the children present in 2007. Finally, we exclude children for whom

there is some missing information on relevant covariates in either of the years. Our data

set, after these exclusions, contains information on 2893 children for both years.

Table 3 describes the relevant summary statistics of our data-set for 2007 and

2009-10. The time spent in school by children in the reference period (a typical day in the

last week) has gone up from 5.87 hours in 2007 to 7.06 hours in 2009-10. This increase in

time spent in school is largely reflective of more regular school attendance. Children in

the survey, who reported attending school regularly, spent almost two hours more in

school than those who reported going to school irregularly, on a typical day. We can,

therefore, interpret greater time spent in school by a child as an indicator of greater

number of days of school attendance.

The rise in time spent in school was accompanied by a rise in the highest grade

completed during this period. But the highest grade completed rose by less than the 3

year increase in the average age during the same period indicating either grade repetition

or drop-outs. However, enrollment rates rose by 10 percentage points, largely a result of

most 5 year olds joining school by 2009-10.10

During the same period, the proportion of children with either parent working in

NREGS almost doubled. This increase in participation on the extensive margin was

accompanied by a rise in the number of parental days of work on NREGS projects as

well. The proportion of children whose mothers were working in NREGS rose from 28

10

There may be a variation in grade attainment depending on when the survey was conducted. In

March of each year, students get promoted to the next grade. While all children in the 2009-10

were interviewed between August of 2009 and March 2010, children in 2007 were interviewed

before and after March. This introduces the possibility that those interviewed before March were

in lower grade than those interview after March. We take this into account in our analysis.

Page 14: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

12

per cent to 61 per cent, a change larger than the corresponding change in proportion of

children whose fathers were working in NREGS (a change from 25 per cent to 49 per

cent). Further, we find that the average number of days that the mothers worked on

NREGS increased by almost five times, while the average number of days worked by

fathers rose, but not as much. Thus the share of the mother in the total work days in

NREGS rose by about 8 percentage points among children who had at least one parent

working in NREGS.

Further, the mean annual household income (in 2009 rupees) went up from Rs.

32,949 in 2007 to Rs 50,683 in 2009-10. The main source of income and the increase in

income was non agricultural activities. Although annual agricultural income almost

doubled during this period, its contribution to total income was minimal in both years.11

Table 3 also suggests that there is a rise in wealth over the period of our study. Using

asset quartiles, we find that a larger proportion of children live in households in the 3rd

and 4th quartile in 2009-10 as compared to 2007. 12

While this change is large, it is

consistent with the rise in real incomes noted above. It is also important to note that the

household size has remained more of less unchanged during this period.

While preliminary evidence presented above suggests that mother's NREGS

participation and number of days of work have gone up, it would be incorrect to draw a

causal link between that and changes in children‟s time spent in school since decisions

regarding labour supply of household members are endogenous. However, the

11

The reference period for non agriculture income is slightly different from agriculture income.

While information on non agriculture income was collected over a reference of last 12 months,

information on agriculture income was collected over the last agricultural year. Since the two

periods have substantial overlap, we add the two to calculate total income. 12

We use the pooled sample of 2007 and 2009-10 to generate the asset index. Pooling over the

years ensures that the asset quartile changes over years reflect absolute changes in wealth rather

than a change in the relative position in the wealth distribution within any year.

Page 15: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

13

introduction of the NREGS also leads to exogenous shifts in the demand for labour. One

such measure of demand is the total number of „in-progress‟ NREGS projects in a mandal

(or sub-district). This is unlikely to be determined by factors specific to the labour supply

decision of any individual household or even a village. However, progress on a larger

number of projects within a mandal indicates that there are relatively more work

opportunities for households residing in that area.13

The last row in Table 3 suggests that

the number of such NREGS projects did increase during the period of our study.

Moreover, this increase was not uniform across mandals. Hence the change in demand

for labour for NREGS projects varied both over time and across mandals in Andhra

Pradesh.

B. Methodology

In this section, we specify our empirical model and discuss the estimation strategy we

adopt to test our hypothesis.

To begin with, note that NREGS participation by household members can have

two distinct effects on children‟s time spent in school (TSS).14

First, as household

members work on NREGS, the total income of the household (INC) may rise.15

In so far

13

It is important here to point out that an individual's decision to not work on NREGS project will

neither affect the progress of the project (unless no person in the mandal wants to work) nor will

it affect the total number of projects in a mandal on which progress has been made. 14

The time spent in school is recorded as hours spent in school on a typical day in the previous

week. The total time spent on education on a typical day consists of time spent in school and time

spent on studying outside school (private tuition and at home). The average time spent on

education outside the school in the sample is less than 20 per cent of the total time spent on

education on a typical day. 15

NREGS work is only one of many activities performed by members of the household. If

NREGS work done by a member does not cause changes in the total labour supplied to other

household activities, then total income will rise by the additional income from NREGS. However,

the possibility of doing work as a part of NREGS is expected to change the allocation of labour to

various activities. If households reallocate work rationally, then total income will tend (contd...)

Page 16: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

14

as households consider the education of children to be a normal good, this income effect

may result in a rise in children‟s time spent in school.16

Second, NREGS could have an

additional direct impact on children‟s education due to greater labour force participation

of mothers, but in two opposite directions: a negative substitution effect and a positive

bargaining power effect. Thus, the net impact of a change in mother‟s participation in the

labour force on her children‟s schooling is an empirical question. We posit that,

controlling for INC and the number of days worked on NREGS by the father

(FATHER_NREGS), a positive effect of the number of NREGS days by the mother

(MOTHER_NREGS) on children‟s educational outcomes would suggest that the latter

effect dominates the negative substitution effect.17

There are several child and household level factors that could confound the effects

of NREGS participation of mothers on her children‟s time spent in school. We, therefore,

include Z - a vector of household variables that may change over time, in our empirical

specification. For instance, households often smooth any income shocks with dissaving

of assets. Hence we take into account household wealth represented by Asset Quartiles

( ). Further, since poorer households are more likely to work on NREGS, omitting

asset ownership would confound the effects of parental labour supply on TSS. We also

include land owned by the household as an indicator of wealth. Households‟ optimization

to increase. However, in this case, the total income need not rise by just the amount earned

through NREGS work. 16

Whether the income effect is significant or not is a function of the cost of schooling as well. If

physical access to schooling is relatively easy and costs of schooling are subsidized (as in primary

schooling), any effect of an increase in household income may be muted for the age group under

study here. 17

As explained earlier, the number of days of NREGS work done by mothers and fathers have

gone up over the period of the study. This is true not only for the districts where NREGS was

implemented in 2008 but also for districts where it was implemented in 2006.

DiASSETS

Page 17: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

15

process is also a function of the size of the household and migration of members can

cause substantial changes in the decisions taken by households. Hence we include the

number of household members (HH_SIZE) in Z as well. Our analysis also controls for

whether the household‟ reference week was a school holiday. However, the results hold

up when we restrict our sample to only those children for whom the previous week was

not a school holiday.

Next, we include X, which denotes the vector of child specific time variant

variables that could affect TSS. As a part of X, we include the highest grade achieved by

the child. This is to account for the fact that the time spent in school may systematically

vary with grade. We include the square of GRADE (SQ_GRADE) to allow for non

linearity in this effect.18

Moreover, the time children can spend in school may depend on

their age. Older children are more likely to spend time working outside or looking after

their siblings. We allow for this effect to be non-linear in age by including age (AGE)

and square of age (SQ_AGE) in X.

While the variables included in Z and X are observable to the econometrician,

there may be unobservables at the geographic level (district, mandal and village),

household level and there may also exist child specific unobserved heterogeneity. If these

unobservables are correlated with the regressors on the right hand-side and they also

affect time spent in school, it would lead to the issue of endogeneity and thereby

inconsistency of our estimates. Our specification, therefore, includes time invariant child

characteristics viz. ability (𝛼𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑 ), household characteristics viz. parental preferences

18

Our results are unchanged when we exclude GRADE from the vector X.

Page 18: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

16

for schooling (𝛼ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑 ) , mandal level characteristics (𝛼𝑚𝑑 ) , and village characteristics

viz. culture( 𝛼𝑣𝑚𝑑 ).

A potential problem for our empirical exercise is the phased implementation of

NREGS. Districts that had NREGS earlier (Phase 1) may be different from those that

had NREGS later (Phase 2). Moreover, these districts may have different economic

growth trajectories as well as trends in educational attainment. To take into account these

concerns, we allow for district specific intercepts 𝛼𝑑 and introduce district specific time

trends We also control for a secular time trend , that allows for increases in

demand for and supply of schooling.19

In addition to district specific trends, there could be trends that are driven by

rising awareness of rights due to social audits. For example, social audits that make

households aware of their rights may also lead to a demand for public schools. Hence

NREGS participation and children‟s time in school could be driven by this rising

awareness. To control for this, we allow the trend to depend on the number of social

audits that have taken place in the mandal prior to the date of the survey

(𝑆𝑜𝑐_𝑎𝑢𝑑𝑖𝑡𝑠𝑚𝑑𝑡 ∗ 𝑡).

More formally, we estimate the following specification:

𝑇𝑆𝑆𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡 = 𝛼0 + 𝛼𝑡 + 𝛼𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑 + 𝛼ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑 + 𝛼𝑣𝑚𝑑 + 𝛼𝑚𝑑 + 𝛼𝑑 + 𝛼𝑑𝑡 + 𝛽𝑋𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡

+ 𝛿𝑍ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡 + 𝜑1𝐼𝑁𝐶ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡 + 𝜑2𝐹𝐴𝑇𝐻𝐸𝑅_𝑁𝑅𝐸𝐺𝑆𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡

+ 𝜑3𝑀𝑂𝑇𝐻𝐸𝑅_𝑁𝑅𝐸𝐺𝑆𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡 + 𝜌𝑆𝑜𝑐_𝑎𝑢𝑑𝑖𝑡𝑠𝑚𝑑𝑡 ∗ 𝑡 + 휀𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡 (1)

where the subscript refers to a child in household in village in mandal m in district

. refers to time, which takes the value 0 for the year 2007 and 1 for the period 2009-

19

This period is also one of renewed efforts to universalize primary education, through district

level government policies (viz., Sarva Shiksha Abhiyan or SSA).

dt

t

c

h

v

d

t

Page 19: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

17

10. Thus, using the temporal variation in the number of days of NREGS work done by

the mothers and fathers between 2007 and 2009-10 our empirical model aims to identify

the effect of NREGS participation of mothers on TSS ( 𝜑3 ).

Given this specification, and using data on a balanced panel of children over the

two time periods, we estimate a child fixed effects model. In doing so, we eliminate

𝛼𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑 , 𝛼ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑 , 𝛼𝑣𝑚𝑑 and as well as . The child fixed effects model uses the

temporal variation for each child and demeans variables from the child level mean.

This eliminates all observable variables that are time invariant; therefore such child (e.g.

the gender of the child) and household level variables (e.g. education of parents that we

may have possibly considered) are eliminated. If we assume that the deviation of the

observed variables from their mean values are not correlated with the deviation of the

error term from its mean values, this estimation procedure would yield consistent

estimators of 𝜑1,𝜑2 and 𝜑3.

The main concern with our estimation strategy is that parental labour supply

decisions are likely to be made simultaneously with investments in children‟s education.

Thus, father‟s and mother‟s participation in the NREGS may remain endogenous even

though we account for unobserved, time invariant household and child level

heterogeneity. To address this simultaneity issue, we adopt a 2SLS estimation procedure

using mandal (sub-district) level rainfall shocks in the month of May and June and

variation in the demand for NREGS labour as instruments. We define a rainfall shock

(RAIN) as the deviation of rainfall recorded in May and June for the mandal in the year

prior to the survey from the long term (20 year) average rainfall, for the same months, in

vd

d

c

Page 20: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

18

that mandal.20

The demand for NREGS labour is captured by the number of projects

currently „in-progress‟ in the mandal (PROJECTS).21

In our preferred specification,

therefore, with three endogenous variables (INC, FATHER_NREGS,

MOTHER_NREGS) and three instruments (RAIN, PROJECTS, RAIN*PROJECTS), our

estimating equation is just identified. We discuss the validity of our instruments next.

C. Validity of instruments

Agricultural production in India continues to be dependent upon rainfall. The choice of

rainfall in May-June of the reference period as an instrument is, thus, driven by the nature

of agricultural activity in the region of our study. Rice is the main crop cultivated in

Andhra Pradesh. Using the YLS data we find that among rural households, the crop

which the largest proportion of households cultivate (almost 36 per cent across rounds 2

and 3) is rice.22

The cultivation of rice is highly water-intensive. The crop is mainly

cultivated in flooded, standing water fields. But prior to cultivation in the paddy fields,

the rice seedlings (which cannot survive in flooded fields) are grown in nurseries. They

are then manually transplanted into the flooded fields. It is therefore expected that rainfall

in the pre-monsoon season will promote the development of rice seedlings enabling

20

The variable capturing rainfall shocks (RAIN) is constructed from the precipitation data

available from the Center of Climatic Research at the University of Delaware. The data includes

monthly precipitation values at 0.5 degree intervals in latitude and longitude. To match this data

at the mandal level, the nearest latitude-longitude to each mandal headquarter is taken. To

construct the rainfall shock at the mandal level, the long term (1990-2008) average mandal level

rainfall in the months of May and June are estimated. Standard deviation of rainfall for the same

period is also calculated at the mandal level. Then rainfall shock is defined as the deviation of

actual rainfall in the months of May and June in the last year from the long term average, divided

by the standard deviation. 21

Data on the number of ongoing projects at the mandal level is obtained from the Andhra

Pradesh Government‟s website on NREGS (http://nrega.ap.gov.in/). 22

Groundnuts is a distant second, with about 16% of rural households engaged in its cultivation.

Page 21: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

19

farmers to increase their cultivation of rice during the monsoon season. This in turn

would create greater demand for labour for transplanting. Majority of the transplanting

work is done by women because it is delicate work and is a highly labour-intensive

activity (Mies, 1986).23

Our assumption, therefore, is that, ceteris paribus, demand for

female labour for agricultural work will be higher if premonsoon rainfall is high.

The monsoon typically arrives in Andhra Pradesh in mid June. Hence the

premonsoon rainfall falls mostly in the month of May and early June. Furthermore,

schools are closed for summer vacations from the last week of April to mid June every

year in Andhra Pradesh.24

Thus it is unlikely that rainfall in this period will have a direct

effect on time spent in school or grade attainment either due to households‟ labour

substitution decisions or supply-side factors such as teacher attendance.

Our second instrument is the number of NREGS projects currently in progress in

the mandal.25

Before we discuss the validity of this instrument it is imperative to discuss

the administration of the NREGA projects in general and in AP in particular. There are

three tiers of administration of NREGA projects in Andhra Pradesh - district, mandal and

village. While the district administration is responsible for overseeing the implementation

of the NREGA program, the Mandal Parishad Development Office (MPDO) is the main

23

Foster and Rosenzweig (1996), using data from Philippines, show that men were more likely to

undertake agricultural tasks that require greater upper body strength such as plowing whereas

women were more likely to be engaged in activities such as weeding. The division of labour, by

gender, thus depends on the comparative advantage of the sexes in various tasks. 24

See http://aputf.org/go_s/Rc.No.31,Dt.22.07.2011.pdf for an official circular of the Department

of Education on the schedule of public schools in AP. 25

This instrument represents a cumulation of all projects which are in progress in a financial year.

Projects are not necessarily completed within the same financial year that they begin in. So this is

a stock variable that reflects previous as well as current NREGS projects. Ideally, we would have

liked to use lagged values of this variable. Unfortunately, since the reference period for the 2nd

round of the YLS is 2006 and the NREGA was initiated in February, 2006, lagged data do not

exist for both rounds of the YLS survey.

Page 22: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

20

agency for administering each NREGA project and sanctioning all financial payments for

projects undertaken in that mandal. The village council‟s role is limited to recommending

the list, and priority, of NREGA projects to be implemented to the MPDO. Since the

NREGA is envisaged as a demand-driven program, households are expected to apply for

work and once a critical mass of demand is generated in a gram panchayat (a collection

of 1 to 3 villages) in a mandal, a project has to be selected from the approved list of

works and sanctioned by the district administration. Thus the main concern with the IV‟s

validity is that current, individual demand may determine the number of projects in

progress, partly or fully, at the mandal level.

Note that our instrument is defined at the level of the mandal - a collection of 11

to 39 gram panchayats (in the YLS sample) - and the sanctioning of projects is at the

district and mandal level. Furthermore, although the NREGA envisages a demand driven

programme, the reality is quite different according to several recent studies. Imbert and

Papp (2012) report that “many people are unaware of their full set of rights under the

programme”; “in practice, very few job card holders formally apply for work while the

majority tend to wait passively for work to be provided.” Other research on NREGS

districts in Andhra Pradesh (Ravi and Engler, 2009; Afridi et al., 2012) also indicates that

the programme is supply rather than demand driven.26

Hence, given the fact that the

program is driven by the supply of projects at the district and mandal level and that our

intrument is defined at the level of the mandal, it is unlikely that there are significant

effects of current household demand on program intensity at the mandal level.

26

In survey of 1500 households across 8 districts in AP, Afridi et al. (2012) find that less than 14

per cent of households has applied for NREGA employment in 2010-11, 4 years after the

inception of the program.

Page 23: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

21

The concern that remains then is whether temporal changes in awareness of

NREGA entitlements (including demanding work; Khera, 2011) are accompanied with

changes in the demand for public schooling (quality or quantity).27

On the other hand, say

there is no increase in awareness but the administration is learning how to implement

NREGS, which improves between 2006-2009 and this learning spills over to the

provision of the public good of interest to us – education. In either case, our IV will not

meet the exclusion restriction as it would have a direct effect on educational outcomes.

We address the latter concern first. In Andhra Pradesh, school participation is near

universal.28

According to the Annual Survey of Education Report (ASER, 2006), the

percentage of out of school rural children in the 6-14 age group was between 0 to 5 per

cent in all the YLS districts except West Godavari where it was between 5 to 10 per cent

in 2006. Learning levels were higher than the average for the country and have remained

more or less steady during this period (ASER, 2006 and 2009). Thus any administrative

“learning” with respective to public schooling would be minimal, if at all. Enrolments in

private rural schools actually declined for 6-14 year olds by about 5 percentage points

between 2006 and 2009 (ASER, 2006 and 2009). This suggests that any improvements in

educational attainment that we find is unlikely to be driven by improvements in either

public schools or an increase in private school presence. Second, while it is quite likely

that administrative capacity and NREGA implementation improves over time, it is

unlikely that this would be accompanied by administrative improvements in public

schooling. The administrative machinery that has been created for the NREGA

27

The NREG Act allows for the conduct of regular “social” audits of project expenditures by

stakeholders. In AP the state government has institutionalised social audits since 2006. 28

Enrolment of children in 6-10 years age group was 92.91per cent in round 2 and 92.58 per cent

in round 3 (92.70 overall); enrolment in 11-14 age group was 80.59 per cent in round 2 and 86.48

per cent in round 3 (83.35 overall) in our sample.

Page 24: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

22

implementation at the grassroot level and which helps expand capacity for the program is

different and delinked from that required for public schooling (see Figure A3 in the

appendix for more details). Third, there has been no change in local governments since

2006 in AP. State legislative elections returned the same political party back to power

(Congress) in May, 2009, after our survey reference period. Hence, there are unlikely to

have been any significant changes in political will for implementation of public

programmes either.

To address the former concern, we first use data from the YLS to check whether

political participation or participation in community led demand for certain public goods

was correlated with the occurrence of social audits. The timing, frequency and conduct of

social audits in a mandal is determined centrally by an independent body – the Society

for Social Audit, Accountability and Transparency (SSAAT) – in Andhra Pradesh.

Hence, the number of audits conducted in a mandal should be exogenous to the village

and household. We find an insignificant effect of the occurrence of social audits on

awareness between the second and third round of the YLS surveys in a household fixed

effects model (see Table A2 in the appendix). Nevertheless, as discussed in the empirical

model above, we include a variable “number of social audits that took place in the

mandal between the two survey rounds” in all our baseline regression analyses to control

for any direct effect of „awareness‟ improvements on children‟s schooling. Our results

are robust to the inclusion of this variable.

Page 25: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

23

4. Results

A. Overall impact on children’s time in school

Our hypothesis is that once we control for households assets, total income and other

child, household village, mandal and district level characteristics, the coefficients of

MOTHER_NREGS would be positive. Results in Table 4 show that this is indeed the

case for time spent in school. Column 1 reports the results of an OLS-FE regression of

child‟s time spent in school on parental participation in NREGS, accounting for

unobservable heterogeneity in child characteristics and differences in trends across

districts. We find that the coefficient of MOTHER_NREGS and FATHER_NREGS are

positive but insignificant. However, as pointed out above, this specification does not

account for the possible endogeneity of labour force participation of parents and

household income. We, therefore, look at the 2SLS results in column 2.29

Instrumenting for the three endogenous variables in column 2, we find that the

coefficient on MOTHER_NREGS is positive and significant at 1 per cent. This result

validates our hypothesis given that the change in days of NREGS work by mothers

29

The first stage results (Table A1 in the appendix) suggest that our instruments are good

predictors of the endogenous variables. First stage regression equations have F statistics ranging

from 42.55 to 71.47. Moreover, at least one instrument is significant in each regression equation

making their use valid. The first stage results suggest that an increase in the number of on-going

NREGS projects in a mandal increases the household income and parents‟ participation in such

projects, as hypothesized. The coefficient on RAIN turns out to be insignificant for female

NREGS participation while significant for male participation, where as the coefficient for

RAIN*PROJECTS is positive and signficant and more or less similar for both female and male

participation in NREGS. These results point out that the response of females to NREGS is lesser

than that of males when the rainfall in May and June is good. This is consistent with the fact that,

in the years of good pre-monsoon rains, females are more likely to work in rice fields than men.

The coefficient of RAIN is negative though insignificant for annual household income. This

insignificance could be because agriculture income is a very small part of total annual household

income. Moreover, here we use rainfall in only May and June as an instrument. However, a good

rain shock for the summer crop may well be followed by a bad rain shock during the winter crop,

resulting in an insignificant (or even negative) effect of May-June rainfall on total annual

agricultural income.

Page 26: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

24

between the two survey rounds represents a substantial increase in the proportion of

household earnings attributable to mothers. To elaborate, between 2007 and 2009-10, the

average number of days worked by the mother on the NREGS projects went up by more

than 16 days. This indicates a doubling of contribution to household income, to 6.8 per

cent in 2009-10, if (as we explained in section 2) there is no crowding out from private

labour. The estimated coefficient of 0.224, therefore, implies a 3.6 hours per day (0.224 x

16.16) increase in the time spent in school of the child over this period. For a typical

school day lasting 8 hours, this effect is equivalent to attending school almost half a day

more. If we extrapolate this impact over an entire academic year, we can view this effect

as an almost 50 per cent increase in school attendance rate. 30

Note that since mother‟s NREGS participation is likely to have two opposing

effects on children‟s educational outcomes, as discussed in the previous section, a

positive coefficient on MOTHER_NREGS indicates that the bargaining effect dominates

any labour substitution effect. Thus, in so far as our estimated coefficient is a

consequence of higher bargaining power of mothers, it may be a lower bound on the

impact of the bargaining effects of NREGS on child outcomes.

In contrast, the effect of FATHER_NREGS is negative and significant at 1

percent significance level in column 2. Disaggregation of this effect, discussed in the

next section, shows that this effect is greater for poorer households and for older boys,

30

We recognize that any additional time spent in school could be substituted by less time spent

studying outside school leading to an insignificant effect of mother‟s NREGS work days on total

time spent on education on a typical day. In an alternate specification, therefore, we consider the

total time spent on education (including time spent studying outside the school) as the dependent

variable. Our results are unchanged.

Page 27: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

25

potentially indicating substitution of fathers‟ time on non-NREGS work with that of

children‟s time.31

In so far as NREGS income is a part of total income, any NREGS work by

parents may lead to a rise in the time spent in schooling. In column 1 we find that the

coefficient on total household income is insignificant. However the point estimate is

positive and the p value is 0.17. Once we account for the endogeneity of household

income in column 2, we get a similar positive but much larger point estimate for income.

However, the p value is still around 0.17. This suggests that, even if there are income

effects, there may be too much heterogeneity in this effect, so as to render the coefficient

insignificant. The insignificant coefficients for asset quartiles echo the same argument. In

rural areas, land is usually a good predictor of wealth. We find that, in the OLS-FE

specification, the effect of land is positive and significant. However, this result turns

insignificant when we look at the 2SLS-FE results in column 2. In a later part of the

paper we will examine this issue more by stratifying households by their base wealth

levels.

As pointed out, children‟s time spent in school and parental NREGS participation

may covary because of increasing awareness, through social audits. While the OLS-FE

results estimate this effect to be negative, the 2SLS-FE results find this effect to be

positive but insignificant. Recall that the variable, “number of NREGS social audits in

the mandal between the two survey rounds x time” allows for different trends in time

31

The negative coefficient on father‟s NREGS work is also consistent with our result on mother‟s

NREGS work. For a given level of income and mother‟s NREGS participation, a rise in father‟s

NREGS participation might imply that a larger share of household income is earned by the father.

If this larger share of income bestows greater bargaining power to fathers relative to mothers, and

fathers prefer to invest resources in goods other than children‟s education, then the time spent in

school by children could fall.

Page 28: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

26

spent in school depending on the number of audits that have taken place in the mandal

before the survey. Our results point out, that if anything, the change in time spent in

schooling is lesser in mandals with more social audits.

The coefficient on household size is negative but insignificant in both columns.

The coefficient on time is positive and significant in column 1 but is insignificant in

column 2. In both cases, the point estimates are large representing the effect of increasing

age of the child over time. While the child‟s age drops out as it is collinear with time, we

find that there is a non-linear effect of age. The square of age turns out to be negative in

columns 1 and 2. The greater the age, the lower the increase in time spent in school. This

reflects the higher opportunity cost of time in school for older children. The coefficient of

the term linear in GRADE is negative and significant while that on the quadratic term is

positive. The argument for GRADE is similar to that of age (and may indeed be picking

up some of the effect). As children progress to higher grades, they are more likely to drop

out of school, leading to a fall in time spent in school in the current year. However, for

those who continue to attend school, as they move into higher grades, the time spent in

school goes up.

B. Heterogeneity of impact on children’s time in school

The reported average effect of NREGS participation by mothers may hide large

heterogeneity of impact across households belonging to different wealth strata. To

address some of these issues related to heterogeneity of effects we run our regressions by

two indicators of household wealth - asset quartiles and land ownership. We construct

four sub-samples of children who belong to households in each of the four asset quartiles

Page 29: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

27

in 2007 (recall that the quartiles are still based on the pooled sample of 2007 and 2009-

10). Doing so not only allows us to look at heterogeneous impacts across wealth levels

but also addresses the issue of transition in wealth quartiles. In addition, we classify

households into those whose land ownership was less than the median land ownership

and more than the median land ownership (based on 2007 distribution of land in the

sample).

The results in Table 5 suggest that the effect of MOTHER_NREGS is significant

for the households which were in the first two quartiles in 2007. The marginal coefficient

on MOTHER_NREGS is 0.105 for the first quartile (column 1) and 0.212 for the second

quartile (column 2). There is no significant impact of MOTHER_NREGS in households

belonging to higher wealth quartiles.

Given that the number of days of NREGS work done by mothers in households

belonging to the first quartile increased from 5.67 days in 2007 to 26.23 days in 2009-10,

the implied increase in time spent in school is 2.16 hours. The effect of NREGS work

done by mothers on time spent in school for the second quartile of wealth is larger at 3.29

even though the increase in days of NREGS work done by mothers rose less, from 5.73

days to 21.26 days. Since the coefficient is insignificant for higher asset quartiles, this

indicates that the overall result, that we observed in the last section, is driven by the sub-

sample of children who belonged to households in the first two wealth quartiles in 2007.

For these children, mother‟s work in NREGS contributed even more to the total income

of the household than in the entire sample. While the NREGS income earned by the

mother as a proportion of total household income was 3.1 per cent in 2007, it was 9.1 per

Page 30: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

28

cent in 2009-10 for households in the first wealth quartile. For the second quartile, this

proportion increased from 3.2 percent in 2007 to 6.2 percent in 2009-10.

The effect of the days worked by the father on NREGS projects on children‟s time

in school is negative (-0.089) and significant only for asset 1. It is insignificant for all

wealth quartiles. This implies that the total effect of working on NREGS is maximum for

households in asset quartile 2 in 2007. In general, households in asset quartile 2 have

shown a large secular rise in time spent in schooling. This is indicated by the large

significant coefficient on the trend (6.405).

A similar story is indicated by results in columns 5 and 6 where households are

classified on the basis of land owned in 2007. The results for days worked on NREGS

projects by the mother and father are significant only for households who owned less than

the median land (1.04 acres) in 2007. The two sets of results therefore indicate that the

days worked on NREGS by the mother, ceteris paribus, has only had an impact for the

poorer households.

Next, we look at whether the effect of mother's days of NREGS work differs by

the characteristics of the child in Table 6. In columns 1 and 2 we disaggregate the overall

analysis by the gender of the child. The coefficient on mothers‟ days of NREGS work

suggests a positive impact on only female children. While the p value in the case of male

children is 0.115 suggesting that there may also be some impact on boys, the coefficient

for the female child at 0.271 is much larger than that for male children (0.177). This

implies that the rise in time spent in school for female children is 4.5 hours (the average

number of days of NREGS work for mothers in the subsample with only female children

is 4.67 days and 21.3 days in 2007 and 2009-10 respectively).

Page 31: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

29

The days of NREGS work by the father has no impact on the female children.

However it is negative (-0.139) and significant for the male children.32

We also find that

in the case of male children, there is a positive secular trend (3.412) indicating a general

rise in schooling for male children over time.

Columns 3 and 4 further disaggregate the effect of NREGS work by parents by

the age of the child. We divide the sample of children into two groups: those who were in

the age group 5-9 years in 2007 and those who were 10-14 years old. Results show that

the effects indeed vary across the two age groups. The days worked by the mother in

NREGS is positive and significant (0.225) for the younger age cohort. The rise in days of

work by the mother (4.4 in 2007 to 20.4 in 2009-10 for this sub-sample) lead to a 3.6

hour increase in time spent in school for this younger cohort. The number of days father

worked on NREGS is negative and significant for both the age groups but it is larger for

the 10-14 age group (-0.276 for 10-14 year age groups relative to -0.168 for the 5-9 year

age group).

Therefore, the overall impact of parental work on NREGS is greater for the

younger age group than for the older age group. There could be two reasons for this.

First, since the opportunity cost of being in school goes up for higher age groups,

mother‟s NREGS income or greater bargaining power may not be able to fully

compensate for these higher costs. Second, as discussed earlier, the substitution effect of

32

Our results are in keeping with the findings of existing research on the impact of parental

resources on children‟s outcomes. Previous literature suggests that the impact of mother‟s

influence on household decision-making may differ by the gender of the child (Thomas 1990;

Murthi et al. 1995) but the literature is not conclusive on whether it exacerbates or reduces gender

differences. For instance, Thomas (1990) finds that in Brazil women‟s education has a

significantly stronger effect on girls‟ health while educated fathers prefer to invest more in boys.

In Java (Thomas et al. 2002) and Cote d‟Ivoire (Haddad and Hoddinott 1994), on the other hand,

women with greater earned income allocate more resources to sons‟ health.

Page 32: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

30

mother‟s NREGS work may kick in more strongly for older children whose time on

household chores is likely to be a closer substitute for mother‟s time. This is also

apparent from the insignificant effect of mother‟s NREGS work on older girls.

C. Impact on children’s grade progression

In the previous sections, we have shown that mothers‟ work on NREGS projects

positively affects children‟s time spent in school. In this section, we delve into whether

an increase in attendance rates in school has translated into higher grade attainment. But

there are certain caveats to interpreting the effect of NREGS work days on children‟s

grade progression. First, the highest grade completed is right censored for the sub-sample

of children who are still enrolled in school. This is not the case, however, for children

who have completed schooling (17 year olds in 2009-10) or have dropped out by the time

of the survey interview. Second, the effect of parental labour market activities may not be

reflected completely in grade attainment for those households which are interviewed

before April (March is the last month of an academic year) since the highest grade

attainted by children in these households would be right censored. Finally, the highest

grade completed is a stock variable that may be determined not just by current NREGS

participation of parents but also program participation between 2007 and 2009-10. Our

assumption of a monotonically increasing relationship between program participation in

2007 and 2009-10 may not be valid.

To find the determinants of GRADE, we consider a slight modification of the

empirical model presented above. We estimate the following specification:

Page 33: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

31

𝐺𝑅𝐴𝐷𝐸𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡 = 𝛼′0 + 𝛼′

𝑡 + 𝛼′𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑 + 𝛼′

ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑 + 𝛼′𝑚𝑑 + 𝛼′

𝑣𝑚𝑑+ 𝛼′

𝑑+ 𝛼′

𝑑𝑡

+ 𝛽′ 𝑋′𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡 + 𝛿 ′𝑍ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡 + 𝜑′

1𝐼𝑁𝐶ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡

+ 𝜑′2𝐹𝐴𝑇𝐻𝐸𝑅_𝑁𝑅𝐸𝐺𝑆𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡 + 𝜑′

3𝑀𝑂𝑇𝐻𝐸𝑅_𝑁𝑅𝐸𝐺𝑆𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡

+ 𝜌′𝑆𝑂𝐶𝐼𝐴𝐿_𝐴𝑈𝐷𝐼𝑇𝑆𝑚𝑑 ∗ 𝑡 + 휀′𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡 2

The dependent variable is grade attainment of a child (subscripts follow the same

convention as in equation 1). The only difference in regressors between this specification

and specification 1 is that GRADE is now the dependent variable. Hence we refer here to

the modified vector of child level characteristics, which does not include GRADE in

𝑋′𝑐ℎ𝑣𝑚𝑑𝑡 .

We report results of OLS-FE and 2SLS–FE in Table 7.33

For the overall sample,

we find that while MOTHER_NREGS is positive and significant in OLS-FE

specification in column 1, it becomes insignificant for 2SLS-FE in column 2. Similarly,

FATHER_NREGS is negative and significant when we run OLS-FE but is insignificant

in the case of 2SLS-FE. Therefore, for the overall sample, we find no effect of NREGS

work (by either parent) on grade progression. However, when we stratify the sample by

households‟ land holdings in 2007, we find that MOTHER_NREGS is positive and

significant for households with less than median land holdings (columns 3 and 4). The

coefficient of 0.031 implies that the increase in the days worked by the mother on

NREGS projects, among this sub-sample (3.87 days in 2007 to 22.2 days in 2009-10), has

lead to an increase in grade attainment by 0.568, which is more than half an academic

year. The days worked by the father has no significant effect on grade attainment. For

households with more than median land holdings, there is no effect of either parent‟s

33

The number of missing values is less when we consider grade attainment. Thus we run the

regressions with 2961 children. We use the same three instruments as in our main specification

for TSS.

Page 34: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

32

working on NREGS. This result substantiates what we have also observed for time spent

in school - that the effect of days of NREGS work by mother is more visible in the lower

economic strata.34

To sum, our results for grade attainment are muted but consistent with what we

observed for time spent in school. It suggests that the days of work by the mother on

NREGS, ceteris paribus, has lead to better educational outcomes for her children.

D. Impact of mother’s work status on empowerment

Our results suggest that an increase in labour force participation of mothers has beneficial

effects on her children but not so of fathers‟. The time allocation hypothesis indicates that

there should be a negative or zero effect of mother‟s labour force participation on

children‟s educational outcomes, particularly girls. While we do find that there is an

insignificant effect of mother‟s program participation on older children and boys, 5 to 9

year olds and girls tend to benefit. While the former can be explained in terms of non-

substitutability of younger children‟s time with mother‟s time on household chores, the

latter effect suggests that women‟s preference could be coming into play.

In order to further test our hypothesis of improvements in women‟s decision-

making abilities within households as a result of increased participation in the labour

market, we use data from the second round of the Young Lives survey. The second round

34

When we classify the sample by children‟s age group, we find that the coefficient on

MOTHER_NREGS is significant and positive for the age group 5-9 years, whereas there is no

significant impact for the older age group of 10-14 years. We do not find any significant impact

of parental participation in NREGS when we classify the sample by any other individual or

household characteristic (viz. gender or household assets).

Page 35: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

33

of the YLS data contains detailed information on various decision-makers within a

household.35

Our dependent variable is the binary response to the following questions:

a.“Is the caregiver responsible for making the key decisions about any of the plots?”

(Land)

b. “Does the caregiver control the use of the earnings from the sale of goods or rent from

any of these plots?” (Earnings from land)

c. “Is the caregiver responsible for making the key decisions about any of these work for

wages activities?” (Wage activities)

d. “Is the caregiver responsible for controlling the earnings from any of these from work

for wages activities?” (Earnings from wage activities)

The sample is restricted to caregivers who are mothers in age group 16-60 years.36

Our main variable of interest is whether the woman works. We expect the woman‟s work

status to be affected by the number of „in-progress‟ NREGS projects in the mandal and

the long-term deviation of rainfall in May-June of the reference period. We, therefore,

instrument work status by these two variables and their interaction. Controls for

individual and household characteristics such as –age, education, household‟s asset

quartiles and household size – are included within a district fixed effects specification.

The results are reported in Table 8.

The positive and significant coefficient on „working‟ across all outcomes suggests

that greater participation of mothers in the labour market does increase the say and

control these women have on important decisions being made within the household. In a

rural setting earnings from land and from wages are likely to be the two most important

35

These data were not collected for households in round 3of the YLS. 36

The labour force participation rate among fathers in our sample is 98.4 per cent, almost

universal.

Page 36: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

34

sources of income for households.37

This result, therefore, bolsters our claim that an

increase in work opportunities for women is likely to have a positive effect on their

decision-making abilities within the household. The positive impact of mother‟s NREGS

work on girls‟ time in school and our analysis here indicates that our findings cannot be

explained purely within a unitary framework of the household.38

5. Conclusion

The role of increasing women‟s bargaining power within households as a means of

reducing poverty has been emphasized in discussions on development policy. In this

paper, we look at one such policy initiative in India - the National Rural Employment

Guarantee Scheme. While the scheme has been conceived primarily to provide

households a guaranteed income through employment on public projects, it is sensitive to

issues of gender discrimination in the labour marker. Given that private casual wages for

women are often less than those of men, the scheme stipulates equal wage rates across

gender. It also gives priority to female employment and targets at least one third of the

beneficiaries to be women. Thus the scheme aims to increase and improve rural women‟s

labour market opportunities.

In this paper we contend that, ceteris paribus, an increase in participation of a

mother on NREGS projects could affect her household‟s outcomes such that they reflect

her preferences better. Using panel data collected by the Young Lives Study in a large

37

We find no impact of work status of mothers on their participation in decisions related to

earnings from livestock and self-employment activities of the household. 38

In order to test for the possibility that schools substitute for day care for working mothers, we

control for the demographic composition of the household. Under this hypothesis, the effect of

mothers working on children‟s time in school should be insignificant if there are older siblings in

the household to take care of the younger ones. But our results are unchanged when we control

for demographic composition of the household. See Table A3 in the appendix for details.

Page 37: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

35

southern state of India (Andhra Pradesh) and taking advantage of intra district variation

in rainfall shock and the number of NREGS projects „in-progress‟, we find that greater

participation of women in NREGS works has a positive effect on her children‟s time in

school. Moreover we find that this effect is largely on children in the poorest wealth

group, for girls and younger children in the household.

Our findings of the positive effect of mothers‟ program participation on children‟s

time spent in school carries implications for their educational attainment as well. Our

results suggest that grade attainment of younger children and those in less landed

households improves due to mothers‟ NREGS participation, implying that more time in

school translates into better educational attainment for some groups of children.

We find evidence that suggests that the positive impact of mothers‟ increased

program participation could be due to her improved position in household decision-

making. Our assertion is supported by recent qualitative evidence on the empowering

effects of NREGS on rural women (Pankaj and Tankha, 2010; Khera and Nayak, 2009)

accompanied by more rigorous findings of increased labour force participation of rural

women due to this public program (Azam, 2012). Thus, our study not only informs us

about the impact of female labour supply on intra-household outcomes but also extends

the current debate in India on the effects of one of its most ambitious poverty alleviation

program.

References

Afridi, Farzana, Vegard Iversen and M. R. Sharan (2012), “Does female leadership

impact on governance and corruption? Evidence from a public poverty alleviation

program in Andhra Pradesh, India,” working paper, International Growth Centre

(IGC).

Page 38: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

36

Anderson, Siwan and Mukesh Eswaran (2009), “What determines female autonomy?

Evidence from Bangladesh,” Journal of Development Economics, 90: 179–191.

ASER (2006 and 2009), Annual status of education report, Pratham Resource Centre,

New Delhi.

Azam, Mehtabul (2012), “The impact of Indian job guarantee scheme on labor market

outcomes: Evidence from a natural experiment,” IZA Discussion Paper No. 6548,

Institute for the Study of Labour, Bonn.

Blumberg, R. L. (1988), “Income under female versus male control: hypotheses from a

theory of gender stratification and data from the third world,” Journal of Family

Issues, 9(1): 51–84.

Chiappori, P. (1988), “Nash-bargained household decisions: A Comment,” International

Economic Review, 29(4): 791–796.

Foster, Andrew and Mark Rosenzweig (1996), “Comparative advantage, information and

the allocation of workers to tasks: Evidence from an agricultural labour market,”

The Review of Economic Studies, 63(3): 347–374.

Grootaert, Christian, and Harry Patrinos (1999), The policy analysis of child labor: a

comparative study, St. Martin‟s Press, New York.

Haddad, Lawrence and Hoddinott, John (1994), “Women's income and boy-girl

anthropometric status in the Cote d'Ivoire,” World Development, 22(4): 543–553.

Hoddinot, John and Lawrence Haddad (1995), “Does female income share influence

household expenditure? Evidence from Cote D‟Ivoire,” Oxford Bulletin of

Economics and Statistics, 57(1): 77–96.

Ilahi, Nadeem (1999), “Children‟s work and schooling under shocks: Does gender

matter? Evidence from the Peru LSMS panel data,” Background paper for

Engendering Development, Technical Report, World Bank, Washington DC.

Imbert, Clement and John Papp (2011), “Impact of a public employment program on

private sector wages: Evidence from India,” Working paper, Princeton University.

Khera, Reetika (2011), The battle for employment guarantee, Oxford University Press,

New Delhi.

Khera, Reetika and Nandini Nayak (2009), “Women workers and perceptions of the

National Rural Employment Guarantee Act,” Economic and Political Weekly,

44(43): 49–57.

Luke, Nancy and Kaivan Munshi (2011), “Women as agents of change: Female income

and mobility in India,” Journal of Development Economics, 94(1): 1–17.

McElroy, M. and M. J. Horney (1981), “Nash-bargained household decisions: Toward a

generalization of the theory of demand,” International Economic Review, 22(2):

333–349.

Page 39: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

37

Mies, Maria (1986), Indian women in subsistence and agricultural labour, Geneva:

International Labour Office.

Murthi, Mamta, Anne-Catherine Guio and Jean Drèze (1995), “Mortality, fertility, and

gender bias in India: A district level analysis,” Population and Development

Review, 21(4): 745–782.

Pankaj, Ashok and Rukmini Tankha (2010), “Empowerment effects of the NREGS on

women workers: A study in four states,” Economic and Political Weekly, 45(30):

45–55.

Qian, Nancy (2008), “Missing women and the price of tea in China: The effect of sex-

specific earnings on sex imbalance,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(3):

1251–1285.

Quisumbing, Agnes and John Maluccio (2003), “Resources at marriage and intra-

household allocation: evidence from Bangladesh, Ethiopia, Indonesia, and South

Africa,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 65(3): 283–327.

Ravi, Shamika and Monika Engler (2009), “Workfare as an effective way to fight

poverty: The case of India's NREGS,” Available at SSRN:

http://ssrn.com/abstract=1336837.

Rosenzweig Mark and T.P. Schultz (1982), “Market opportunities, genetic endowments,

and intrafamily resource distribution: Child survival in rural India,” American

Economic Review, 72(4): 803–815.

Skoufias, E. (1993), “Labor market opportunities and intrafamily time allocation in rural

households in South Asia,” Journal of Development Economics, 40(2): 277–310.

Thomas, Duncan (1990), “Intra-household resource allocation – an inferential approach,”

Journal of Human Resources, 25(4): 635–664.

Thomas, Duncan (1994), “Like father, like son; like mother, like daughter: Parental

resources and child height,” Journal of Human Resources, 29(4): 950–988.

Thomas, Duncan, Dante Contreras and Elizabeth Frankenberg (2002), “Distribution of

power within the household and child health,” Working Paper, University of

California, Los Angeles.

Uppal, Vinayak (2009), “Is the NREGS a safety net for children? Studying the access to

the National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme for Young Lives families, and

its impact on child outcomes in Andhra Pradesh,” Young Lives Student Paper,

University of Oxford.

World Bank (2012), World Development Report, World Bank, Washington DC.

Page 40: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

38

Notes: Individuals belonging to the working age of 16-60 years are included. Sample size

is 5832 in 2007 and 6021 in 2009-10.

Source: Young Lives data.

Notes: Same as in Figure 1.

Source: Young Lives data.

Figure 2: Labour Force Participation by Work Type and Gender

34 33 28 45

31 39

58 55

32

28 44

41

0

20

40

60

80

100

2007 2009-10 2007 2009-10 2007 2009-10

Male Female All

%

Casual Wage Other

Figure 1: Labour Force Participation by Gender

92

59

75

89

72 80

0

20

40

60

80

100

Male Female All

%

2007 2009-10

Page 41: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

39

Notes: The figures are at the household level. The sample consists of 2122 households in 2007

and 2114 households in 2009-10. NREGS was implemented in the Phase 1 districts in 2006 and

in the rest of the districts in 2007 and 2008.

Source: Young Lives data.

Figure 3: Number of Days Worked in NREGS (Household Level)

0

0

0

8

8

16

5

5

11

17

23

41

16

23

39

17

23

40

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45

Male

Female

All

Male

Female

All

Male

Female

All Overall

Number of days

2007 2009-10

Ph

ase

2 &

3

dis

tric

ts

Ph

ase

1

dis

tric

ts

Page 42: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

40

Notes: The wage rates are calculated for the working population in the age group of 16-60 years.

The wage rates are deflated using CPI-AL and are expressed in 2009-10 rupees.

Source: National Sample Survey data from 55th round (1999-00), 61

st round (2004-05) and 66

th round (2009-10).

Notes: The labour force participation figures are calculated considering both the usual principal and subsidiary

activity status of the individuals. Working population belonging to the age group of 16-60 years is considered.

Source: National Sample Survey data from 55th round (1999-00), 61

st round (2004-05) and 66

th round (2009-10).

Figure 5: Participation in Public Casual Labour in

Andhra Pradesh

0.03 0.00

6.41

6.49

0.06 0.00 0.00

1.00

2.00

3.00

4.00

5.00

6.00

7.00

1999-00 2004-05 2009-10

%

Male Female

Figure 4: Wage Rate for Public Casual Labour in Andhra Pradesh

95

60

86

48 57

86

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1999-00 2004-05 2009-10

Male Female

Page 43: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

41

Table 1: Labour force participation by work type, gender and asset quartile (%)

2007

(Sample size = 5832)

2009-10

(Sample size = 6021)

Change between

rounds

Asset

Quartiles Gender Casual Other All Casual Other All Casual Other All

Asset

Quartile 1

Male 48 44 92 44 46 90 -4 2 -2

Female 41 28 69 59 24 82 17 -4 13

All 45 36 80 51 34 86 7 -1 6

Asset

Quartile 2

Male 39 53 92 36 53 89 -3 0 -3

Female 29 31 60 50 27 77 20 -4 17

All 34 42 76 43 40 83 9 -2 7

Asset

Quartile 3

Male 27 65 92 29 59 88 2 -7 -5

Female 18 32 50 36 30 66 18 -2 16

All 22 48 71 32 44 77 10 -4 6

Asset

Quartile 4

Male 8 82 91 9 78 87 1 -5 -4

Female 8 40 48 14 33 47 6 -7 -1

All 8 61 69 11 55 66 3 -6 -3

Notes: (a) Individuals in the age group of 16-60 years are considered. (b) Asset Quartiles are generated from an

Asset Index which is constructed by Principal Component Analysis of several binary asset ownership variables

at the household level. The assets which are considered are: television, radio, car, motorbike, bicycle,

telephone, mobile phone, refrigerator, fan, electric oven, table and chair, sofa and bedstead.

Source: Young Lives data.

Table 2: Number of days worked in NREGS by asset quartile (household level)

2007

(N = 2122)

2009-10

(N = 2114)

Change between

rounds

Asset Quartiles Male Female All Male Female All Male Female All

Asset Quartile 1 7 6 13 19 28 48 12 22 34

Asset Quartile 2 6 6 12 17 24 41 11 18 30

Asset Quartile 3 5 5 9 16 20 37 12 15 27

Asset Quartile 4 3 2 5 8 10 18 5 7 13

Note: The figures are at the household level. See Table 1 for description on the Asset Quartiles.

Source: Young Lives data.

Page 44: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

42

Table 3: Summary statistics

2007 2009-10

Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev. Obs Mean Std. Dev.

Child characteristics

Sex (Male=1, Female=2) 2893 1.52 0.50 2893 1.52 0.50

Age (yrs.) 2893 8.28 2.99 2893 11.28 2.99

Enrolment 2893 0.80 0.40 2893 0.90 0.29

Time spent in school (hours) 2893 5.87 2.11 2893 7.06 2.46

Highest grade completed 2961 2.63 2.60 2961 4.75 3.05

Parents participated in NREGS 2893 0.33 0.47 2893 0.66 0.47

Total number of days parents worked in

NREGS 2893 9.29 21.44 2893 36.00 47.59

Mother's characteristics

Mother's age (yrs.) 2893 30.35 5.48 2893 33.31 5.45

Whether mother is working 2890 0.61 0.49 2886 0.84 0.37

Whether mother has worked in NREGS 2893 0.28 0.45 2893 0.61 0.49

Number of days mother worked in

NREGS 2893 4.64 11.18 2893 20.80 28.36

Mother's share in total days parents

worked in NREGS 2893 0.18 0.32 2893 0.41 0.37

Mother's share in total days parents

worked in NREGS conditional on parents

participated in NREGS

966 0.54 0.33 1902 0.62 0.28

Father's characteristics

Father's age (yrs.) 2893 36.29 6.35 2893 39.22 6.26

Whether father is working 2886 0.99 0.11 2886 0.98 0.15

Whether father has worked in NREGS 2893 0.25 0.43 2893 0.49 0.50

Number of days father worked in NREGS 2893 4.65 11.86 2893 15.20 24.66

Father's share in total days parents

worked in NREGS 2893 0.15 0.29 2893 0.25 0.29

Father's share in total days parents

worked in NREGS conditional on parents

participated in NREGS

966 0.46 0.33 1902 0.38 0.28

Household characteristics

Annual non-agricultural income (Rs.) 2893 28650 30269 2893 42108 47551

Annual agricultural income (Rs.) 2893 4299 22572 2893 8575 40526

Asset quartile 1 2893 0.39 0.49 2893 0.15 0.36

Asset quartile 2 2893 0.25 0.43 2893 0.19 0.39

Asset quartile 3 2893 0.23 0.42 2893 0.27 0.44

Asset quartile 4 2893 0.13 0.33 2893 0.39 0.49

Household size 2893 5.76 2.13 2893 5.74 2.20

Land owned (acre) 2893 2.15 3.30 2893 3.55 41.05

Page 45: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

43

Total number of days household worked

in NREGS 2893 11.23 26.78 2893 42.81 55.92

Total number of social audits between the

two rounds 2893 1.14 0.58 2893 1.14 0.58

Whether date of interview was during

school summer vacation period 2893 0.08 0.27 2893 0.00 0.00

Whether date of interview was after

March 2893 0.35 0.48 2893 0.00 0.00

Community (Mandal) characteristics

Rainfall shock in May-June 2893 0.50 0.48 2893 -0.61 0.50

Number of 'in-progress' NREGS projects 2893 2.11 4.63 2893 6.70 10.92

Source: Young Lives Study

Page 46: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

44

Table 4: Effect of number of days mother worked in NREGS on child’s time spent in school

OLS-FE 2SLS-FE

(1) (2)

Annual household income in thousands (INC) 0.001 0.077

(0.172) (0.175)

Number of days mother worked in NREGS (MOTHER_NREGS) 0.001 0.224***

(0.445) (0.005)

Number of days father worked in NREGS (FATHER_NREGS) 0.001 -0.264***

(0.578) (0.003)

Square of age (SQ_AGE) -0.064*** -0.052***

(0.000) (0.000)

Highest grade completed (GRADE) -0.164** -0.471**

(0.012) (0.023)

Square of highest grade completed (SQ_GRADE) 0.039*** 0.043**

(0.000) (0.016)

Household size (HH_SIZE) -0.049 -0.425

(0.131) (0.178)

Asset Quartile 2 (D2ASSETS

) 0.039 0.040

(0.729) (0.908)

Asset Quartile 3 (D3ASSETS

) -0.199 -0.162

(0.110) (0.749)

Asset Quartile 4 (D4ASSETS

) -0.228 -0.892

(0.161) (0.210)

Land owned (LAND) 0.002** -0.003

(0.014) (0.447)

Number of social audits * Time -0.316** 0.220

(0.020) (0.718)

Date of interview during summer vacation -0.699*** -0.812

(0.001) (0.226)

Time 4.141*** 1.526

(0.000) (0.395)

Constant 11.122***

(0.000)

District Level Trends Yes Yes

Child Fixed Effects Yes Yes

Observations 5,786 5,786

Number of Children 2,893 2,893

R-squared 0.302

Notes: Robust p values in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 47: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

45

Table 5: Decomposition of effect by asset quartiles and land ownership (2SLS-FE)

Asset Quartiles Land Ownership

Asset

Quartile 1

Asset

Quartile 2

Asset

Quartile 3

Asset

Quartile 4

Land ≤ Median

(1.04 acre)

Land > Median

(1.04 acre)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Annual household income in thousands (INC) 0.001 -0.093 0.487 -0.040 0.017 0.205 (0.988) (0.266) (0.910) (0.859) (0.516) (0.879) Number of days mother worked in NREGS (MOTHER_NREGS) 0.105** 0.212* 1.418 0.724 0.147*** 0.713 (0.024) (0.061) (0.914) (0.846) (0.001) (0.723) Number of days father worked in NREGS (FATHER_NREGS) -0.089** -0.133 -2.221 -0.798 -0.187*** -0.819 (0.041) (0.316) (0.893) (0.800) (0.005) (0.745) Square of age (SQ_AGE) -0.079*** -0.094*** 0.143 -0.057 -0.050*** -0.089 (0.000) (0.000) (0.944) (0.814) (0.000) (0.138) Highest grade completed (GRADE) -0.434** -0.309 -3.403 -1.470 -0.333* -1.657 (0.023) (0.348) (0.881) (0.806) (0.085) (0.781) Square of highest grade completed (SQ_GRADE) 0.045*** 0.052* 0.240 0.059 0.041** 0.107 (0.002) (0.065) (0.843) (0.878) (0.024) (0.655) Household size (HH_SIZE) -0.044 0.456 -3.013 -0.091 -0.161 -0.903 (0.841) (0.490) (0.918) (0.905) (0.356) (0.886) Asset Quartile 2 (D2

ASSETS) 0.600 0.989 -5.480 0.213 -1.194

(0.100) (0.550) (0.912) (0.520) (0.805) Asset Quartile 3 (D3

ASSETS) 0.092 1.364 1.092 -7.334 0.134 -1.678

(0.847) (0.317) (0.955) (0.864) (0.758) (0.489) Asset Quartile 4 (D4

ASSETS) 0.030 2.525 -15.625 -0.254 -1.034

(0.974) (0.175) (0.889) (0.656) (0.772) Land owned (LAND) 0.043 0.161 -0.286 0.007 0.153 -0.011 (0.688) (0.609) (0.926) (0.796) (0.210) (0.905) Number of social audits * Time -0.602 -1.336 6.375 -0.343 -0.146 1.143 (0.127) (0.342) (0.953) (0.940) (0.760) (0.916) Date of interview during summer vacation -0.287 -2.071 -1.538 -4.628 -0.497 -2.422 (0.509) (0.115) (0.964) (0.822) (0.309) (0.643) Time 4.959*** 6.405* -15.449 4.556 2.449* 0.638 (0.000) (0.053) (0.951) (0.451) (0.061) (0.983)

District Level Trends Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Child Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 2,248 1,448 1,352 738 3,056 2,730 Number of Children 1,124 724 676 369 1,528 1,365

Notes: Robust p values in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 48: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

46

Table 6: Decomposition of effects by gender and age group (2SLS-FE)

Gender Age-group

Male Female 5-9 years 10-14 years

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Annual household income in thousands (INC) 0.013 0.132 0.049 0.040

(0.772) (0.449) (0.388) (0.590)

Number of days mother worked in NREGS (MOTHER_NREGS) 0.177 0.271* 0.225*** 0.122

(0.115) (0.095) (0.004) (0.185)

Number of days father worked in NREGS (FATHER_NREGS) -0.139** -0.467 -0.168** -0.276**

(0.022) (0.115) (0.013) (0.048)

Square of age (SQ_AGE) -0.064*** -0.030 -0.033 -0.036

(0.000) (0.438) (0.252) (0.403)

Highest grade completed (GRADE) -0.608*** -0.088 -0.511** -0.164

(0.003) (0.847) (0.023) (0.746)

Square of highest grade completed (SQ_GRADE) 0.063*** 0.012 0.035 0.033

(0.000) (0.783) (0.342) (0.271)

Household size (HH_SIZE) 0.014 -0.913 -0.070 -0.524

(0.947) (0.409) (0.784) (0.336)

Asset Quartile 2 (D2ASSETS

) -0.149 0.394 -0.119 0.275

(0.617) (0.652) (0.770) (0.602)

Asset Quartile 3 (D3ASSETS

) -0.638 1.069 -0.118 -0.015

(0.131) (0.583) (0.818) (0.985)

Asset Quartile 4 (D4ASSETS

) 0.044 -2.498 -0.804 0.118

(0.941) (0.316) (0.379) (0.858)

Land owned (LAND) -0.089 -0.006 -0.135 -0.000

(0.209) (0.605) (0.241) (1.000)

Number of social audits * Time 0.175 0.109 0.071 -0.255

(0.726) (0.946) (0.927) (0.673)

Date of interview during summer vacation -1.172 0.197 -2.165*** 1.578

(0.124) (0.903) (0.002) (0.345)

Time 3.412*** -1.012 1.260 0.645

(0.003) (0.866) (0.586) (0.859)

District Level Trends Yes Yes Yes Yes

Child Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Observations 2,794 2,992 3,544 2,242

Number of Children 1,397 1,496 1,772 1,121

Notes: Robust p values in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 49: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

47

Table 7: Effect of number of days mother worked in NREGS on child’s on grade progression

Overall Heterogeneity (2SLS-FE)

OLS-FE 2SLS-FE Land ≤ Median

(1.04 acre)

Land > Median

(1.04 acre)

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Annual household income in thousands (INC) 0.000 -0.035* -0.017 -0.055 (0.817) (0.051) (0.167) (0.461) Number of days mother worked in NREGS (MOTHER_NREGS) 0.003*** 0.033 0.031* -0.034 (0.003) (0.161) (0.069) (0.819) Number of days father worked in NREGS (FATHER_NREGS) -0.002** -0.024 -0.028 0.010 (0.046) (0.294) (0.224) (0.949) Square of age (SQ_AGE) 0.015*** 0.014*** 0.015*** 0.014** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.026) Household size (HH_SIZE) -0.034** 0.165 0.087 0.222 (0.033) (0.149) (0.448) (0.526) Asset Quartile 2 (D2

ASSETS) -0.122** -0.204** -0.259** 0.156

(0.024) (0.024) (0.010) (0.681) Asset Quartile 3 (D3

ASSETS) -0.054 -0.261* -0.212 0.079

(0.345) (0.094) (0.135) (0.854) Asset Quartile 4 (D4

ASSETS) -0.093 0.151 0.054 -0.004

(0.234) (0.440) (0.795) (0.991) Land owned (LAND) 0.000 0.003** 0.076 0.004 (0.128) (0.033) (0.176) (0.424) Number of social audits * Time 0.049 -0.329 -0.367 -0.257 (0.500) (0.217) (0.296) (0.703) Date of interview after March 0.116** -0.326 -0.144 -0.281 (0.020) (0.176) (0.608) (0.537) Time 1.463*** 2.160*** 1.958*** 2.818 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.241) Constant 1.652*** (0.000)

District Level Trends Yes Yes Yes Yes

Child Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Observations 5,922 5,922 3,142 2,780 Number of Children 2,961 2,961 1,571 1,390

R-squared 0.764

Page 50: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

48

TaTable 8: Effect of work status of mothers on their decision-making within household

Land

Earnings from

Land

Wage

Activities

Earnings from

Wage

Activities

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Working 1.061*** 1.242*** 0.966*** 1.364***

(0.003) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001)

Age -0.013 -0.031 0.015 -0.002

(0.521) (0.144) (0.420) (0.949)

Age squared 0.0002 0.0004 -0.0002 0.00003

(0.392) (0.140) (0.431) (0.941)

Highest grade passed 0.006** 0.007** 0.002 0.007*

(0.029) (0.021) (0.427) (0.100)

Household size -0.012* -0.009 -0.009 -0.018*

(0.065) (0.200) (0.240) (0.071)

Asset quartile 2 0.075* 0.091** 0.030 0.067

(0.086) (0.043) (0.459) (0.185)

Asset quartile 3 0.084 0.154** 0.018 0.096

(0.158) (0.013) (0.743) (0.165)

Asset quartile 4 0.115 0.137* 0.074 0.200*

(0.150) (0.094) (0.410) (0.087)

Household‟s land ownership -0.005 0.001 -0.018*** -0.019**

(0.360) (0.907) (0.009) (0.024)

Muslim 0.247** 0.199 0.012 0.300*

(0.049) (0.160) (0.926) (0.088)

Christian 0.125 -0.026 -0.076 -0.233

(0.410) (0.854) (0.594) (0.117)

SC -0.097* -0.117** 0.047 0.091

(0.066) (0.033) (0.426) (0.216)

ST -0.080 -0.121 0.072 0.016

(0.370) (0.186) (0.301) (0.853)

Backward caste -0.023 0.022 0.071 0.152**

(0.622) (0.647) (0.232) (0.047)

Mixed caste -0.338 -0.316 0.025 -0.055

(0.197) (0.306) (0.832) (0.527)

Constant -0.162 -0.002 -0.085 -0.067

(0.548) (0.996) (0.748) (0.837)

District fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Observations 1,946 1,977 1,500 1,474

Notes: Robust p-values in parantheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at

1%.

Page 51: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

49

Appendix

Figure A1: Participation in Private Casual

Labour in Andhra Pradesh

42

45 45

38 39 40

34

36

38

40

42

44

46

48

1999-00 2004-05 2009-10

%

Male Female

Figure A2: Wage Rate for Private Casual Labour

in Andhra Pradesh

68 73

115

78

43 45

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

1999-00 2004-05 2009-10

Male Female

Notes: Notes: The wage rates are calculated for the working population in the age group of 16-60 years.

The wage rates are expressed in 2009-10 rupees.

Sour Source:National Sample Survey data from 55th round (1999-00), round (2004-05) and 66

th round (2009-10).

Page 52: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

50

Table A1: First stage regressions (for overall results)

Time Spent in School

Annual

household

income in

thousands (INC)

Number of days

mother worked in

NREGS

(MOTHER_NREGS)

Number of days

father worked in

NREGS

(FATHER_NREGS)

(1) (2) (3)

Rainfall shock in May-June (RAIN) -12.895 2.570 7.032*

(0.108) (0.587) (0.091)

Number of ongoing NREGS projects (PROJECTS) 0.359** 0.200** 0.481***

(0.045) (0.043) (0.000)

RAIN * PROJECTS -0.126 0.479*** 0.408***

(0.660) (0.002) (0.002)

Square of age (SQ_AGE) -0.106 -0.011 0.007

(0.226) (0.822) (0.879)

Highest grade completed (GRADE) -0.141 0.527 -0.699

(0.916) (0.474) (0.308)

Square of highest grade completed (SQ_GRADE) 0.066 0.021 0.053

(0.568) (0.769) (0.423)

Household size (HH_SIZE) 5.112*** 0.044 0.053

(0.001) (0.894) (0.839)

Asset Quartile 2 (D2ASSETS

) -1.753 1.450 0.797

(0.252) (0.214) (0.460)

Asset Quartile 3 (D3ASSETS

) -4.128 2.137 0.853

(0.113) (0.136) (0.520)

Asset Quartile 4 (D4ASSETS

) 7.124** -3.045* -2.902**

(0.023) (0.079) (0.048)

Land owned (LAND) 0.069*** -0.004* -0.001

(0.000) (0.070) (0.669)

Number of social audits * time -10.592*** -0.427 -2.983*

(0.001) (0.833) (0.098)

Date of interview during summer vacation 0.885 8.152*** 6.150***

(0.814) (0.000) (0.000)

Time 13.880 18.894** 25.889***

(0.392) (0.042) (0.002)

Constant 17.383 -0.196 -0.939

(0.201) (0.969) (0.843)

District Level Trends Yes Yes Yes

Child Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Observations 5,786 5,786 5,786

Number of Children 2,893 2,893 2,893

R-squared 0.129 0.269 0.190

F-Stat 45.49 71.47 42.55

Notes: Robust p-values in parantheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 53: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

51

Figure A3: Administration of NREGA projects in Andhra Pradesh

Note: functionaries specific to NREGS in italics.

District Collector

Project Director

Additional Project Director

Dis

tric

t L

evel

Fu

nct

ion

ari

es

Mandal Parshad Development Officer (MPDO)

Additional Program Officer

(APO)

Asst. Engineer (AE)

Computer

Operators/Accounts

Officers

Techinical

Assistants (TA) M

an

dal

( or

sub

-dis

tric

t) L

evel

Fu

nct

ion

ari

es

Gram Panchayat

Field Assistant (FA)

Mate/Group Leader

Gra

m P

an

chaya

t L

evel

Fu

nct

ion

ari

es

Page 54: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

52

Table A2: Effect of social audits on household awareness

Taken

action on a

community

problem

Participated

in awareness

campaign

Participated in

protest march /

demonstration

Voted in

local

elections

Index 1# Index 2

##

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Number of social audits * Time 0.039 -0.046 -0.070*** 0.002 -0.191 -0.191

(0.225) (0.105) (0.001) (0.832) (0.132) (0.131)

Average age of the household 0.002 -0.002 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.002

(0.492) (0.428) (0.531) (0.547) (0.813) (0.824)

Household size 0.001 0.009 0.000 0.001 0.019 0.019

(0.832) (0.136) (0.969) (0.745) (0.431) (0.434)

Land owned 0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000

(0.204) (0.607) (0.492) (0.247) (0.790) (0.793)

Asset Quartile 2 (D2ASSETS

) 0.034 0.010 -0.009 -0.003 0.056 0.057

(0.116) (0.633) (0.572) (0.742) (0.530) (0.524)

Asset Quartile 3 (D3ASSETS

) 0.031 0.038 -0.002 -0.002 0.114 0.114

(0.203) (0.117) (0.901) (0.815) (0.243) (0.241)

Asset Quartile 4 (D4ASSETS

) 0.050 0.047 -0.006 -0.005 0.153 0.154

(0.115) (0.145) (0.779) (0.680) (0.248) (0.244)

Time -0.086** -0.077** 0.074*** 0.005 -0.103 -0.105

(0.022) (0.038) (0.004) (0.651) (0.493) (0.488)

Constant 0.033 0.076 0.015 0.974*** -0.351* -0.349*

(0.554) (0.123) (0.652) (0.000) (0.096) (0.098)

District Level Trends Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Household Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Observations 4,229 4,230 4,231 4,234 4,226 4,226

Number of Households 2,123 2,123 2,123 2,123 2,123 2,123

R-squared 0.046 0.056 0.038 0.022 0.057 0.058

Notes: Robust p values in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

# Index 1 is obtained by principal component analysis (PCA) of the dependent variables in column 1, 2, 3 and 4.

## Index 2 is obtained similarly by PCA of the dependent variables in column 1, 2, and 3 (excluding 4).

Page 55: Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in ...ftp.iza.org/dp6593.pdf · Female Labour Force Participation and Child Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural

53

Table A3: Effect of number of days mother worked in NREGS on child’s time spent in school

OLS-FE 2SLS-FE

(1) (2)

Annual household income in thousands (INC) 0.001 0.071

(0.202) (0.166)

Number of days mother worked in NREGS (MOTHER_NREGS) 0.001 0.225***

(0.456) (0.004)

Number of days father worked in NREGS (FATHER_NREGS) 0.001 -0.267***

(0.558) (0.002)

Square of age (SQ_AGE) -0.063*** -0.054***

(0.000) (0.000)

Highest grade completed (GRADE) -0.161** -0.468**

(0.016) (0.021)

Square of highest grade completed (SQ_GRADE) 0.039*** 0.043**

(0.000) (0.015)

Number of 0-4 years old females in household 0.071 -0.569

(0.574) (0.367)

Number of 0-4 years old males in household 0.047 -0.238

(0.730) (0.664)

Number of 5-9 years old females in household 0.076 0.044

(0.483) (0.898)

Number of 5-9 years old males in household 0.013 -1.165

(0.927) (0.113)

Number of 10-15 years old females in household 0.048 -0.153

(0.645) (0.723)

Number of 10-15 years old males in household -0.048 -0.686

(0.737) (0.162)

Number of females above 15 years of age in household -0.022 -0.698

(0.812) (0.257)

Number of males above 15 years of age in household -0.165* -0.076

(0.081) (0.816)

Asset Quartile 2 (D2ASSETS

) 0.051 -0.006

(0.649) (0.985)

Asset Quartile 3 (D3ASSETS

) -0.186 -0.235

(0.139) (0.609)

Asset Quartile 4 (D4ASSETS

) -0.218 -0.860

(0.181) (0.212)

Land owned (LAND) 0.002** -0.002

(0.014) (0.506)

Number of social audits * Time -0.308** 0.108

(0.025) (0.842)

Date of interview during summer vacation -0.697*** -0.773

(0.001) (0.245)

Time 4.098*** 1.810

(0.000) (0.269)

Constant 10.907***

(0.000)

District Level Trends Yes Yes

Child Fixed Effects Yes Yes

Observations 5,786 5,786

Number of Children 2,893 2,893

R-squared 0.302

Notes: Robust p values in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Controls for households‟ demographic composition in italics.


Top Related