cost minimization and cost curves

46
1 Cost Minimization and Cost Curves Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 3.1a, 3.2a-b, 4.1

Upload: cordelia-weeks

Post on 02-Jan-2016

85 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

DESCRIPTION

Cost Minimization and Cost Curves. Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 3.1a, 3.2a-b, 4.1. Agenda. The Cost Function and General Cost Minimization Cost Minimization with One Variable Input Deriving the Average Cost and Marginal Cost for One Input and One Output - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

1

Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

Beattie, Taylor, and WattsSections: 3.1a, 3.2a-b, 4.1

Page 2: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

2

Agenda The Cost Function and General Cost

Minimization Cost Minimization with One Variable

Input Deriving the Average Cost and

Marginal Cost for One Input and One Output

Cost Minimization with Two Variable Inputs

Page 3: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

3

Cost Function A cost function is a function that

maps a set of inputs into a cost. In the short-run, the cost function

incorporates both fixed and variable costs.

In the long-run, all costs are considered variable.

Page 4: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

4

Cost Function Cont. The cost function can be

represented as the following: C = c(x1, x2, …,xn)= w1*x1 + w2*x2 +

… + wn*xn

Where wi is the price of input i, xi, for i = 1, 2, …, n

Where C is some level of cost and c(•) is a function

Page 5: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

5

Cost Function Cont. When there are fixed costs, the cost function

can be represented as the following: C = c(x1, x2| x3, …,xn)= w1*x1 + w2*x2 + TFC Where wi is the price of the variable input i, xi, for

i = 1 and 2 Where wi is the price of the fixed input i, xi, for i

= 3, 4, …, n Where TFC = w3*x3 + … + wn*xn

When inputs are fixed, they can be lumped into one value which we usually denote as TFC

Where C is some level of cost and c(•) is a function

Page 6: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

Cost Function Cont. Suppose we have the following

cost function: C = c(x1, x2, x3)= 5*x1 + 9*x2 + 14*x3 If x3 was held constant at 4, then the

cost function can be written as: C = c(x1, x2| 4)= 5*x1 + 9*x2 + 56

Where TFC in this case is 56

6

Page 7: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

7

Cost Function Cont. The cost function is usually meaningless

unless you have some constraint that bounds it, i.e., minimum costs occur when all the inputs are equal to zero.

There are two major uses of the cost function: To minimize cost given a certain output

level. To maximize output given a certain cost.

Page 8: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

8

Standard Cost Minimization Model Assume that the general production function

can be represented as y = f(x1, x2, …, xn).

),...,,(:subject to

...

21

2211,...,,... 21

n

nnxxxtrw

xxxfy

xwxwxwMinn

Page 9: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

9

Cost Minimization with One Variable Input Assume that we have one variable input (x)

which costs w. Let TFC be the total fixed costs.

Assume that the general production function can be represented as y = f(x).

)(:subject to

...

xfy

TFCwxMinxtrw

Page 10: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

10

Cost Minimization with One Variable Input Cont. In the one input, one output world,

the solution to the minimization problem is trivial. By selecting a particular output y, you

are dictating the level of input x. The key is to choose the most

efficient input to obtain the output.

Page 11: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

11

Example of Cost Minimization Suppose that you have the following

production function: y = f(x) = 6x - x2

You also know that the price of the input is $10 and the total fixed cost is 45.

2

...

6)(:subject to

4510

xxxfy

xMinxtrw

Page 12: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

12

Example of Cost Minimization Cont. Since there is only one input and one

output, the problem can be solved by finding the most efficient input level to obtain the output.

yx

yx

yx

yx

yxx

xxy

93

2

946

2

4366

2

))(1(4)6()6(

06

6

2

2

2

Page 13: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

13

Example of Cost Minimization Cont. Given the previous, we must decide

whether to use the positive or negative sign. This is where economic intuition comes in. The one that makes economic sense is the

following:

yx 93

Page 14: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

14

Cost Function and Cost Curves There are many tools that can be

used to understand the cost function: Average Variable Cost (AVC) Average Fixed Cost (AFC) Average Cost (ATC) Marginal Cost (MC)

Page 15: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

15

Average Variable Cost Average variable cost is defined as the

cost function without the fixed costs divided by the output function.

APP

wAVC

xf

wxAVC

y

wxAVC

)(

Page 16: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

16

Average Fixed Cost Average fixed cost is defined as the cost

function without the variable costs divided by the output function.

)(xf

TFCAFC

y

TFCAFC

Page 17: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

17

Average Total Cost Average total cost is defined as the cost

function divided by the output function. It is also the summation of the average

fixed cost and average variable cost.

)()( xf

TFC

xf

wxATC

y

TFC

y

wxATC

y

TFCwxATC

Page 18: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

18

Marginal Cost Marginal cost is defined as the derivative of

the cost function with respect to the output. To obtain MC, you must substitute the

production function into the cost function and differentiate with respect to output.

MPP

wMC

xfyf

yfwyTVC

TFCyfwyTC

dy

ydTVC

dy

ydTCMC

)(y of inverse is )(

)(*)(

)(*)(

)()(

1

1

1

Page 19: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

19

Example of Finding Marginal Cost Using the production function y = f(x)

= 6x - x2, and a price of 10, find the MC by differentiating with respect to y.

To solve this problem, you need to solve the production function for x and plug it into the cost function. This gives you a cost function that is a

function of y.

Page 20: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

20

Example of Finding Marginal Cost Cont.

ydy

dcMC

ydy

dcMC

ydy

dcMC

y

y

yx

xxy

9

5

)9(10*2

1

)1()9(10*2

10

91030c(y)C

)9310(c(y)C

:givesfunction cost theinto thisPlugging

93

6

2

1

2

1

2

Page 21: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

21

Notes on Costs MC will meet AVC and ATC from

below at the corresponding minimum point of each. Why?

As output increases AFC goes to zero.

As output increases, AVC and ATC get closer to each other.

Page 22: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

22

Production and Cost Relationships Summary Cost curves are derived from the

physical production process. The two major relationships

between the cost curves and the production curves: AVC = w/APP MC = w/MPP

Page 23: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

23

Product Curve Relationships When MPP>APP, APP is increasing.

This implies that when MC<AVC, then AVC is decreasing.

When MPP=APP, APP is at a maximum. This implies that when MC=AVC, then AVC

is at a minimum. When MPP<APP, APP is decreasing.

This implies that when MC>AVC, then AVC is increasing.

Page 24: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

24

Product Curve Relationships Cont.

)(')(

0)(')(

0)(')(

0)]([

)(')(

)(

2

xxfxf

xxfxf

xwxfxwf

xf

xwxfxwf

dx

dAVC

xf

wxAVC

Page 25: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

25

Product Curve Relationships Cont.

AVCMC

APP

w

MPP

wAPPMPP

MPPAPP

xfx

xf

xxfxf

11

)(')(

)(')(

Page 26: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

26

Example of Examining the Relationship Between MC and AVC

Given that the production function y = f(x) = 6x - x2, and a price of 10, find the input(s) where AVC is greater than, equal to, and less than MC.

To solve this, examine the following situations: AVC = MC AVC > MC AVC < MC

Page 27: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

27

Example of Examining the Relationship Between MC and AVC Cont.

0

02

26626

10

6

10

26

10

6

10

6

10

)( 2

x

x

xxxx

MCAVCxMPP

wMC

xxx

x

xf

wxAVC

Page 28: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

28

Example of Examining the Relationship Between MC and AVC Cont.

x

xx

xxxx

MCAVCxMPP

wMC

xxx

x

xf

wxAVC

0

2

62626

10

6

10

26

10

6

10

6

10

)( 2

Page 29: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

29

Example of Examining the Relationship Between MC and AVC Cont.

0

26626

10

6

10

26

10

6

10

6

10

)( 2

x

xxxx

MCAVCxMPP

wMC

xxx

x

xf

wxAVC

Page 30: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

30

Review of the Iso-Cost Line The iso-cost line is a graphical

representation of the cost function with two inputs where the total cost C is held to some fixed level. C = c(x1,x2)=w1x1 + w2x2

Page 31: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

31

Finding the Slope of the Iso-Cost Line

2

1

1

2

2

11

22

2

11

22

22

1122

2211

w

w

dx

dx

w

xw

w

Cx

w

xw

w

C

w

xw

xwCxw

xwxwC

Page 32: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

32

Example of Iso-Cost Line Suppose you had $1000 to spend

on the production of lettuce. To produce lettuce, you need two

inputs labor and machinery. Labor costs you $10 per unit, while

machinery costs $100 per unit.

Page 33: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

33

Example of Iso-Cost Line Cont. Given the information above we

have the following cost function: C = c(labor, machinery) = $10*labor

+ $100*machinery 1000 = 10*x1 + 100*x2

Where C = 1000, x1 = labor, x2 = machinery

Page 34: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

34

Example of Iso-Cost Line Graphically

x2

x1

10

100

X2 = 10 – (1/10)*x1

Page 35: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

35

Finding the Slope of the Iso-Cost Line

10

110

10

100

10

100

1000

100

100

101000100

100101000

1

2

12

12

12

21

dx

dx

xx

xx

xx

xx

Page 36: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

36

Notes on Iso-Cost Line As you increase C, you shift the

iso-cost line parallel out. As you change one of the costs of

an input, the iso-cost line rotates.

Page 37: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

37

Input Use Selection There are two ways of examining how

to select the amount of each input used in production. Maximize output given a certain cost

constraint Minimize cost given a fixed level of

output Both give the same input selection

rule.

Page 38: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

38

Cost Minimization with Two Variable Inputs Assume that we have two variable inputs (x1 and

x2) which cost respectively w1 and w2. We have a total fixed cost of TFC.

Assume that the general production function can be represented as y = f(x1,x2).

),(:subject to 21

2211,... 21

xxfy

TFCxwxwMinxxtrw

Page 39: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

39

First Order Conditions for the Cost Minimization Problem with Two Inputs

0),(

0

0

0

0

),(),2,1(

21

2

22

2

1

11

1

212211

2

1

xxfy

MPPw

x

fw

x

MPPw

x

fw

x

xxfyTFCxwxwxx

x

x

Page 40: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

40

Implication of MRTS = Slope of Iso-Cost Line Slope of iso-cost line = -w1/w2, where w2 is

the cost of input 2 and w1 is cost of input 1. MRTS = -MPPx1/MPPx2 This implies MPPx1/MPPx2 = w1/w2

Which implies MPPx1 /w1 = MPPx2/w2

This means that the MPP of input 1 per dollar spent on input 1 should equal MPP of input 2 per dollar spent on input 2.

Page 41: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

41

Example 1 of Cost Minimization with Two Variable Inputs

Suppose you have the following production function: y = f(x1,x2) = 10x1

½ x2½

Suppose the price of input 1 is $1 and the price of input 2 is $4. Also suppose that TFC = 100.

What is the optimal amount of input 1 and 2 if you want to produce 20 units.

Page 42: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

42

Example 1 of Cost Minimization with Two Variable Inputs Cont.

Summary of what is known: w1 = 1, w2 = 4, TFC = 100 y = 10x1

½ x2½

y = 20

2

1

22

1

1

21,...

10:subject to

100421

xxy

xxMinxxtrw

Page 43: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

43

Example 1 of Cost Minimization with Two Variable Inputs Cont.

classin doneSolution

010

02

1104

02

1101

1010041),2,1(

2

1

22

1

1

2

1

22

1

12

2

1

22

1

11

2

1

22

1

121

xxy

xxx

xxx

xxyxxxx

Page 44: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

44

Solving Example 1 Using Ratio of MPP’s Equals Absolute Value of the Slope of the Cost Function

4x

1x20

4

20

xx20

)(x)10(4xy

function production into Plug3.

4

4

1

4

1Set 2.

.1

1

2

12

2

1

22

1

2

2

1

22

1

2

12

1

2

2

1

1

2

2

1

yxand

yx

y

xx

x

x

w

wMRTS

x

x

MPP

MPPMRTS

x

x

Page 45: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

45

Solving Example 1 Using MRTS from the Isoquant and Setting it Equal to the Slope of the Cost Function

4x

1x

205100

usingfor x Solve .4520

44

1

100

4

1Set3.

100MRTS

MRTS 2.Find

100100

Isoquant Find .1

1

2

12

2

12

1

21

2

2

1

21

2

1

2

11

2

1

2

2

yyyx

x

yyx

xy

w

wMRTS

xy

x

x

xy

x

yx

Page 46: Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

46

Final Note on Input Selection It does not matter whether you are

trying to maximize output given a fixed cost level or minimizing a cost given a fixed output level, you want to have the iso-cost line tangent to the isoquant. This implies that you will set the absolute

value of MRTS equal to the absolute value of the slope of the iso-cost line.