corruption and its implications for the economic...

130
1 CORRUPTION AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR THE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE MERCOSUR NATIONS: AN ECONOMETRIC APPROACH Submitted by Tariq Spalding Raza Northwestern University Mathematical Methods in the Social Sciences Senior Thesis Advisor: Professor Mark Witte May 2005

Upload: vuongkhuong

Post on 15-May-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

1

CORRUPTION AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR THE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE MERCOSUR

NATIONS: AN ECONOMETRIC APPROACH

Submitted by

Tariq Spalding Raza Northwestern University

Mathematical Methods in the Social Sciences Senior Thesis

Advisor: Professor Mark Witte May 2005

2

ABSTRACT

This thesis conducts an in-depth examination of corruption in the Mercosur nations and its implications for economic development by using an econometric approach. This type of investigation combines relevant aspects of mathematics, economics, and statistics to develop an econometric model explaining the impact of corruption on the economic development of the four Mercosur nations - Brazil, Argentina, Uruguay, and Paraguay. This field of investigation regarding the impact of corruption on economic development has only recently attracted a significant amount of academic and investigational interest due to the recently developed methodologies for measuring corruption. The output of such research has important implications for policy formation at national and international levels, as well as for multinational firms operating in environments where corruption often influences governmental and business relations. This study focuses on the impact of corruption in the Mercosur nations. Due to the many variables that can influence the level of corruption in a nation and its impact on the economy, the study develops a microeconomic model that investigates the impact of corruption on individual firms. This research yields an econometric model that demonstrates the impact of corruption on the growth rate of firms operating in an environment characterized by different levels of corruption. We take up the computer industry for the purpose of this study and investigate the different sectors of this industry into more detail. To understand the phenomenon further and analyze the results obtained from the econometric model in greater detail, we conducted survey questionnaires and structured interviews to determine the responses and perceptions of firms and managerial agents in the Mercosur nations to corrupt practices among bureaucrats.

3

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

This thesis was developed under the guidance of several professors who have provided invaluable commercial and academic contacts to assist in the project. Special gratitude goes to Professor Mark Witte, my advisor for this MMSS senior thesis. His exceptional suggestions and guidance have made this work possible. This research was also made possible due to Northwestern’s financial support, as the University has funded my travel to the Mercosur nations during the summer of 2004 and Winter Break of 2005. For this I am grateful to both Dean Mary Finn for her kindness in providing my summer research grant, and to Professor Josef Barton and The Undergraduate Research Grants Committee for providing me a year research grant for this project. I am also indebted to Professor Rosa Matzkin who has provided research contacts at the Universidad de San Andrés and Universidad Torcuato di Tella, both in Argentina. Through Professor Matzkin, I have established contact with Professor Ernesto Schargrodsky, a noted expert in corruption. Professor Schargrodsky specializes in the collection of data on corruption through survey questionnaires and interviews; his excellent suggestions on the methodology of this thesis and his thoughtful suggestions on the design of the survey questionnaire and structured interviews’ questions were extremely important for the accuracy of the results and for the high rate of response from the surveys’ respondents. Also, I would like to express my gratitude to all the professors in the MMSS program, and in particular to Professor William Rogerson for giving me the opportunity to participate in this rewarding program.

I dedicate this work to the memory of my mom, Yula, who was a great woman. Her assistance continuously strengthened my confidence in my abilities and desire for knowledge through the infinite process of learning. Also, special thanks are owed to my family, in particular my dad, Raza, my grandma, Tita, my brother, Zafar, and close friends, Geert and Olga Van Koeverden, Ibrahim, Zebeda, and Faruk Kanamia, whose continuous support was essential for the completion of both this thesis and my studies at Northwestern. This work could not have been completed without the support of many other people from Brazil, Paraguay, Uruguay, and Argentina. Too numerous to specifically list here, they range from professors who provided important guidance and critique of the methodology to managers from firms in various industry sectors whose willingness and patience to answer the survey questionnaires and structured interview questions were essential.

4

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Abstract ........................................................................................................................... 2 List of Tables and Figures ........................................................................................ 6 Chapter 1: Introduction ............................................................................................ 8

1.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................... 8 1.2 Structure of the Thesis ..................................................................................... 10

Chapter 2: Literature Review................................................................................ 13

2.1 Corruption and its Impact on Economic Growth ...................................... 13 2.2 Corruption Indices ............................................................................................ 18 2.3 Research Gap: Statement of the Problem ................................................... 23

Chapter 3: Framework for the Study ................................................................. 25

3.1 Research Questions and Research Framework.......................................... 25 3.2 Hypothesis........................................................................................................... 26 3.3 Theoretical Constructs ..................................................................................... 27 3.4 Industry Sector Selection ................................................................................ 32

Chapter 4: Research Design ................................................................................... 35

4.1 Operationalizing Variables for the Test Instruments ............................... 35 4.1.1 Economic Growth of Firms ............................................................................. 36 4.1.2 The Level of Corruption .................................................................................. 37

4.2 Pilot Study........................................................................................................... 42 4.3 Identification of the Sample Population...................................................... 44 4.4 Sample Selection Process and Data Collection ......................................... 46 4.5 Data Analysis Plan............................................................................................ 54

Chapter 5: Data Analysis, Results & Discussion ............................................ 59

5.1 Sample Description........................................................................................... 59 5.2 Reliability of Scale Measures ........................................................................ 60 5.3 Factor Analysis .................................................................................................. 61 5.4 Testing for Heteroscedasticity ....................................................................... 63 5.5 Testing for Endogeneity .................................................................................. 67 5.6 Testing for Spatial Autocorrelation .............................................................. 69 5.7 Hypothesis Testing ........................................................................................... 71

5.7.1 ROI and Level of Corruption........................................................................... 71 5.7.2: The Rent Seeking Behavior and Industry Sectors .......................................... 73

5

5.7.3: Differences in Rent Seeking Behavior across Nations and Rate of Growth of Firms ......................................................................................................................... 77 5.7.4: The Overall Model.......................................................................................... 79

5.8 Analysis of Structured Interviews................................................................. 82 5.8.1 Sample Description.......................................................................................... 82 5.8.2 Competitive Disadvantage Because of Rent Seeking Behavior of Bureaucrats................................................................................................................................... 83 5.8.3 Corruption Level in Computer Industry .......................................................... 84 5.8.4 Changes in Corruption Level ........................................................................... 84 5.8.5 Analysis of Open Ended Questions ................................................................. 86

5.9 Discussion ........................................................................................................... 89 Chapter 6: Implications, Limitations, and Future Research Directions 93

6.1 Contribution and Implications ....................................................................... 93 6.2 Limitations .......................................................................................................... 94 6.3 Future Research Directions ............................................................................ 96 6.4 Conclusion .......................................................................................................... 97

References..................................................................................................................... 99 Appendices

Appendix 1: Transparency International Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI) 2003................................................................................................................ 104 Appendix 2: CPI and EMI Irregular Payments Comparison, Sample Data..................................................................................................................................... 107 Appendix A: Methodology ................................................................................. 108

A.1 Development of Questionnaire ........................................................................ 108 A.2 Interview Data.................................................................................................. 110 A.3 External Data.................................................................................................... 113 A.4 Data Collection Methodology.......................................................................... 113 A.5 Data Collection in the Mercosur Nations......................................................... 114 A.6 Pilot Study Analysis......................................................................................... 115 A.7: Data Collection through the Internet............................................................... 123

Appendix B: Correlations Between all variables ........................................... 128 Appendix C: Questionnaire................................................................................. 129

6

LIST OF TABLES: Table 4.1: Mercosur Nation GDP ..................................................................................... 52

Table 5.1: Distribution of respondents across the nations ................................................ 59

Table 5.2: Distribution of respondents across the seven sectors of computer industry.... 60

Table 5.3 Mean and Standard Deviation of ROI of Firms in Four Mercosur Nations ..... 60

Table 5.4 Mean and Standard Deviation of ROI of Firms in Different Industry Sectors. 60

Table 5.5 Reliability of scale measures ............................................................................ 61

Table 5.6: Inter-item correlations ..................................................................................... 61

Table 5.7: Factor Analysis ................................................................................................ 62

Table 5.8: Test for Heteroscedasticity .............................................................................. 65

Table 5.9: Test for Endogeneity........................................................................................ 68

Table 5.10: Mean Value of Residuals............................................................................... 70

Table 5.11: Regression Analysis of ROI as Dependent Variable and Corruption Level as

Independent Variable ........................................................................................................ 72

Table 5.12: ANOVA with Corruption Level as dependent variable and Industry Sector as

independent variable ......................................................................................................... 74

Table 5.13: Regression with Corruption Level as dependent variable and Industry Sector

as independent variable..................................................................................................... 75

Table 5.14: ANOVA to assess the differences in Rent Seeking Behavior ....................... 77

Table 5.15: Regression with Corruption Level as dependent variable and Country as

independent variable ......................................................................................................... 78

Table 5.16: Overall Model with ROI as dependent variable and Corruption Level,

Country, and Industry Sector as independent variables.................................................... 80

Table 5.17: Distribution of interviewees across the nations ............................................. 82

Table 5.18: Distribution of respondents across the seven sectors of computer industry.. 82

Table A.1: Industry Data................................................................................................. 119

Table A.2: Respondents from the Mercosur Nations...................................................... 119

Table A.3: ROI and Respondents ................................................................................... 119

Table A.4: Correlations between different variables ...................................................... 120

Table A.5: Factor Analysis ............................................................................................. 121

7

Table A.6: Regression Analysis with ROI as dependent variable and Corruption Level as

independent variable ....................................................................................................... 122

Table B.1: Correlation between different variables............................................................... 128

LIST OF FIGURES:

Fig. 1 Research Framework .............................................................................................. 26 Fig. 2: Demand Supply for Rents ..................................................................................... 30

8

Chapter 1

INTRODUCTION

1.1 Introduction

Corruption generally defines a transaction where individuals bound by a

principle-agent agreement take advantage of their position by selling a third-party

property rights that do not belong to them (Colombatto, 2001). In the context of

governmental corruption, the principle-agent agreement is between the government and

the official in the bureaucracy. This bureaucracy is bound by the agreement to conduct a

particular function for the citizens of the nation on behalf of the government. When

bureaucrats use the power of their position to increase or reduce costs for some at the

expense of others, they violate the implicit agreement with the government to render

services fairly and impartially. Thus, the bureaucrat who receives an “inducement” to

perform a service extracts wealth from the payer of the bribe without producing value

equivalent to the extracted wealth.

From an economic perspective, corruption is generally accounted for in the rent-

seeking theory, which was originated with Tulloch (1980). Rent-seeking occurs when a

government, firm, or individual expends resources to bring about an uncompensated

transfer of goods or services from another entity. Although the rent-seeking theory is

primarily concerned with the way that firms or individuals seek changes in public policy

to benefit them at the expense of others, this theory also applies to corrupt practices.

These practices, such as bribery, confer benefits on the corrupt official at the expense of

the firm or individual supporting the corrupt practice. They do so by paying the bribe.

9

Essentially, the corrupt official receives a transfer of wealth with compensation neither to

the firm nor to the individual transferring the wealth.

The rent-seeking approach to corruption does not attempt to assign a moral status

to the act; instead, it views corruption as an economic function that influences the transfer

of goods and services by raising costs and creating artificial market barriers. The

approach also views the action or non-action of the government in permitting the

corruption to flourish as a policy position intended to benefit a small group, such as

bureaucrats who profit from the rent seeking activity.

A market economy generally consists of a system of interactions where

individuals acquire and communicate information about scarcity through a pricing

mechanism that allows for the private determination of the best method to allocate

resources. Market disturbances can occur due to a plethora of factors, governmental

policy and technological changes, that induce price changes. These alterations encourage

individuals to act in a manner that does not fully reflect the way that they would allocate

resources if the disturbance were absent. In this context, bureaucratic corruption operates

as a market disturbance. It induces market participants to act in a manner that fails to

reflect their perception of the most efficient manner to allocate resources. In effect, A

portion of the market price is directed towards a corrupt bureaucrat; as a result, the cost

for all market participants increases and a percentage of the cost is misallocated.

10

Despite the prevalent recognition that corruption has a negative impact on

economic growth, some significant difficulties remain in many nations in rooting out

corruption. These obstacles exist due to the difficulties that individuals and single firms

encounter when attempting to resist corrupt practices in an environment where corruption

is endemic. This is due to strategic complementarities, which are situations where if one

agent engages in either a corrupt or non-corrupt practice, other agents receive incentives

to engage in similar practices. For example, if a bureaucrat operates in an environment

where his peers and superiors are likely to be corrupt, then it is unprofitable for the

bureaucrat to resist engaging in corruption (Mauro, 1995). Such individuals often justify

their corruption as being a form of efficiency.

1.2 Structure of the Thesis

Given this background of corruption, such as the rent-seeking behavior of

bureaucrats, this thesis will investigate the impact of rent-seeking behavior of bureaucrats

on the economic development of the nation. For the investigation, we chose the computer

industry in the four Mercosur nations. We study the seven sectors of this industry:

Software, Computer Manufacturing, Computer Supply, Semiconductor Manufacturing,

Networking or other services, Peripheral Manufacturing, and others. The thesis is laid out

in six chapters. The second chapter provides a review of existing literature. It summarizes

the key findings of research on corruption and its impact on economic development. The

culmination of this chapter is the identified research gap.

The third chapter covers the study’s framework, identification of key variables

and constructs, and the research hypotheses. In this framework, we show the relationships

11

that we are going to study. Identification of key variables and constructs is important to

establish the relationships. Development of research hypotheses is the last part of this

chapter that will help us to perform the appropriate statistical tests and analyze the

results.

Chapter four describes the methodology and provides details on methodology in

terms of sample size, sampling procedure, measuring instruments used, data collection

method, and the data analysis plan. In this chapter, we describe in detail how we chose

the sample size and its minimum requirement. Then, we move onto our sampling

procedure best to suit our requirements and constraints. To measure the variables

identified in the previous chapter, we next developed our measurement instrument.

Continuing the same chapter, we presented our data analysis plan in which we provide

details on statistical tests used for analysis.

The fifth chapter presents the data analysis. We first provide the analysis of

results obtained from the econometric model. We also show our further investigation and

support/reject our findings from the earlier part by the outcome of analysis of structured

interviews conducted for the said purpose. At the end of this chapter, we discuss our

results and generate insights.

The final chapter deals with the contribution and implications where we discuss

interesting insights generated as the output of this research and implications for

12

academicians and practitioners, including policy makers. Finally, in this chapter we

discuss limitations of this research and directions for future research to enhance the field.

13

Chapter 2

LITERATURE REVIEW

This chapter is broadly divided into three sections. In the first, we take up

literature on corruption and its impact on the economic growth. In second section, we

look at measurement of corruption and related problems. The last section deals with

summarizing the literature and identification of the research gap.

2.1 Corruption and its Impact on Economic Growth

The review of related literature provided an overview of the research regarding

corruption and its impact on economic growth. In the most part, the available research on

the issue of corruption has generally adopted a macroeconomic approach, examining

corruption in terms of GDP, its impact on foreign direct investment, and its affect on the

allocation of resources on a national level. In addition, the literature can be broadly

grouped into quantitative and qualitative analysis of the impact of corruption. The

primary issue involved with the quantitative research approaches has been the means

used to operationalize the somewhat subjective variable of corruption. The qualitative

studies focused on identifying and raising the issues. Thus, based on the review of related

literature, theoretical frameworks and models are proposed.

Extensive literature examined corruption from the perspective of rent-seeking

behavior, which is the opportunity for an individual or a group to obtain income that

exceeds the income normally available in a perfectly competitive market. Kahn and Jomo

(2000) examined the impact of government-created rents on the development of Asian

14

economies; this differs from rents due to corruption because the government officially or

unofficially sanctions the rent. The impact of official government rent and the unofficial

rents due to corruption on economic growth is variable, as some types of rents are not

invariably harmful to the economy. Hutchcroft (1997) supports this argument; the study

found no simple or direct correlation between corruption and the economic growth of a

developing country. The way that privileges and rents are distributed in the economy

form four independent variables that determine the corruptive impact on the dependent

variable of economic growth. In situations where corruption does not prevent

development, the economy could grow despite the corrupt environment.

Antwi and Adams (2003) found that when a governmental agency diverts

resources from outside sources intended for urban renewal projects through high salaries

and privileges for administrators, very few funds reach their intended use. This model

corresponds with that of Hutchcroft’s model by establishing conditions where corruption

impedes economic development. Mbaku (1999) concluded that political and institutional

structures in African nations foster rent-seeking behavior by placing a large number of

restrictions on ordinary economic activities. A complex regulatory system creates a

strong tendency for bureaucrats to take advantage of their positions by seeking gratuities

for performing routine services; this leads to endemic and institutionalized corruption.

Colombatto (2004) examined corruption as a breach of contract between a

principal and an agent; the ethics of the corruption is contingent on the underlying terms

of the contract. In the context of government, the bureaucrat is bound by the implied

15

contract associated with the position and breaches the contract through the sale of

administrative functions that should be freely granted.

Corruption in the private sphere is self-limiting, because competitive forces

eventually force the corrupt practices to end. Corruption in the public sphere, however, is

subject only to the structural limitations placed on governmental activities.

Easterly’s assessment indicated corruption’s effect on economic growth varies

both in different countries and within a nation over time, as variable factors determine the

impact (Easterly, 2001). The two decentralized and centralized models of corruption

suggest that the way in which corrupt institutions operate in a society is a strong factor

for determining corruption’s economic impact. In the decentralized model, the impact of

corruption on economic growth appears to be more focused and reduces the overall level

of incentives for individuals to engage in economic activity. This accounts for some of

the differences in the impact of corruption among various nations.

Research of Fisman and Gatti (2004) appears to support Easterly’s position. Their

research suggests that decentralized governments are more corrupt because spending

decisions are made at the local level, with less oversight of local officials by the central

government. De Soto contends that when a government imposes excessive regulations, it

reduces the rate of economic growth by raising the costs associated with business (De

Soto, 2002). This creates a widespread disincentive for firms to engage in business, and

economic growth reduces.

16

Dixit’s position suggests that some degree of corruption is inevitable in all

economic systems due to the system’s size (Dixit, 2003). In this model, self-enforced

honesty functions only in small economic systems where there are penalties in the form

of loss of trading relationships as the price for dishonesty. As the economic system

expands in size, only structural factors such as oversight of bureaucratic operations can

reduce the general propensity towards dishonesty. In nations lacking institutions

necessary to replace self-governance of honesty with oversight, corruption will likelier be

a significant factor in economic activity. To some degree, this position conforms to that

of McCarthy and Hagan (2001); they argue that corruption arises from a misapplied

investment in human capital. Once a corrupt system is in place within an economy, it

tends to provide an ongoing investment in criminal social capital. From this perspective,

the system encourages individuals to be corrupt and trains them in the techniques

necessary for successful use of corrupt practices. As such, the society becomes immune

to the judgments of corruption, with the practices accepted as the norm.

Mauro (1995) conducted one of the early empirical investigations of corruption

and economic growth in nations by using the Business International measure of

corruption, which has subsequently been incorporated into the Economist Intelligence

Unit (Coalition Report, 2000). Due to the high potential of variables impacting economic

growth, other than corruption, the study also incorporated nine other measures of the

macroeconomic environment, including political and labor stability. A correlation

between corruption and low economic growth exists. A difficulty with this study,

however, was the methodology used to quantify the variables that determined the

17

outcome. Because it depended on the quantification of variables through the surveys

conducted by Business International, the process was not identical for all countries.

Business International used various data sources and methods for each nation to

determine the level of corruption and other factors such as the amount of red tape and the

transparency of government operations. Nonetheless, the study represents a reasonable

effort to quantify and operationalize macroeconomic variables prior to the development

of more definitive and concise methods of examining corruption and its effect on an

economy. An important finding is that a more homogenous society is less likely to

experience corruption; it will instead have a more efficient bureaucracy than a society

characterized by many ethnic and linguistic groups.

Mauro based a qualitative assessment of how corruption affects the economy on

the findings of his empirical research (Coalition Report, 2000). Corruption is more likely

to occur when the government creates barriers to economic activity that can produce

excessive profits such as market entry barriers. Individuals collecting the high profits are

willing to protect their position by bribing government officials. Corruption will likely

occur when bureaucrats are poorly paid and thus become corrupt to maintain an adequate

standard of living. The payments made to corrupt officials operate as an indirect tax,

which reduces incentives to engage in economic activity and reduces profitability. This

raises the transaction costs and encourages a lower investment rate due to the lower levels

of return. It further distorts the revenues available to the government; this reduces the

ability of the government to engage in development and infrastructure enhancement.

18

Rosenberg (2003) provided qualitative discussion of the factors contributing to a

corrupt environment and suggests that the debate on corruption is focusing on the best

methods to reduce or eliminate corruption rather than on corruption’s causes. Corruption

is endemic and can be found in all nations. Larger governments, however, tend to be less

corrupt, for they have more resources at their disposal and a greater ability to oversee the

bureaucrats’ activities.

A potential proxy for corruption is the type of investor protection statutes in a

nation and the degree that they are enforced (La Porta et al, 1998). The general outcome

of weak protections for investors is to marginalize the small investor; the ownership of

public corporations is concentrated in the hands of a few politically well-connected

individuals who can obtain protections from the legal system. Of the Mercosur nations,

only Brazil had relatively good protections for investors, which suggests that the

ownership of corporations in the other three Mercosur nations is concentrated in the

hands of a relatively few individuals. This creates an incentive for these individuals to

protect their position through corrupt practices and a disincentive for the marginal

investor to seek ownership in public corporations. A relatively low level of enforcement

of investor protection laws exist in the Mercosur nations, thus reducing the amount of

foreign direct investment occurring in these nations.

2.2 Corruption Indices

Empirical research into corruption highly depends on the measure used to

quantify a nation’s corruption. Such quantification is necessary for establishing the value

19

of the key independent variable of the study, which is the level of corruption in a specific

environment. Corruption, however, is a generic term that describes a collection of

variables, which are identified as corrupt practices. As a result, there can be some degree

of difference in the various methods used to measure corruption that have been developed

from the types of variables included as the foundational data for the measure.

Additionally, there are differences in how data is collected and weighted to form the

measure. To a large degree, the differences in the way the measure of corruption is

constructed can impact a replication of the findings of a study due to the potential for

substantially different values assigned to the independent variable of corruption.

The only existing global index for the measurement of corruption that provides

comprehensive data in a unified manner is the index developed by Transparency

International. Formed in 1993, the organization’s objective is to reduce global corruption

by publicizing corrupt practices. In 1997, the organization began publishing the

Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI), which ranks countries according to the degree that

business, outside observers, public officials, and politicians perceive corruption. The CPI

is based on a survey of senior managers in a large number of nations; it solicits

information such as the frequency of bribery, the perception of corruption in civil service,

and the amount of red tape encountered in dealing with the bureaucracy. The CPI is a

composite index, as it makes use of both the survey data and the assessments of countries

by independent analysts (Lambsdorff, 2002). It also uses additional different sources such

as the World Bank business Environment Survey and Economic Intelligence Unit Data.

A deficiency in the methodology for the development of the index is variability in the

20

nature of the composite sources in successive years, which undermines comparability. In

addition, the number of sources used in the composite index for each country is variable

(See Appendix 1). Despite its shortcomings, however, the CPI is currently the best tool

available to measure corruption.

The black market activity index, which is a sub-index of Economic Freedom

Index (EFI), can also potentially be used to measure corruption. The EFI includes a

component that determines the level of “irregular payments” occurring in a nation’s

economy on a scale of 0-10, with 10 representing a high level of irregular payments. This

component of the EFI functionally measures the level of black market activity present in

an economy; this activity acts as a proxy measure for corruption. The irregular payments

component of the EFI, however, is not available for all nations. The only source for the

irregular payments data is the Global Competitiveness Report by the World Economic

Forum (2003 Annual, 12).

Researchers examining corruption have also used proxy measures for corruption

drawn from the indices prepared by the Economic Intelligence Unit (EIU). This private

firm sells business and economic information. The EIU makes indices on 56 risk factors

available on various nations and creates a composite score for the overall risk represented

by the country. In addition, the risk factors include a number of specific risks such as

political stability and risk of terrorism. One of the risk factors measured is corruption,

which is based on the analysts’ perception of the level of corruption in the nation. All risk

factors including corruption are rated on a scale of 0-10. Some of the additional risk

21

factors such as the efficiency of the legal system have also been used as proxy measures

for corruption.

A regional corruption index to monitor the nations of Eastern Europe that is

known as the Corruption Monitoring System (CMS) has been developed (Coalition

Report, 2000). The development of this index uses a similar methodology to the CPI in

that it heavily relies on surveys conducted among managers in both the target nations and

independent analyst opinions. The output of the index, however, is significantly different

from the output of the CPI; it ranks each nation in specific areas of corrupt practices

rather than giving an overall ranking for the nation. In effect, this index is actually four

separate indices that measure attitudes towards corruption, the prevalence of corrupt

practices, and an assessment of the scope of corruption and corruption-related

expectations. Each nation in the region is assigned a score from one to ten in each of the

four major index areas, but the rankings of the nations, with respect to each other as well

as an overall ranking, is not given (Coalition Report, 2000). This difference in output

between the CPI and the CMS makes it difficult to compare the two systems in a

meaningful manner.

Due to the substantial differences in the way corruption information is gathered

and quantified in the various measures or indices of corruption, an analysis of the

deviation occurring between measurements is difficult. The CPI is the only index that

presents corruption information in a coherent and unified manner. The EIU data on

corruption is embedded in reports regarding the risk factors in various countries; it does

22

not provide relative rankings of the nations. As a result, the data must be extracted from

the reports manually. In addition, it is not presented in a format that provides for

comparability. Similarly, the CMS does not provide unified data that enables a precise

comparison with the EPI.

In general, corruption research increasingly relies on the use of the CPI as the

primary measurement for corruption’s existence in a specific nation. The use of

researcher-developed measures for corruption raises the issue of comparability and

replication of the study findings when another type of measurement system is used.

While the EIU was often used as a basis for obtaining standardized measures of past

corruption, the development of the CPI has functionally reduced the inherent difficulties

with the EIU’s scattered presentation of corruption data. This is apparent from the

complex method that Mauro used in his 1995 study of corruption, which relied on the

EIU as the primary source of information to quantify corruption (Mauro, 1995). As a

result, the CPI represents the most precise measurement of corruption in the present; its

use supports the ability of other researchers to replicate the findings of a study.

Wilhelm (2002) conducted a study to validate the CPI as an appropriate measure

of corruption, which is a research area not yet examined. This study attempted to

determine whether there was correlation between the CPI and two EFI sub-indices of

irregular payments, which was a proxy for black market activity, and unnecessary

restrictions on business activity. The findings of the study indicated a significant

correlation between the three measures. In addition, the study determined that there was a

23

highly significant correlation between the CPI and real domestic gross product per capita.

This finding further suggests that the CPI is the most valid measure for corruption that is

currently available.

2.3 Research Gap: Statement of the Problem

The above literature review on corruption and its impact on economic growth

suggests that the research focuses mostly on how corruption affects economic growth at

the macroeconomic level. None of the studies reviewed looked at the impact of

corruption at the microeconomic level. The research studies took up different regions of

the world such as Africa and Asia; however, we found no study covering the Mercosur

nations.

In the Mercosur nations, the relatively high levels of corruption can adversely

affect the growth rate of individual firms, as the GDP growth encounters a negative

impact. Due to the rent-seeking behavior of bureaucrats, most of whom seek to maximize

the size of their wealth, firms involved in highly regulated industry sectors with good

prospects for future growth are more likely to have to pay a higher bribe to officials than

firms in non-regulated industry sectors with poor prospects for future growth.

Additionally, similarly situated firms in Mercosur nations with higher CPI’s, such as

Paraguay and Argentina, are more likely to pay higher levels of bribes than firms in

nations with lower CPI such as Uruguay and Brazil. The problem lies in developing an

appropriate measure for dishonesty suitable for use on a microeconomic scale to

determine if this corruption would affect individual firms’ growth rates.

24

We also highlighted the difficulties in measuring the corruption. The research

lacks a generic approach to measure the corruption. The field is void of reliable and valid

scales to operationalize the corruption as a construct. With this, we set forth for the

research and try to fill the identified gaps. The next section deals with research questions,

the framework for the study, and the hypotheses.

25

Chapter 3

FRAMEWORK FOR THE STUDY

3.1 Research Questions and Research Framework

The following points emerged out of the literature review.

I. The impact of corruption is well researched in the literature; however, all the

studies are focused at the macroeconomic level. None of the studies reviewed

looked at the impact of corruption on economic growth at the microeconomic

level, such as the firm level.

II. We found studies covering different regions of the world, but none covering the

impact of corruption on the economic growth of the Mercosur nations.

III. We also highlighted the shortcomings of different indices of corruption. During

the literature review, we learned that the field is void of reliable and valid scales

to measure the corruption.

This study was designed to answer the following research questions:

1. Does the rent-seeking behavior of bureaucrats have a negative impact on

the growth rate of firms?

2. Are there differences in the perceptions of rent-seeking behavior of

bureaucrats among firms in Mercosur nations in different industry sectors?

26

Country

Industry

Level of Corruption

ROI

3. Does the impact on growth of rent-seeking behaviors on similarly situated

firms in the Mercosur nations correspond with predictions based on the

CPI?

To answer the above research questions a conceptual framework is proposed as

shown in figure 1.

Fig. 1 Research Framework

3.2 Hypothesis

To answer the research questions posed above, here we develop research

hypotheses. It contended that identifiable differences in the impact of corruption on the

growth of firms in the Mercosur nations exist. The hypotheses formulated for the study in

their alternative form were as follows:

H1α1: Firms that pay a higher rate of bribes have a slower rate of growth.

27

H2α1: There are differences in rent-seeking behavior among bureaucrats in

different industry sectors.

H3α1: The general climate of corruption in a nation impacts rent-seeking

behavior among bureaucrats and the rate of growth of firms.

3.3 Theoretical Constructs

The basic theoretical model for the study is based on the assumptions of previous

researchers regarding the relationship between corruption and economic growth. The

model’s fundamental assumption is that corruption is a form of rent-seeking behavior that

creates economic barriers to growth and diverts resources, which would otherwise

develop infrastructure and other supports for economic growth. Rent-seeking occurs

when resources are expended to bring about an uncompensated transfer of goods or

services, which thereby confers a benefit on the corrupt official. This benefit has a higher

economic value than the one conveyed in return to the individual or firm conferring the

benefit. Over the long run, the corrupt practices create disturbances to the market

economy in which resources are not allocated efficiently (Colombatto, 2004). The result

is a lower level of market efficiency and growth in environments characterized by high

levels of corruption.

A difficulty with establishing a theoretical model for the way in which corruption

affects an economy, however, is that researchers have developed two separate theoretical

models for corruption. The first focuses heavily on the diversion of economic resources

by corrupt bureaucratic officials, thus resulting in less investment in the basic

28

infrastructure necessary for economic growth. This theoretical position assumes that the

diversion of resources leads to a lower marginal product of capital. In effect, the model

proposes that corruption’s actual economic impact relates to the quantity of resources

diverted by corrupt practices (Mauro, 1995).

This diversion model presumes that the government is the primary agent that

controls the economic distribution of goods and services and the degree of investment

that will occur to foster future economic growth. It further presumes that equilibrium will

be established between the ability of the corrupt bureaucrats to extract rents and the

willingness and the ability of the economic agents to pay rents. The level that such

equilibrium occurs is contingent on a number of factors - the degree of governmental

control over the economy, the population’s acceptance of the status quo, and the benefits

that the population perceives from the operation of the economic and political system—

that cannot be precisely measured and is often psychological in nature. As a result, the

model is flexible enough to accommodate the apparent differences in the level of

corruption occurring in various nations as well as the differences in corruption’s impact

on economic growth.

The second type of model often used to support research into corruption focuses

on the restrictions that exist on rent seeking behavior. It assumes that human nature is

such that corruption inherently occurs within all markets. It also assumes that markets

tend to create different types of barriers to corrupt practices; government-created barriers

exist when the markets are large and complex, such as the ones that exist in a national

29

market environment. As a result, the government can create either strong or weak barriers

to corruption; both depend on a variety of political, cultural, and social factors. At the

same time, the model also presumes that there are negative economic and political

consequences to the existence of corruption, with the governmental management of

barriers to corruption contingent on the degree of the market’s tolerance for corrupt

practices. In effect, political risk increases significantly when the level of corruption

exceeds the tolerance of the market.

Equilibrium occurs when the desire of the bureaucrat to collect rent is balanced

with the negative political reaction to the consequences of the inequitable transfer of

wealth. It is expressed as ∑=

=N

i

irr1

in which r is the bribe rate, which is the sum of the

individual decisions of politicians’ determinations of how high a bribe rate ir will be

imposed on the economy. A destabilizing event occurs when the government imposes

increased restrictions on corruption, which theoretically reduce the bribe rate until a new

equilibrium point is reached. Such an event can also occur when the government loosens

restrictions on the bribe rate, causing the equilibrium point to rise. Both actions on the

part of the government have transaction costs, the extent and impact of which are based

on the specific circumstances of the political and market environment. This government

intervention model suggests that corruption is an endogenous variable in an economy

(Coupet, 2003).

In both models, the actions of the government are critical in determining the level

of corruption. At the same time, such actions are contingent on a wide variety of social,

30

political, cultural, and economic factors. As a result, we see a third model - the supply

and demand model. In this model, positive or negative growth in the economy can

destabilize equilibrium, which impacts the corrupt bureaucrats’ abilities to extract rents.

A small amount of economic growth, which impacts the supply of available rents, brings

a corresponding increase in the demand from bureaucrats for rents. As a result, the

equilibrium point between demand for rents and the ability of the economy to supply

rents will shift upwards in the short run. Because the aggregate demand of bureaucrats in

such an environment is potentially infinite, the demand for rents will likely exceed the

economy’s ability to supply rents in the short run. As a result, demand will temporarily

exceed supply before establishing a long-run equilibrium. The figure below represents the

impact of a small amount of growth on rent-seeking behavior.

Fig. 2: Demand-Supply for Rents

In this model, the market and economy creates an initial demand for rents R* at

point “a”. The willingness of the firms to pay the rents is in accordance with the demand,

Demand Curve

Rent Rate Supply Curve

RP2

dc

e

b

RP1

P’P”P*

R*

R”

R’

a

Economy’s ability to pay rents

31

which establishes an initial equilibrium. This equilibrium is based on the economy’s

ability to absorb the rent demand. With economic expansion, however, rent-seeking

activity also increases moving to R”, which establishes a short-run equilibrium at point

“b”. Encouraged by this increase in ability to collect rent, the demand increases to R’,

thus establishing a new short-run equilibrium at point “c”. The ability of the economy to

pay rents, however, becomes fixed at point P”. When bureaucrats demand rents beyond

this level, the rent-paying firm experiences negative growth and can potentially refuse to

pay the rent or can exit the market to avoid the rent costs. As a result, there is a surplus of

rent demand that the economy cannot absorb at point “d”. To eliminate the surplus in

demand, rent-seeking behavior abates sufficiently to establish equilibrium between the

economy’s ability for paying the rents and the rent-seeking behavior (King and Handa,

2003). As a result, the economy functions to place some degree of limitation on the rent-

seeking behavior of bureaucrats. In this model, there is real GDP growth only when its

growth rate exceeds the level of increased rent demand. At the same time, the need for

the economy to expand faster than the rate of consumption due to corrupt practices

operates as a disincentive for growth.

From a microeconomic perspective, the individual firm considering a project,

which will result in earnings growth, has to add the additional cost of corruption to the

project. This effectively increases the hurdle rate necessary for the project to achieve

profitability. To be considered viable, the project must provide sufficient future cash

flows to justify both capital investment and also the forecasted costs of corruption. The

32

aggregate decisions occurring on the microeconomic level consequently affect the

economy as a whole.

After considering the theoretical models often used in corruption research, the

supply and demand model coupled with the governmental intervention model offer the

best means to describe the impact of corruption on the economy. The resource diversion

model appears to be more suited to closed or quasi-closed economies where governments

possess a high degree of control over resource allocation. In contrast, governmental

interventions, or the lack of such interventions, can impact the rent demand. At the same

time, normal market forces can operate to impact the supply and demand for rents. As a

result, a synthesis of both the government intervention and the supply and demand

models is necessary to effectively describe corruption’s effects.

3.4 Industry Sector Selection

The criteria for selecting an industry sector for the purposes of this study was to

choose one that was substantially present in all four of the Mercosur nations; it consisted

of regulated and unregulated sectors and was large enough to contain a number of varied

sized firms. The criteria enabled the selected industry to represent the economy as a

whole; the data obtained regarding the sector will indicate the economic impact of

corruption. A large number of industry sectors were considered. The natural resources

and transportation sectors fit some of the criteria, yet are heavily regulated in some

Mercosur nations. Other industries - durable and consumer goods manufacturing - are not

33

well-developed in the two smaller Mercosur nations, Uruguay and Paraguay. The

agricultural and textile industries are subject to a high degree of government protection.

Based on the criteria and the consideration of alternative industries, the study

focused on the computer hardware and software industry sector. This industry is broad

enough to have participants in all four of the Mercosur nations. A large number of small

and medium sized firms competing for local and export market shares compose the

software segment of the industry sector. This is largely due to the low capital intensity

required for software development, which primarily depends on knowledge assets rather

than industrial infrastructure.

Additionally, the software segment consists of both indigenous firms and

subsidiaries of multinational firms. This segment of the industry is not regulated in the

Mercosur nations. A small number of firms that produce completed computers and

peripheral products characterize the computer manufacturing segment of the industry.

These firms are essentially assemblers of component parts, with a supply chain composed

of a large number of smaller firms competing with each other to sell components to the

larger firms. This segment of the industry is partially regulated through various

protections that foster the development of an indigenous computer production industry in

the region. The regulations focus on limiting competition by creating barriers for new

market entrants, particularly for competitors that are foreign subsidiaries. The industry

sector also includes semiconductor manufacturers and providers of networking systems

34

and services. This segment is less developed in the four Mercosur nations and largely

involves subsidiaries of multinational firms with significant expertise in this area.

This chapter provided the research questions, hypothesized relationships, and the

context of the problem. It was proposed that the firms that pay higher bribes have slower

rate of growth. As we study the Mercosur nations, it was proposed that there exists

differences in rent-seeking behavior of bureaucrats at the national and the industry sector

level.

35

Chapter 4

RESEARCH DESIGN

This chapter describes the research design used to test the conceptual research

framework. Here we describe the operationalization of variables, sample selection

process, data collection method, and data analysis plan adopted for testing the hypotheses

proposed.

The goal of a formal research design, which is a road map for conducting

research, is to test the proposed hypotheses or answer the research questions. It provides

answers for the following questions: What techniques will be used to gather data? What

kind of sampling will be used? How will time and cost constraints be dealt? (Cooper and

Emory, 1995); What kind of analysis methods will be adopted to test the proposed

hypotheses? Accordingly, “A research design thus ensures that the study (a) will be

relevant to the problem and (b) will use economical procedures.” (Churchill, 1994)

4.1 Operationalizing Variables for the Test Instruments

The test instruments (see Appendix A for details) for this study consisted of a

survey questionnaire and a structured interview. Both were administered to a sample

population of managers in the Mercosur nations to determine their perceptions of

corruption and its impact on the firms’ growth. As both were based on the literature

review to date and the study’s theoretical assumptions, the test instruments gauged the

microeconomic effects of corruption. There will be some emphasis on the role that

36

corruption plays in the managerial decision-making process with respect to resource

allocation and project hurdle rates. The research design has a microeconomic focus,

although some macroeconomic factors may be considered in the development of the test

instrument.

4.1.1 Economic Growth of Firms

Based on the theoretical construct established for this study, the dependent

variable is the economic growth of specific firms in the Mercosur nations. The dependent

variable is the variable that is most easily measured in the context of this study; it will be

quantified as return on assets (ROA), or similarly, as return on investment (ROI). As a

measure of an organization’s productivity, it is determined by dividing the net earnings of

the organization by the total assets. This can be expressed as a percentage. The

theoretical premise behind the use of ROA to operationalize this variable is that the rate

of ROA growth over a period of time will be higher for firms not dealing with corrupt

practices. It is further based on the assumption that bribes or other types of rents paid by

the organization are masked in the operating expenses of the firm; consequently, the net

earnings of the firm and ROA are reduced.

The selection of the ROA as the means to operationalize the dependent variable

has an inherent difficulty, as other variables can impact the economic growth of specific

firms; intangible factors such as business goals and human resources management are

included. This difficulty is present with all possible measures of a firm’s economic

growth, which is the result of the interaction of a large number of quantitative and

37

qualitative factors. The strategy used to minimize the impact of this difficulty on the

study’s findings will be to aggregate the firms by industry sector and nationality. The

assumption behind the use of this strategy is an aggregate of firms within an industry

segment will behave in a group manner; the individual variations between firms will

cancel themselves, thus creating a representative average. This strategy will also support

one of the research questions that investigate the possible differences in the perceptions

and impact of corruption on different industry segments within the same Mercosur

nation.

4.1.2 The Level of Corruption

A large number of potential variables can indicate the level of corruption in the

environment and can be characterized as rent-seeking behaviors. These include, but are

not limited, to (1) the prevalence of direct payment of cash bribes to public officials to

obtain government services; (2) the direct payment of non-cash benefits to public

officials for the same purpose; (3) barriers to commerce in the form of licenses and

permits granted only to some individuals and firms; (4) the prevalence of cronyism in

either the distribution of governmental benefits or in the granting of licenses and permits;

(5) and direct competition by government owned entities in some industry sectors.

Previous researchers have used different means – such as determining the level of red-

tape encountered in an economy - to operationalize these concepts (Mauro, 1995).

Another method is examining the percentage of bribe rent-seekers in the

governmental apparatus (Coupet, 2003). No standard methodology exists that is used for

38

operationalizing the concepts associated with corruption, which provides a wide degree

of latitude for the present research.

An important independent variable involves the number and amount of the bribes

necessary for the firm to pay as a condition of conducting business in the specific

environment. The number of bribes provides an indication whether corruption is either

centralized or decentralized in the national economy. A larger number of bribes suggest

that corruption is decentralized and, therefore, endemic to the economy; thus, corruption

becomes more difficult to control. A smaller number of bribes suggest that corruption is

both centralized and also controlled by few public officials. The phraseology used in the

test instrument will avoid the use of the word “bribe” to reduce the possibility that

respondents will not be candid due to a feared perception in admitting to wrongdoing

(See Appendix C, Questions 2 and 3).

The variables were based on a four-tiered ordinal scale, which indicated

agreement or disagreement with a stated premise. This methodology used closed-end

questions that facilitated coding of the responses and the ability of the research to

produce inferential statistical comparisons. The questions asked respondents if they

strongly agreed, simply agreed, simply disagreed, or strongly disagreed with a statement.

An additional benefit to the use of this method for gathering data in the area of corruption

was that it did not directly ask the individual respondents whether they participated in the

corrupt practice; instead, it focuses on whether they have observed corrupt practices. This

39

was intended to further increase candor by disassociating the respondent from the

corruption.

The amount of the bribe that the firm must pay as a condition of doing business in

the corrupt environment can theoretically impact the firm’s level of investment. In

practice, a high amount of bribe payments functions as a significant additional operating

cost that does not produce value to the firm. Due to the higher operating costs, individual

projects must produce a higher rate or return or hurdle rate in to be economically viable.

As a result, projects that do not produce value for the firm are generally not pursued,

which limits the firm’s growth. Because the perception of the bribe’s magnitude is a

relative concept contingent on the firm’s’ size and the economic advantage perceived of

particular transactions, the survey questionnaire will not directly inquire to the

respondents’ perception of the magnitude of the bribe-taking. Instead, it will examine

whether the amount of bribes demanded by bureaucrats functions as a factor in the

decision making process. This is essentially a proxy measure for the number of bribes

that the firm pays, which avoids the difficulties associated with obtaining a candid

response.

Question 4 of the survey questionnaire elicited information regarding the impact

of bribes on projects undertaken by the firm (See Appendix C, Question 4). The question

is worded such that it is equally applicable to both large and small firms. It also assumes

that bureaucrats’ rent-seeking behaviors will be commensurate with the position of the

firm; the bribe-taker increase or decrease the amount demanded in accordance with the

40

financial position of the firm. As a result, larger firms will be subject to higher demands

in terms of the amount; however, the impact on the decision to continue with a project

will be relatively the same as in the case of smaller firms with less demand.

Question 5 of the survey questionnaire was intended to elicit information

regarding the degree that a response to rent-seeking behavior is entrenched in corporate

culture (See Appendix C, Question 5). The theoretical assumption is that in corrupt

environments, the firm adopts a planning position where the payment of bribes or other

types of gratuities is a normal cost of doing business and is fully integrated into the

project planning phase.

Question 6 of the survey questionnaire elicited information regarding the

perceived importance of the payment of bribes to the competitive positioning of the firm

(See Appendix C, Question 6). In a corrupt environment, we see a strong potential for

firms or individuals, who are well-connected politically and willing to bribe officials, that

will obtain an unfair competitive advantage over rival firms. To some degree, this relates

to the extent of corruption in the general environment. Theoretically, in a corruption-free

open market economy, competitive advantage depends on firm-specific factors such as

core competencies and the ability to deploy those competencies in the market. In a

corrupt environment, however, the corruption becomes an additional factor in

determining competitive advantage. In effect, it can erect an artificial barrier to market

entry for firms unwilling to meet the required price for doing business in a corrupt

environment.

41

The survey questionnaire also contained a question for determining if the

respondents perceived that corruption hampered their ability to fully engage in trade with

other Mercosur nations, which is the intent of the Mercosur trading arrangement (See

Appendix C, Question 7). Although the Mercosur nations have a trading agreement that

ostensibly removes barriers to commerce, the potential exists for officials in the various

member nations to extract rents from firms or individuals from other Mercosur nations.

This is done as a condition of doing business in the bureaucrat’s home nation. In theory,

the bureaucrat collecting the bribe faces a lower degree of political risk because the

payment originates outside the country; therefore, it does not directly affect the local

constituency. At the same time, a requirement to pay bribes both in the home country and

in other nations can undermine the benefits of the Mercosur agreement to the firm by

increasing its costs. As a result, the perception that the level of corruption in other

Mercosur nations is high enough to impede trade could potentially reduce the firm’s

growth rate.

The survey questionnaire directly inquired if there was a perceived difference in

the amounts of bribes charged in both the home nation and other Mercosur nations (See

Appendix C, Question 8). The purpose of this question was to determine the perceived

level of the barrier to trade presented by corruption. The theoretical assumption is that a

relatively high perception of corruption in another nation, when compared to the home

nation, will result in less trade and a lower growth rate for the firm. In addition, if the

level of corruption is perceived as lower in another Mercosur nation when compared to

42

the home country, then a firm could potentially shift resources to that nation to take

advantage of lower business cost.

4.2 Pilot Study

A pilot study (see Appendix A for details) was conducted on the data collected

during the course of the summer of 2004 in the Mercosur nations. The purpose of the

pilot study was to determine if the survey test instrument produced predictive and reliable

information. By their nature, pilot studies involve a relatively small population; the

population is not necessarily representative of the larger study population. The purpose of

the pilot study is to examine the reliability and validity of the test instrument and not to

produce findings that may be generalized to the larger population. The data obtained

during the pilot study, however, was incorporated into the study due to the determination

following the pilot study that the survey questionnaire test instrument was suitable for

gathering data and was also reasonably predictive.

The data collection process for the pilot study that involved chain referrals and a

high level of in-person contact with mangers in the computer industry produced 72

completed survey test questionnaires. Because the survey questionnaire uses closed-

ended questions, it provides a natural structure for the coding frame of the data. Various

frames were developed for the pilot test based on the internal data provided by the survey

questionnaire; this included frames based on the nation of origin of the respondents and

frames based on the segment of the computer industry of the respondents. Because of the

small number of respondents in the pilot study, certain segments of the industry were

43

underrepresented and were not used for this initial stage of analysis. There were sufficient

numbers to conduct an analysis based on the four Mercosur nations, although there were

relatively few respondents from Uruguay and Paraguay as expected. The external data,

which was necessary to support the analysis, was the change in ROI of the firms with

managers participating in the study, with the information necessary to determine ROI

obtained from public sources. The data was further analyzed to establish a three-year

average percentage change in ROI.

Data analysis was accomplished by regression analysis on the coding frame based

on total results; it was not performed on the coding frame based on national differences

due to the relatively small numbers of respondents from Uruguay and Paraguay. The

findings of the initial regression analysis for the pilot study tended to support the

hypothesis of the study - higher levels of corruption as determined by managers’

perceptions of the level of corruption tends to depress the financial performance of firms.

This suggested that the survey questionnaire would be predictive and would be suitable

for use in the larger study.

The pilot test also revealed a potential difficulty with serial correlation in the

sample methodology; the errors could be correlated across nations contemporaneously.

This results in errors in county i at time t appearing to be correlated to errors in country

j at time t , with the errors tending to be the result of the interdependence of the

countries. This is particularly the case in the situation of the Mercosur nations that tend to

have a higher degree of interdependence than nations that are not geographically,

44

culturally, and economically linked. Errors also tend to be heteroscedastic, as they have

differing variances across different nations. This can produce higher values for some

variables that tend to be less restricted in the national political, social, and economic

system. The impact of the heteroscedastic effect can come from the various scales of the

national economies; larger economies such as Brazil have the potential to have a number

of significant differences in factors such as unemployment rates when compared to the

nations with smaller economies.

4.3 Identification of the Sample Population

The summer research of 2004 conducted in the Mercosur nations enabled the

development of a clearer definition of the sample population. The study focuses on

managers in the various segments of the computer industry in the four Mercosur nations.

An ideal sample population would include a balanced number of representatives from

each of the four nations, from the firms in the various segments of the computer industry,

and from firms of variable size. A large number of respondents are necessary to

accomplish this. A sample size, which is too small, is not sufficiently representative; a

sample that is too large wastes time and resources without achieving a significantly

greater level of accuracy. For the present study, the basis of determining the optimal size

of the sample population is a confidence level of 95% with a confidence interval of 5.

These parameters indicate that the findings of the study are likely to be within 5 units

95% of the time. A population of unknown size characterized the study because it is not

possible to determine with any accuracy the total size of the computer industry in the

Mercosur nations.

45

The Central Limit Theorem forms the basis for determining the size of a sampling

to achieve the intended confidence interval and confidence level when the total size of the

population is unknown. This theorem contends that the repeated sampling of a population

produces an average of the tested attribute representing the population as a whole. In this

approach, the values obtained by the sampling are distributed around the true value in a

range of plus or minus 5 intervals 95% of the time. The formula for determining the

sample size is( )2SE

pqn = ; n is the sample size, p is the proportion of the population

possessing the attribute, q is p−1 , and SE is the standard error. At the 95% confidence

level and the confidence interval of 5, the SE is .05/1.96 = .02551. The confidence

interval is expressed in the form of a hundredth decimal and is the numerator; the 95%

confidence is a constant of 1.96 and is the denominator. This produces an estimate of the

standard error that will be found with a sampling using this confidence level and

confidence interval. In the case of the current research, the proportion of the population

possessing the outcome attribute is unknown. In these types of situations, we select p at

.5, because we assume equal numbers of the population possess the attribute and do not

possess the attribute. This is the method used with large populations, such as the

population in the current study in which there is an equal chance that a respondent will or

will not possess the attribute. These assumptions result in the following substitutions:

( )( ) ( )

384000651./25.

02551./5.15. 2

2

==

−=

=

nnn

SEpqn

46

This indicates that the optimal sample size for the study is 384. While an increase

in confidence level or a decrease in confidence interval would produce greater accuracy

in results, it would increase the size of the sampling to a level beyond the budgetary and

time constraints of the present study. Establishing this number for the size of the sample

provides guidelines for the amount of data gathering activity that has to occur on a

regular basis to achieve the desired sampling size by the conclusion of the data gathering

phase of the study.

4.4 Sample Selection Process and Data Collection

While the original sampling strategy was envisioned as a fully random process in

which every member of the total population had an equal and independent chance of

being included in the sample population, difficulties with accessing the study population

resulted in a modification of the sampling strategy. During the course of the summer

research, it became apparent that access to the sample population by an outsider to the

industry would be difficult, particularly in consideration of the sensitive nature of the

study focusing on corruption in the business environment. This led to the development of

a chain referral sampling strategy where respondents, who had become members of the

sample population, identified members of the total population. This type of referral

network diminished the independence of the sampling by encouraging members of

population to participate based on the recommendation of the individual or organization

providing the referral. This approach to sampling also increased the possibility that self-

selection bias skews the findings. Self-selection bias under these circumstances operates

by selecting a larger group of respondents who are members of a particular organization

47

such as the software association used as basis for referral in Argentina. Additionally, it

tends to select a group of respondents with a relationship with a firm or an organization

making the referral and excluding respondents lacking a relationship. The potential for

various types of biases was addressed through the development of a variation in the

sampling strategy. This resulted in some of the sampling conducted through a random

process that identified members of the industry and randomly sought participation in the

study.

The developed random sampling strategy, focused on establishing email contact

with firms in the computer industry in the Mercosur nations. These firms were recognized

by internet searches that identified firms with websites and identified portals providing

links to computer firms in the targeted geographic area. An email introduction, which

explained the nature of the study and asked for the participation of managers in filling out

the survey questionnaire, approached the managers in these firms. In cases where the

website listed the direct email addresses of managers at the firm, the introductory

information was addressed directly to the individual managers. Also, another random

strategy adopted, was to contact either by telephone or by mail firms identified through

physical business directories, which were collected for each Mercosur nation during the

summer of 2004 and winter break of 2005, when the researcher traveled to the Mercosur

nations. These processes increased the degree of randomization of the sampling process

by obtaining a significant number of responses not based on the referral method.

48

The random internet sampling strategy, however, had its own set of issues that

could potentially introduce bias into the sampling process. Because the firms were

identified based on websites, the sampling strategy excluded those firms that did not

maintain a website. Due to the nature of the computer industry in which participating

firms leverage technology and view a website as a condition of doing business, this risk

was not deemed significant. Not all firms that maintain websites are easily found by

internet search engines, however, with newer websites and those using flash technology

often excluded from search results. Additionally, the quality of the search engine findings

is contingent on the terms used for the search, which could result in the introduction of

researcher bias into the selection process. This occurs when the researchers pre-conceived

concepts regarding the methods to conduct a search to identify the sample population

results in the selection of only a certain type of firm that has characteristics that conform

to the researcher’s concepts. These factors suggest a significant possibility that some

firms would have been overlooked in the selection process.

In the initial execution of this strategy during the course of the research, the

sectors of computer supply and networking were not well represented. This was initially

attributed to the nature of the search parameters used on the internet. This fact proved to

be right after an alteration of the search parameters, produced a significant increase in the

representation of these sectors. Note that the computer supply segment of the industry

was also poorly represented during the pilot study. However, the researcher chose, at that

time, to decide its viability as a category for the industry after the conclusion of the data-

gathering period. Based on the success obtained after the alteration of the search

49

parameters described above, the researcher concluded that not necessary to eliminate

these sectors as a category for the industry.

Another potential limitation in the use of random solicitation via the internet is the

tendency of recipients of unsolicited email to delete the email without reading it or to

assume that the contents of the email are in some way deceptive. The strategy adopted to

minimize the impact of these possibilities was contacting the non-respondent firms by

telephone and regular mail to introduce the study through another communications

medium. In the majority of cases, the website also contained either the telephone number

or the address of the firm, thus supporting the use of an alternative means of contact. The

general strategy was to approach firms that do not respond to email solicitation by regular

mail approximately 10 days after the initial email contact. Telephone contact with these

firms occurred during the winter break of 2005 when the researcher traveled to the

Mercosur nations.

The general data collection strategy for individuals who have agreed to participate

in the study either as the result of a referral or a random solicitation by email was to send

the survey questionnaire by email immediately upon receiving the respondent’s

agreement to participate. If the completed survey questionnaire was not returned within a

week of dispatch, a follow-up reminder email was sent. There were a small percentage of

individuals that agreed to participate in the study but did not return completed survey

questionnaires even after the follow-up reminder. Given the feasibility of each case at the

50

time, those individuals were contacted either by telephone or by mail during the winter

break.

While the email random solicitation process was highly effective in the initial

weeks after implementation in increasing the number of respondents, it eventually

became evident that the method was producing a diminishing rate of returns. This was

due to the finite number of firms that could be identified through the methodology and

the relatively high rate of non-response to the solicitation request. The sole reliance on

this method would create some uncertainty in the ability to reach the optimal number of

participants in the study. This led to a resumption of the referral method of solicitation

with individuals returning completed survey questionnaires asked to provide referrals to

managers from other firms. They were also asked if their names could be mentioned in

the solicitation materials as the referring party. The resumption of the use of the referral

method to identify potential participants increased the rate of agreement to participation.

Based on this experience with diminishing rates of return, a significant number of

individuals were randomly contacted by means of unsolicited email did not read the

email or did not respond due to concerns regarding the legitimacy of the study. When the

referral method was used, the mention of the referring party in the solicitation materials

helped to establish credibility for the study. In the coding process, a notation indicating

whether the completed survey questionnaire was the result of a referral or random direct

solicitation was developed. This will allow the identification of the percentages of the

two types of data in the final analysis. There is no guarantee, however, that data identified

51

as obtained from random solicitation was not subject to indirect referral through

communication between respondents that the researcher was not aware.

Despite the inherent flaws in the sample selection strategies, the referral and

random internet selection methods were considered the best means to approach the study

population in order to obtain a viable sample. The random selection aspects of the

internet identification process offset the deficiency in the referral method of dependency

on an industry group with existing relationships. The referral method functioned as an

alternative method to identify respondents, offsetting some of the deficiencies in the

internet selection method of overlooking segments of the total population. Due to these

considerations, the sampling error that remained in the study is considered minimal and

the lowest possible level considering the difficulties associated with data collection in an

international environment.

An additional issue in the sampling strategy is the disproportionate size of the

computer industry in Brazil and Argentina when compared to Uruguay and Paraguay. In

the pilot study, only 18% of the respondents were from Paraguay and Uruguay, despite an

effort during the summer research period to collect data specifically from these two

nations. This raised the possibility that the members of the sample population from these

two nations were not representative, and that pooling of the data would result in the

perceptions of corruption in Brazil and Argentina controlling the outcome of the study. It

further suggested at the time that too high a representation from Uruguay and Paraguay

could disproportionately influence the findings from the two larger nations. However,

52

this issue was resolved after selecting a sampling strategy specifically designed to deal

with the issue of disproportionate geographic representation in the sampling.

A sampling strategy considered for dealing with the issue of disproportionate

geographic representation in the sampling involved sampling from the four Mercosur

nations in proportion to the relative size of the nation’s GDP. Table 5 presents the total

GDP of the Mercosur nations and the relative contribution of each member nation in

percentage terms.

Table 4.1: Mercosur Nation GDP

Brazil Paraguay Uruguay Argentina GDP Total 500 7.7 11.2 432 950.9 52.6% 0.8% 1.2% 45.4%

While this sampling strategy would support the pooled analysis of the data in

order to provide representative findings for the Mercosur nations as a whole, the number

of respondents from Paraguay and Uruguay should be relatively small. As a result, the

sampling would not produce enough data to support statistical significance for the

findings from these two nations when considered separately from the findings for the

Mercosur nations as a whole.

The sampling strategy that dealt with this problem focused on the use of

disproportionate stratified sampling, which involved drawing a disproportionate number

of samples from Paraguay and Uruguay when compared to the samples from Brazil and

53

Argentina. This allowed for a statistically meaningful evaluation of data when Paraguay

and Uruguay are considered separately. Nonetheless, disproportionate stratified samples

tend to have standard errors that are less precise than proportionate stratified samples of

the same population. When compared to simple random samples, disproportionate

stratified samples can be either more or less precise, depending on the factors that

influence the error in the various strata. A greater degree of precision tends to occur when

the means of the variable of interest are heterogeneous in the strata. As such, this

sampling method presumes that the means of the strata will be heterogeneous, and the

data produced by the method will not be compromised by an inappropriate sampling

strategy.

The sampling strategy was time consuming, although many aspects of the process

were automated. Each of the firms, which were solicited for participation in the study,

had to be individually identified and recorded in a master file to prevent duplication of

solicitation. The solicitation materials were pro forma, but they were somewhat modified

to be specific to the firm or manager being approached. Regular mail subsequently

contacted firms that did not respond to the email solicitation. A record was made of the

date that the solicitation materials are sent. When an individual agreed to participate, the

survey questionnaire was automatically sent with the date of emailing noted. If the

completed survey questionnaire was not returned within the estimated period, the

reminder was automatically sent. A final list of individuals who had agreed to participate,

yet had not completed the survey questionnaire, was prepared at the end of the fall

quarter of 2004 to support contact by the researcher during the winter break of 2005.

54

4.5 Data Analysis Plan

The researcher chose for the use of pooled analysis to analyze the data collected.

Pooled time series cross-sectional analysis (TSCS) combines time series for several

cross-sections that could be repeated observations over time or fixed units such as

nations. This methodology allows the use of more than one case in predicting economic

phenomenon. In the present study, the time series is 1 because the data was gathered at a

single point in time; the number of spatial units is 4, which corresponds to the number of

Mercosur nations. This produces a pooled array of cross-sectional data of XN × or

14× . The pooled array can also be used with factors such as firm size or segment in the

industry.

This produces the generic pooled linear regression equation that is based on

ordinary least squares of the following:

ukitkk

u eXY ++= ∑=

ββ2

1

In this formula, i is the cross-sectional unit N ; t is the temporal unit T ; K is a

specific explanatory variable resulting in uY as the dependent variable and uX as the

independent variable for unit i and time t . ue is random error, 1β is the intercept, kβ is

the slope parameters. The TSCS model is based on the assumptions that the error term

has a mean of zero, the error term has a constant variance over all observations and the

error terms corresponding to different points in time are not correlated. Because the

55

observations are taken at a single point of time in this study, the third assumption does

not apply. The error term functional measures the accuracy of the ordinary least squares

method. If the standard error is small, then all of the sample estimates based on the

sample size tend to be similar and considered representative of the population. If the error

term is large, however, the statistics fail to represent the population.

For the ordinary least squares method to produce optimal results, the errors must

be homoscedastic and independent of each other. This requirement indicates that the

TSCS approach could violate the standard assumptions of the ordinary least squares

method, when there is significant heteroscedasticity due to inherent factors in the

econometric model or the data collection process. In effect, the error terms would violate

the basic assumptions that they have a constant variance over all observations, and that

they have a mean of zero. Thus, when errors are heteroscedastic, they have differing

variances across different nations, which can produce higher values for some variables

that tend to be less restricted in the national political, social, and economic system. An

example of the heteroscedastic effect comes from the scale of the national economy in

Brazil when compared to Paraguay, with factors such as the flows of workers in and out

of employment tending to be higher in nations with large and diverse economies.

Furthermore, errors can be correlated across nations contemporaneously. This results in

errors in country i at time t appearing to correlate to errors in country j at time t , with

the errors tending to be the result of the interdependence of the countries. This is

particularly the case in the situation of the Mercosur nations that tend to have a higher

56

degree of interdependence than nations that are not geographically, culturally, and

economically linked.

When there is a heteroscedastic situation, the standard errors of the estimates are

biased because they do not have a mean of zero and a constant variance over all

observations. As a result, the usual t statistics, F statistics, and other outputs of the

ordinary least squares method does not produce a meaningful basis to develop inferences.

This issue can be resolved using tests for heteroscedasticity that provide a better estimate

of the error occurring at different locations or points in time. Typically, tests of

heteroscedasticity should test the null hypothesis regarding equal variance against some

specific alternative heteroscedasticity specification. The Breusch-Pagan test determines

any linear forms of heteroscedasticity. This test is based on a regression model

exy += β' where ( ) ( )tzfeVar '2 γσ == . The test of the null hypothesis occurs at

0=γ for arbitrary smooth functions f . Some concern remains, however, that the

Breusch-Pagan test is asymptotically equivalent to a certain F test and may not be a

viable indication of actual linear heteroscedasticity. For the purposes of the present study,

however, the Breusch-Pagan test provides adequate parameters to determine linear

heteroscedasticity. The White Test determines if there are non-linearities by using

squares and cross products of all of the x’s. This is based on the use of a

heteroscedasticity consistent covariance matrix estimator that permits asymptotically

correct inference on β when there is heteroscedasticity of an unknown form. The White

test is generally viable; however, in some situations it can be significantly biased with

finite samples; the level of bias decreases as the sample size increases.

57

A potential solution to this issue is to create an estimate of the variance-

covariance matrix of the errors rather than attempt to identify the matrix, which is

generally designated by Ω . This provides a coefficient estimator β . This approach deals

with error complications by specifying a model for heteroscedasticity and a model for

contemporaneous correlation. This heteroscedasticity correction is in the form of ( )2iteE

and the contemporaneous correlation is in the form of ( )jtit eeE . In some situations, the

error process has a large number of parameters, which results in estimates of standard

errors to understate their actual level of variability. Some debate regarding the

appropriateness of this method for organizing econometric data exists, but it remains

widely used despite the potential of standard error inflation that can result in a flawed

determination of significance.

We generally refer to the corrected standard error as a robust standard error. The

robust standard errors have asymptotic justifications; therefore, they are not valid for

small sample sizes. Additionally, the robust standard error cannot cope with situations

where the number of outliers exceeds the ability of the estimation method to compensate.

The robust standard error becomes increasingly unreliable as heteroscedasticity increases.

Due to the magnitude of this study, the size of the sample should not present a great

difficulty for an accurate computation of the robust standard error. The number of outliers

will likely not be beyond the capacity of a traditional heteroscedasticity method - the

Breusch-Pagan test - to identify and compensate.

58

The number of coding possibilities in the present study creates a difficulty with

developing a more accurate method of the analysis of the data and for the determination

of heteroscedasticity. Coding is based on the structure of the survey questionnaire; as a

result, it is possible to code the responses of the sample population in accordance with the

respondent’s nation or origin and segment of the computer industry from data

endogenous to the survey questionnaire. Coding the data based on size of the firm and

ROI from data exogenous to the survey questionnaire is possible. These coding

possibilities are spatial and not temporal factors, which establishes a situation in which

the number of spatial factors N are greater than the number of temporal factors T, or

TN > . Thus, we can have an event where there is cross-sectional dominance, where

there are more spatial than temporal units.

The model used for analysis may suffer from heteroscedasticity due to country-

and-industry effects. To test the validity of this assumption, a preliminary test of

significance will determine the level of equality of the coefficients. The outcome of this

test will be the basis for the decision to pool. The question, which will be addressed by

this process, is whether to estimate the models separately for different cross-section units

or to estimate the model by pooling the entire data set. The TSCS analysis represents the

combined average partial effect for time and space, yet does not yield information

regarding the relative contribution of the two dimensions to its value. In the study’s

context, it does not address whether the variation, if any, is due to cross-country

differences or cross-industry sector differences.

59

Chapter 5

DATA ANALYSIS, RESULTS & DISCUSSION

This chapter covers the testing and results of the econometric model. The chapter

is divided into nine sections. The first section deals with the sample description covering

the model’s characteristics. The second section deals with the reliability of scale used to

measure the corruption. The third deals with the factor analysis. Sections four, five, and

six deal with testing for heteroscedasticity, endogeneity, and spatial autocorrelation,

respectively. Section seven delves into the results of regression and ANOVA to test the

hypotheses. Section eight deals with the analysis of the structured interviews. Finally, in

section nine we provide the discussion on the results obtained.

5.1 Sample Description

We have a sample of 560 respondents across all the four Mercosur nations and

seven industry sectors. With respect to nation, distribution of respondents is shown in

table 5.1. The distribution of respondents across the seven sectors of computer industry is

shown in table 5.2.

Table 5.1: Distribution of respondents across the nations

Nation Argentina Uruguay Paraguay Brazil Total Number of respondents 254 37 95 174 560Percentage 45.36 6.61 16.96 31.07 100

60

Table 5.2: Distribution of respondents across the seven sectors of computer industry

Industry Sector Software Comp_man Com_supp Semc_man Networking Peripherals Others

Total

Number of respondents 82 72 90 83 74 75 84 560Percentage 14.64 12.86 16.07 14.82 13.21 13.39 15.00 100

ROI is the dependent variable in this study; we try to analyze the impact of the

corruption level on the economic growth, including the ROI of the firms in Mercosur

nations for the computer industry. Tables 5.3 and 5.4 show the mean and standard

deviation of ROI of firms in the four Mercosur nations and in the seven industry sectors.

Table 5.3 Mean and Standard Deviation of ROI of Firms in Four Mercosur Nations

Paraguay Argentina Brazil Uruguay Mean -3.60 1.00 5.25 9.09 Std. Dev. 2.18 4.65 3.70 0.88

Table 5.4 Mean and Standard Deviation of ROI of Firms in Different Industry Sectors

Software Comp_man Com_supp Semc_man Networking Peripherals Others Mean 2.18 2.62 2.07 2.16 2.03 1.71 1.78Std. Dev. 5.53 5.33 5.23 5.08 4.84 5.26 5.38

5.2 Reliability of Scale Measures

The scale used to measure the level of corruption is tested for the reliability

analysis using Cronbach’s alpha. Cronbach’s alpha is a model of internal consistency,

based on average inter-item correlation. The Cronbach’s alpha should be greater than

61

0.60 to use the scale for research purpose (Nunnally, 1978). The results of the reliability

test are reported in Table 5.5.

Table 5.5 Reliability of scale measures

Number of items Cronbach’s Alpha

Level of Corruption 7 0.87

5.3 Factor Analysis

The inter-item correlations of scale items used to measure the level of corruption

are shown in table 5.6.

Table 5.6: Inter-item correlations

Q_2 Q_3 Q_4 Q_5 Q_6 Q_7 Q_8 1 .786(**) .786(**) .779(**) .786(**) .766(**) -.107(*). .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .012

Q_2

560 560 560 560 560 560 560.786(**) 1 .790(**) .756(**) .766(**) .765(**) -.118(**)

.000 . .000 .000 .000 .000 .005

Q_3

560 560 560 560 560 560 560.786(**) .790(**) 1 .759(**) .777(**) .776(**) -.121(**)

.000 .000 . .000 .000 .000 .004

Q_4

560 560 560 560 560 560 560.779(**) .756(**) .759(**) 1 .762(**) .751(**) -.123(**)

.000 .000 .000 . .000 .000 .003

Q_5

560 560 560 560 560 560 560.786(**) .766(**) .777(**) .762(**) 1 .780(**) -.122(**)

.000 .000 .000 .000 . .000 .004

Q_6

560 560 560 560 560 560 560.766(**) .765(**) .776(**) .751(**) .780(**) 1 -.121(**)

.000 .000 .000 .000 .000 . .004

Q_7

560 560 560 560 560 560 560-.107(*) -.118(**) -.121(**) -.123(**) -.122(**) -.121(**) 1

.012 .005 .004 .003 .004 .004 .

Q_8

560 560 560 560 560 560 560** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed). * Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed).

62

As we can see from Table 5.6, the first six items of the scale are highly and

significantly correlated to each other. The last item, though not highly correlated with

other items of the scale, does have significant correlations.. This suggests that there must

be some underlying variable to which these items are indicating; therefore, we perform

the factor analysis. Table 5.7 shows the results of factor analysis.

Table 5.7: Factor Analysis Communalities

Initial ExtractionQ_2 1.000 .823Q_3 1.000 .810Q_4 1.000 .818Q_5 1.000 .791Q_6 1.000 .813Q_7 1.000 .801Q_8 1.000 .027

Extraction Method: Principal Component Analysis.

Total Variance Explained

Initial Eigenvalues Extraction Sums of Squared

Loadings Component Total

% of Variance

Cumulative % Total

% of Variance

Cumulative %

1 4.884 69.766 69.766 4.884 69.766 69.7662 .979 13.980 83.745 3 .258 3.680 87.425 4 .246 3.514 90.939 5 .224 3.198 94.137 6 .209 2.981 97.119 7 .202 2.881 100.000

Extraction Method: Principal Component Analysis.

63

Component Matrix(a)

Component 1 Q_2 .907Q_3 .900Q_4 .905Q_5 .889Q_6 .902Q_7 .895Q_8 -.165

Extraction Method: Principal Component Analysis. a 1 components extracted.

The results of the factor analysis suggest that there exists a common underlying

construct onto which the seven items of the scale load. In other words, the scale items

used to measure the perception level of the level of corruption indicate one construct

called the Corruption Level. For further analysis, we use the factor scores (Also see the

correlation between different variables provided in Appendix B).

5.4 Testing for Heteroscedasticity

As discussed earlier - that we are analyzing the impact of corruption across

nations and across industries - we must test the heteroscedasticity of the data. Here we

provide the results of the White’s test performed on the dataset. Unlike the other tests, the

White’s general heteroscedasticity test does not rely on the assumption like normal

distribution, and it is fairly easy to implement (Gujarati, 2003).

We initially performed the following regression to obtain the residuals:

iikikk

jijj

i uXXXY ++++= ∑∑ 331 ββββ

64

Where iY = ROI (dependent variable)

jiX = Dummy variables for country (independent variables)

j = Brazil, Argentina, and Uruguay

Note that Paraguay is used as the base country.

kiX = Dummy variables for industry sectors (independent variables)

k = All the industry sectors except software

Note that Software is used as the base industry sector.

iX 3 = Corruption Level (Independent variable)

iu = Residuals

Once we estimate the residuals, the auxiliary regression as shown in the following

equation is performed:

∑∑∑∑

∑∑∑∑+++

+++++=

jjiki

kkiki

k jjiki

ikikk

jij

jkikk

jij

ji

XXXXXX

XXXXXhatu

13

134

32

322

12)(

ααα

αααααα

As we have nine dummy variables, the squares of these are omitted from the final

auxiliary regression because these are the same as the original variables, which result in a

perfect correlation between the two. Regression also resulted in the removal of cross

products amongst country dummy variables and industry sector dummy variables, as

these products are zero. The results obtained are as shown below in table 5.8 (variables

VAR00001 to VAR00045 are cross products between independent variables and the

cross products not shown are the ones removed from the model as mentioned above).

65

Table 5.8: Test for Heteroscedasticity

Model Summary

Model R R

Square

Adjusted R

Square

Std. Error of the

Estimate 1 .262(a) .069 .001 2.93677

a Predictors: (Constant), VAR00045, VAR00039, VAR00042, VAR00035, VAR00044, VAR00030, VAR00006, VAR00005, OTHERS, CORR_SQR, VAR00003, VAR00022, VAR00004, VAR00007, VAR00021, VAR00019, VAR00020, VAR00011, VAR00013, VAR00012, VAR00018, VAR00014, VAR00023, VAR00015, VAR00016, VAR00009, VAR00017, BRAZIL, NETWORKI, SEMC_MAN, VAR00024, VAR00008, PERIPH, COM_SUPP, COM_MAN, ARGENTINA, Corruption Level , PARAGUAY

ANOVA(b)

Model Sum of Squares df

Mean Square F Sig.

Regression 331.780 38 8.731 1.012 .452(a)Residual 4493.418 521 8.625

1 Total 4825.198 559

a Predictors: (Constant), VAR00045, VAR00039, VAR00042, VAR00035, VAR00044, VAR00030, VAR00006, VAR00005, OTHERS, CORR_SQR, VAR00003, VAR00022, VAR00004, VAR00007, VAR00021, VAR00019, VAR00020, VAR00011, VAR00013, VAR00012, VAR00018, VAR00014, VAR00023, VAR00015, VAR00016, VAR00009, VAR00017, BRAZIL, NETWORKI, SEMC_MAN, VAR00024, VAR00008, PERIPH, COM_SUPP, COM_MAN, ARGENTINA, Corruption Level , PARAGUAY b Dependent Variable: RES_SQR

66

Coefficients(a)

Unstandardized Coefficients

Standardized Coefficients

Model B Std. Error Beta t Sig. (Constant) 1.721 1.366 1.260 .208ARGENTINA .477 1.449 .081 .329 .742BRAZIL -.194 1.593 -.031 -.122 .903URUGUAY -9.055 9.139 -.766 -.991 .322COM_MAN .674 1.528 .077 .441 .659COM_SUPP .807 1.432 .101 .564 .573SEMC_MAN .698 1.373 .084 .508 .612NETWORKI .922 1.374 .106 .671 .503PERIPH -.334 1.425 -.039 -.234 .815OTHERS .558 1.471 .068 .379 .705Corruption Level .026 .905 .009 .029 .977

CORR_SQR -.283 .203 -.081 -1.396 .163VAR00003 .187 1.637 .014 .114 .909VAR00004 .908 1.514 .081 .600 .549VAR00005 -.618 1.500 -.051 -.412 .680VAR00006 -.767 1.543 -.055 -.497 .619VAR00007 -.050 1.507 -.004 -.033 .974VAR00008 -.869 1.544 -.081 -.563 .574VAR00009 -.144 .805 -.030 -.179 .858VAR00011 .205 1.877 .015 .109 .913VAR00012 .266 1.796 .020 .148 .883VAR00013 .027 1.777 .002 .015 .988VAR00014 -1.146 1.817 -.079 -.631 .529VAR00015 .850 1.857 .060 .458 .647VAR00016 -.776 1.882 -.048 -.412 .680VAR00017 -.461 .943 -.077 -.488 .625VAR00018 -1.528 2.648 -.058 -.577 .564VAR00019 -.225 2.791 -.007 -.081 .936VAR00020 -.402 2.813 -.013 -.143 .886VAR00021 -1.259 2.896 -.036 -.435 .664VAR00022 -.106 3.040 -.003 -.035 .972VAR00023 -1.322 2.649 -.053 -.499 .618VAR00024 -7.181 6.511 -.794 -1.103 .271VAR00030 .060 .591 .007 .101 .920VAR00035 .728 .574 .098 1.269 .205VAR00039 .419 .613 .051 .683 .495VAR00042 -.188 .646 -.023 -.291 .771VAR00044 .388 .608 .051 .637 .524

1

VAR00045 -.304 .587 -.039 -.519 .604a Dependent Variable: RES_SQR

67

According to White’s test under the null hypothesis that there is no

heteroscedasticity, the sample size times the R2 obtained from the auxiliary regression

asymptotically follows the chi-square distribution with degrees of freedom equal to the

number of regressors in the auxiliary regression. In this case, we have R2 = 0.069 and

degrees of freedom are 38; therefore, n* R2 = 560*0.069 = 38.64. The 5% critical chi-

square value for 38 degree of freedoms is 53.38 and at 10% it is 49.51. Also, none of the

coefficients of the variables in auxiliary regression are significant. We conclude that there

is no heteroscedasticity, and we can safely pool the data for further analysis.

5.5 Testing for Endogeneity

To test the endogeneity we first run the following regression:

ikikk

jijj

i uXXZ +++= ∑∑ δδδ1

Where iZ = Corruption Level (dependent variable)

jiX = Dummy variables for country (independent variables)

j = Brazil, Argentina, and Uruguay

Note that Paraguay is used as the base country.

kiX = Dummy variables for industry sectors (independent variables)

k = All the industry sectors except software

Note that Software is used as the base industry sector.

iu = Residuals

68

Once we estimate the residuals, then the auxiliary regression as shown in the

following equation is performed:

iii Xhatu εωω ++= 21)(

iX = Corruption Level (Independent variable)

The results are as shown in table 5.9.

Table 5.9: Test for Endogeneity

Variables Entered/Removed(b)

Model Variables Entered

Variables Removed Method

1

Corruption Level,

Residual(a). Enter

a All requested variables entered. b Dependent Variable: ROI

Model Summary

Model R R

Square

Adjusted R

Square

Std. Error of the

Estimate 1 .962(a) .925 .924 1.43522 a Predictors: (Constant), Corruption Level , Residual

ANOVA(b)

Model Sum of Squares df

Mean Square F Sig.

Regression 14099.549 2 7049.774 3422.44

1 .000(a)

Residual 1147.346 557 2.060

1

Total 15246.895 559

a Predictors: (Constant), Corruption Level , Residual b Dependent Variable: ROI

69

Coefficients(a)

Model Unstandardized

Coefficients Standardized Coefficients t Sig.

B Std.

Error Beta (Constant) 2.072 .061 34.166 .000Residual .627 .123 .090 5.117 .000

1

Corruption Level -5.368 .092 -1.028 -

58.181 .000

a Dependent Variable: ROI The results show that the coefficient of residual in auxiliary regression is significantly

different from zero. According Durbin-Wu-Hausman test, we have endogeneity.

5.6 Testing for Spatial Autocorrelation

As pointed out earlier, we need to test for spatial correlation across nations and

industry sectors. First, we test across nations and the following regression is used to get

the residual values:

ikikk

ii uXXZ +++= ∑ δδδ 21

kiX = Dummy variables for industry sectors (independent variables)

k = All the industry sectors except software

Note that Software is used as the base industry sector.

iX = Corruption Level

iu = Residuals

In the next step, we calculate the mean values of residuals for respective countries. The

mean values are as shown in table 5.10

70

Table 5.10: Mean Value of Residuals

Paraguay Argentina Brazil Uruguay Mean -0.3891 -0.0581 0.1891 0.5087

Next we calculate Moran’s I according to the following formula (Cliff and Ord, 1973;

Odland, 1988):

XX i − = iu residual for country i

XX j − = ju residual for country j, where i≠j

jiW , = weights assigned to pair of countries i and j. In this, all weights are 1 as the

countries are not only physically close but also economically well integrated.

N = 4 the number of countries

We get value of I = -0.28675. The expected value of Moran’s I is calculated as follows.

)1/(1)( −−= NIE = -0.3333

Then we calculate the standard error of )(IE by the following formula:

In our case )( IES = 0.47140. We then calculate )(IZ by the following formula and get the

value of 0.0988. Using t-distribution with DOF as 3, at 5 % confidence level, we

conclude that there is no spatial autocorrelation.

∑∑ ∑∑∑

−−=

i j i iji

i j jiji

XXW

XXXXWNI 2

,

,

)()(

))((

⎥⎥

⎢⎢

−+=

∑∑ ∑ ∑ ∑

ij ij

ij ij i j ijijijIE wN

wNwwNSQRTS 22

2222

)( ))(1(

)()(3

71

Now we test for the spatial autocorrelation for industry variables. For this we use the

following regression to find the residuals:

ijijj

ii uXXZ +++= ∑ δδδ 21

jiX = Dummy variables for country (independent variables)

j = All the countries except Paraguay

Note that Paraguay is used as the base country.

iX = Corruption Level

iu = Residuals

We found that the mean values for residuals are zero for all industry sectors;

therefore, we need not test further and can safely say that there is no spatial

autocorrelation across industry sectors.

5.7 Hypothesis Testing

5.7.1 ROI and Level of Corruption

H1α1: Firms that pay a higher rate of bribes have a slower rate of growth.

To the test the relationship between the rate of bribes - level of corruption - and

rate of growth of firms, we performed a regression with ROI as the dependent variable

and the construct called Corruption Level as identified in factor analysis. The results are

shown in tables 5.11.

)(

)()(IESIEIIZ −

=

72

Table 5.11: Regression Analysis of ROI as Dependent Variable and Corruption Level as Independent Variable

Variables Entered/Removed(b)

Model Variables Entered Variables Removed Method

1 Corruption Level . Enter

a All requested variables entered. b Dependent Variable: ROI

Model Summary

Model R R

Square

Adjusted R

Square

Std. Error of the

Estimate 1 .960(a) .921 .921 1.46725

a Predictors: (Constant), Corruption Level

ANOVA(b)

Model Sum of Squares Df

Mean Square F Sig.

Regression

14045.619 1 14045.619 6524.27

4 .000(a)

Residual 1201.276 558 2.153

1

Total 15246.895 559

a Predictors: (Constant), Corruption Level b Dependent Variable: ROI

Coefficients(a)

Unstandardized

Coefficients Standardized Coefficients t Sig.

Model B

Std. Error Beta

(Constant) 2.072 .062 33.420 .0001 Corruption

Level -5.013 .062 -.960 -80.773 .000

a Dependent Variable: ROI

The results of regression analysis suggest that Corruption Level explains 92.1 %

of variation in firms’ growth rate. The overall model was found to be significant

(p=0.000). The coefficient of Corruption Level, (-5.013), indicates that hypothesis 1,

73

which states that firms that pay higher rate of bribes have slower rate of growth, is

supported.

5.7.2: The Rent Seeking Behavior and Industry Sectors

H2α1: There are differences in rent-seeking behavior among bureaucrats in different

industry sectors.

To assess the relationship between the industry sector and rent-seeking behavior

of bureaucrats, we first performed ANOVA with Corruption Level as the independent

variable and industry sector as the dependent variable. The results are shown in table

5.12.

74

Table 5.12: ANOVA with Corruption Level as dependent variable and Industry Sector as independent variable

Descriptives

Corruption Level

95% Confidence Interval for Mean

N Mean Std.

Deviation Std.

Error Lower Bound

Upper Bound

Minimum

Maximum

Software 82 -0.00677 1.04992 0.115944 -0.23746 0.223926 -1.52261 1.569527Comp_man 72 -0.10762 1.025204 0.120821 -0.34853 0.13329 -1.97882 1.569527Com_supp 90 0.019992 0.988643 0.104212 -0.18707 0.22706 -1.52388 1.569527Semc_man 83 -0.01702 0.938801 0.103047 -0.22202 0.187969 -1.98517 1.569527Networking 74 -0.01937 0.98387 0.114373 -0.24731 0.208575 -1.52261 1.533955Peripherals 75 0.096507 1.055453 0.121873 -0.14633 0.339345 -1.67769 1.569527Others 84 0.02515 0.988189 0.10782 -0.1893 0.2396 -1.52512 1.569527Total 560 7.77E-17 1 0.042258 -0.083 0.083003 -1.98517 1.569527

ANOVA

Corruption Level

Sum of Squares df

Mean Square F Sig.

Between Groups 1.677121 6 0.27952 0.277352 0.947594 Within Groups 557.3229 553 1.007817 Total 559 559

The results overall show that the model is insignificant, and in rent-seeking there

are no differences among bureaucrats in different industry sectors. To analyze further and

75

understand if at least one industry sector is different than others, we did the regression

with Corruption Level as the dependent variable and industry sector as the independent

variable. Table 5.13 lays out the results.

Table 5.13: Regression with Corruption Level as dependent variable and Industry

Sector as independent variable

Variables Entered/Removed(b)

Model Variables Entered

Variables Removed Method

1 OTHERS, NETWO

RKI, COM_M

AN, SEMC_M

AN, COM_SU

PP, PERIPH(

a)

. Enter

a All requested variables entered. b Dependent Variable: Corruption Level

Model Summary

Model R R

Square

Adjusted R

Square

Std. Error of the

Estimate 1 0.054774(a) 0.003 -0.00782 1.003901

a Predictors: (Constant), OTHERS, NETWORKI, COM_MAN, SEMC_MAN, COM_SUPP, PERIPH

76

ANOVA(b)

Model Sum of Squares df

Mean Square F Sig.

Regression 1.677121 6 0.27952 0.277352 0.947594(a)Residual 557.3229 553 1.007817

1

Total 559 559 a Predictors: (Constant), OTHERS, NETWORKI, COM_MAN, SEMC_MAN,

COM_SUPP, PERIPH b Dependent Variable: Corruption Level

Coefficients(a)

Unstandardized Coefficients

Standardized

Coefficients

Model B Std.

Error Beta t Sig. (Constant) -0.00677 0.110862 -0.06104 0.951348COM_MAN -0.10085 0.162135 -0.03379 -0.62203 0.534176COM_SUPP 0.02676 0.153259 0.009837 0.174603 0.861455SEMC_MAN -0.01026 0.15631 -0.00365 -0.06562 0.947705NETWORKI -0.0126 0.160965 -0.00427 -0.07829 0.937625PERIPH 0.103274 0.1604 0.035204 0.643856 0.519936

1

OTHERS 0.031917 0.155847 0.011407 0.204798 0.837805

a Dependent Variable: Corruption Level

We found that the overall model explains just 0.3 % of the variation in Corruption

Level. The model is insignificant, as suggested by the p value of 0.947594. Looking at

the coefficients and their significance, we conclude that none of the industry sectors is

significantly different in rent-seeking behavior of bureaucrats; hence, the hypothesis 2 is

not supported.

77

5.7.3: Differences in Rent Seeking Behavior across Nations and Rate of

Growth of Firms

H3α1: The general climate of corruption in a nation impacts rent-seeking behavior

among bureaucrats and the growth rate of firms.

Table 5.14 shows the results of ANOVA with Corruption Level as the dependent

variable and Country as the independent variable.

Table 5.14: ANOVA to assess the differences in Rent Seeking Behavior

Descriptives Corruption Level

N Mean Std.

Deviation Std.

Error 95% Confidence

Interval for Mean Minimum Maximum

Lower Bound

Upper Bound

Paraguay 95 1.05279

13 .44173777 .04532134 .9628047 1.1427779 .08567 1.56953

Argentina 254 .203116

3 .90566833 .05682668 .0912027 .3150300 -1.98517 1.56953

Brazil 174

-.594379

6 .73239380 .055522

63 -.7039685 -.4847906 -1.97882 1.07423

Uruguay 37

-1.30228

88 .09778782 .016076

22 -1.3348929 -1.2696847 -1.52261 -1.22032

Total 560 .0000000 1.00000000 .042257

71 -.0830033 .0830033 -1.98517 1.56953

78

ANOVA

Corruption Level

Sum of Squares Df

Mean Square F Sig.

Between Groups 239.997 3 79.999 139.432 .000

Within Groups 319.003 556 .574

Total 559.000 559

The results of ANOVA support the hypothesis 3 that there exist differences

in rent-seeking behavior among bureaucrats in different nations (p=0.000). To take it

further, we performed a regression analysis to Corruption Level as the dependent variable

and country as the independent variable. For this purpose, Uruguay is taken as the base

country. The results of the regression analysis are shown in table 5.15.

Table 5.15: Regression with Corruption Level as dependent variable and Country

as independent variable

Variables Entered/Removed(b)

Model Variables Entered Variables Removed Method

1 URUGUAY, ARGENTINA, BRAZIL(a) . Enter

a All requested variables entered. b Dependent Variable: Corruption Level

Model Summary

Model R R

Square

Adjusted R

Square

Std. Error of the

Estimate 1 .655(a) .429 .426 .75746107

a Predictors: (Constant), URUGUAY, ARGENTINA, BRAZIL

79

Coefficients(a)

Model Unstandardized

Coefficients Standardized Coefficients t Sig.

B Std.

Error Beta (Constant) 1.053 .078 13.547 .000ARGENTINA -.850 .091 -.423 -9.327 .000BRAZIL -1.647 .097 -.763 -

17.047 .000

1

URUGUAY -2.355 .147 -.586 -16.044 .000

a Dependent Variable: Corruption Level

The country explains the 42.9% of the variation in rent-seeking behavior of

bureaucrats. Overall, the model is significant (p = 0.000) with each country having

significant relationship. Compared to Paraguay, which is ranked lowest amongst

Mercosur nations on CPI index, we found that Corruption Level is perceived to be

highest in Argentina. Amongst the Uruguay and Brazil, the Uruguay Corruption Level is

perceived to be lower.

5.7.4: The Overall Model

To understand which variables affect ROI and how the relationship is, we

performed the regression analysis with ROI as the dependent variable and Corruption

Level, Country, and Industry Sector as the independent variables. The results are shown

in table 5.16.

80

Table 5.16: Overall Model with ROI as dependent variable and Corruption Level, Country, and Industry Sector as independent variables

Variables Entered/Removed(b)

Model Variables Entered

Variables Removed Method

1 OTHERS, Corruption Level , NETWO

RKI, COM_M

AN, BRAZIL,

SEMC_MAN,

COM_SUPP,

URUGUAY,

PERIPH, ARGENT

INA(a)

. Enter

a All requested variables entered. b Dependent Variable: ROI

Model Summary

Model R R

Square

Adjusted R

Square

Std. Error of the

Estimate 1 .962(a) .925 .924 1.44110

a Predictors: (Constant), OTHERS, Corruption Level , NETWORKI, COM_MAN, BRAZIL, SEMC_MAN, COM_SUPP, URUGUAY, PERIPH, ARGENTINA

81

ANOVA(b)

Model Sum of Squares Df

Mean Square F Sig.

Regression

14106.742 10 1410.674 679.260 .000(a)

Residual 1140.153 549 2.077

1

Total 15246.895 559

a Predictors: (Constant), OTHERS, Corruption Level , NETWORKI, COM_MAN, BRAZIL, SEMC_MAN, COM_SUPP, URUGUAY, PERIPH, ARGENTINA

b Dependent Variable: ROI

Coefficients(a)

Model Unstandardized

Coefficients Standardized Coefficients t Sig.

B Std.

Error Beta (Constant) 1.429783 0.233695 6.118159 .000COM_MAN -0.09189 0.233207 -0.00589 -0.39402 .694

COM_SUPP 0.028655 0.220157 0.002017 0.130156 .896

SEMC_MAN -0.00238 0.22532 -0.00016 -0.01058 .992

NETWORKI -0.11126 0.233172 -0.00722 -0.47717 .633

PERIPH 0.087352 0.230905 0.005702 0.378305 .705OTHERS -0.23259 0.224065 -0.01592 -1.03806 .300ARGENTINA 0.577531 0.189016 0.055102 3.055455 .002

BRAZIL 1.039265 0.228656 0.092174 4.545105 .000URUGUAY 1.557871 0.34059 0.074165 4.574034 .000

1

Corruption Level -4.74127 0.080936 -0.90784 -58.5804 .000

a Dependent Variable: ROI The overall model explains 92.4 % of the variation in ROI. We also found that the

model is significant (p = 0.00). The Corruption Level and Country variables have a

significant relationship with ROI. Higher coefficients of Uruguay and Brazil suggest that

ROI of firms in these countries are higher. This is the case because we found that the

82

corruption levels in these countries are lower. We found that none of the industry sector

variables have a significant impact on ROI.

5.8 Analysis of Structured Interviews

To understand the impact of corruption in greater detail, structured interviews

were conducted. Details on the methodology and questions asked by the researcher are

provided in Appendix A. This section provides the results of the structured interviews.

5.8.1 Sample Description

The distributions of respondents for the quantitative analysis part, according to

both the nation and sectors of industry, are provided in the earlier section. Here we

provide the distributions of interviewees according to the nation and industry.

Table 5.17: Distribution of interviewees across the nations

Nation Argentina Uruguay Paraguay Brazil Total Number of respondents 24 4 9 18 55Percentage

43.64 7.27 16.36 32.73 100

Table 5.18: Distribution of respondents across the seven sectors of computer

industry

Industry Sector Software Comp_man Com_supp Semc_man Networking Peripherals Others

Total

Number of respondents 6 7 9 7 5 12 9 55Percentage 10.91 12.73 16.36 12.73 9.09 21.82 16.36 100

Overall, we found that these distributions represent the earlier sample obtained

from survey responses. As expected, the differences were due to the convenient approach

83

used for interviews depending on the availability of the respondents as well as the time

and cost involved in conducting interviews.

5.8.2 Competitive Disadvantage Because of Rent Seeking Behavior of

Bureaucrats

Respondents were asked if the rent-seeking behavior of bureaucrats in their nation

results into competitive disadvantage for their firms compared with firms in other

Mercosur nations. Specifically, the following question was asked to them to make the

comparison:

Do requests from officials for payments along with those required by regulations create a competitive disadvantage when compared to firms in other Mercosur nations?

Overall, 76.36% (42) of the respondents said that their firms are in the

disadvantaged position when compared with the firms in other Mercosur nations. Further,

all the respondents from Argentina and Paraguay said that the rent-seeking behavior of

officials in their nation has created barriers for them to be competitive and perform better.

Nine (50%) of the Brazilian respondents responded otherwise, that their firms are not in

the disadvantaged position when compared with the firms in the other Mercosur nations.

To understand the impact of corruption on the economic growth of firms in

Mercosur nations at the international level, we asked respondents to reflect on the

competitive position of their firms in the global market. For this purpose, we asked the

following question:

84

Do requests from officials for payments along with those required by regulations create a competitive disadvantage in the global market?

Pooled across nations, 23.63% (13) of the respondents feel that the rent-seeking

behavior of the bureaucrats did not hamper competitive position of their firms in the

global market is. All the respondents (4) from Uruguay said that at the international level,

their firms’ competitive position is unaffected by corruption in their country. Rest 9

(16.36%) are from Brazil who said that the competitive position of their firm is not

disadvantaged due to corruption in their country.

5.8.3 Corruption Level in Computer Industry

We asked the following question to understand whether respondents recognize

that rent-seeking in their industry is different from other industries.

Do you perceive requests from officials for payments along with those required by regulations as more or less than in other industries?

We found that little over 75% (76.36%) of the respondents feel that rent-seeking

behavior of the bureaucrats in their industry is more than the other industries. All the

respondents in Computer Supply, Peripherals, Networking, and Computer Manufacturing

sectors said that the corruption in their industry is more than the corruption in other

industries.

5.8.4 Changes in Corruption Level

To understand the changes in rent-seeking behavior of officials over the period of

time, we asked two questions:

85

Do you perceive requests from officials for payments along with those required by regulations as increasing, decreasing, or about the same as in the past?

Do you think that requests from officials for payments in addition to those required by regulations as more, less, or about the same in your country when compared to other Mercosur nations?

The first question refers to how respondents see the change in corruption over the

period of time for their industry. 60% (33 of 55) of the respondents felt that the

corruption in their industry has increased over the period of time; 30.9% said that the

corruption level is about the same as in the past, and the rest said it has decreased. All the

respondents from Paraguay said that the corruption in their industry has increased. With

respect to industry sector, five respondents from software sector said that corruption has

decreased in their industry.

When asked to compare with other nations, respondents from Paraguay (9) said

that the rent-seeking behavior of bureaucrats in their nation has changed for the worse.

Interesting enough, respondents from Uruguay said that the rent-seeking behavior of

bureaucrats in their nation has changed positively when compared to other Mercosur

nations.

To a large degree, the closed-ended questions were intended to elicit information

that could corroborate the data gathered through the survey test instrument. At the same

time, these inquiries should create a wider perspective regarding subjective factors such

as competitive advantage. In general, the closed-ended questions were anticipated to

86

produce a ‘yes or no’ response. The interviewees, however, were not discouraged from

elaborating on their response.

5.8.5 Analysis of Open Ended Questions

To understand the issues involved in corruption, we asked respondents four open

ended questions. The responses were transcribed and common emergent themes were

identified for each one of them. Here we provide the analysis of responses to open ended

questions.

Considering the various areas of operation - building construction, employment, importing or exporting - of your industry’s firm, in what area is a request from an official for payments other than those required by regulations most likely to occur?

The above question was asked to respondents so that they can reflect upon areas

of operations where they are facing the problem of corruption the most. The intention

was not to rank the areas of operations but to get the idea on problems faced by firms. In

addition, respondents were free to quote any other area of operations apart from

mentioned in the question in which they are facing hurdles.

More than 90% of the respondents said that there is a prevalent and widespread

corruption in the field of land acquisition to build new facilities. In the same activity,

getting clearances for new facilities firms need to pay bribes to officials so that the work

goes on smoothly. Same number of respondents also raised the issue of number of

clearances required and different stages of projects at which they need to approach

officials for clearances. Interestingly, they suggested that there should be one window

87

clearance scheme. Few of the respondents said that there should be more transparency

from the government side to deal with expansion of the existing facilities or build new

facilities.

Next, little over 85% of the respondents from computer manufacturing, computer

supply, semiconductor manufacturing and peripherals said that they face problems in

importing and exporting goods. To get these activities done smoothly, quite often, they

have to pay bribes to officials.

Do you believe that government policies and officials support your industry by removing barriers to commerce?

To understand the problems faced by firms when dealing in regional (Mercosur)

and international markets, we asked the question as stated above. Respondents were free

to quote any particular nations name in which they are facing problems and suggest any

changes or improvements.

Business executives felt that they are not able to exploit the trade agreements

among Mercosur nations. Especially, firms in Uruguay and Brazil complained that while

dealing with officials in Paraguay they have to pay bribes to officials. However, they are

very happy when dealing in countries outside Mercosur region. Quite a few of them

suggested that the countries in Mercosur region should take care that the trade

agreements must be implemented strictly. The primary theme that came out is the fact

88

that to compete in the international market all the countries in Mercosur region should

stand together.

To investigate the perceptions of respondents on how government should deal

with corruption, we asked them to suggest any changes and improvements. Specifically

we asked the following question:

Do you believe that your industry would be more prosperous if government operations

were more closely supervised or regulated?

All the respondents said that the government should closely supervise the officials

more closely and be transparent on the corruption cases. They suggested that corruption

cases against officials should be made public so that other officials learn from them.

Interestingly, 80% of the respondents said that the supervision or regulations are

not the ultimate solutions as these may increase burden on officials and firms both. Also,

they fear that officials may find ways and means to extract rents. Rather, sweeping

changes are required to deal with the issue of corruption and increase the efficiency of

government setup. Some of them suggested policies like staff rotation and

implementation of E-governance.

The next question was to understand the awareness of corruption in the industry.

Are you aware of any experiences of other firms resulting in the firm suffering economic harm from requests from officials for payments in addition to those required by regulations?

89

Very likely, we found that all the respondents were aware of the corrupt dealings

in which the other firms were forced/unforced. However, 40% respondents from said that

such dealing by other firms were unforced. Thus, they raised the issue that firms should

be strict in dealing with corrupt officials. They believe that if all firms in industry stand

together then corruption can be wiped out totally.

Finally, 95% of the respondents felt that nothing less that sustained campaign

against corruption will help them to wipe it and achieve desired economic growth.

5.9 Discussion

The purpose of this thesis was to conduct an in-depth examination of corruption

in the Mercosur nations and its implications for economic development using an

econometric approach. In the process, we measured the perceived level of corruption in

four nations and seven industry sectors. Our methodology enabled us to combine relevant

aspects of mathematics, economics, and statistics in an effort to develop an econometric

model explaining the impact of corruption on the economic development of the four

Mercosur nations - Brazil, Argentina, Uruguay, and Paraguay.

As pointed out in the literature review section of the thesis, the various corruption

indices suffer from different lacunae. In this research, we developed an index called

“Corruption Level.” The index consists of events of corruption, number of such events,

difficulty in completing projects due to such events, including the delays and payments

90

made to officials in project planning, competitive position of firms due to payment/non-

payment to officials, and difficulty in taking advantages of trading arrangements with

other Mercosur nations due to corruption in other Mercosur nations. This index was

developed through rigorous statistical analysis. Our results showed that the reliability of

the scale of the index is very well above the accepted level. We also made sure that the

scale items for the index and the index, as a whole is valid.

We proposed that the firms operating in the environment characterized by high

level of corruption should have slower rate of growth. Our result indicates that the higher

the Corruption Level measured by the index, the lower is the growth rate of firms. There

are a number of studies showing how corruption affects the growth rate of the GDP, level

of investments, and allocation of resources. Their approach and conclusions are at the

macroeconomic level. However, many other factors influence the GDP, level of

investments, and allocation of resources. We took this path of research to the next level

and showed that all these effects come from the micro level. In the micro level context,

such as at the firm level studies, our results are similar to the results of Gaviria (2002)

and suggest that the impact of corruption is significant at the firm level also.

While investigating the firm level effects, we proposed that within an industry

there are no differences in rent seeking behavior across different sectors of the industry.

For this purpose, we took up the computer industry and considered seven different sectors

of the industry. In many developing nations software, semiconductor manufacturing, and

computer manufacturing firms are doing excellent contributions to the economy. Firms in

these sectors are having direct and indirect effects on the economic growth rate.

91

Additionally, our aim helped us to control for business environments. For example, the

business environment for a software firm can be significantly different from the firm in

computer manufacturing or computer supply or peripherals sector of the industry. The

results indicate that there are no differences in rent-seeking behavior of bureaucrats in

different industry sectors. However, the analysis of close-ended questions indicates that

the corruption in computer industry is more than the corruption in other industries.

These results on corruption in computer industry could be because of the

centralized decision making in the government. Decisions regarding different sectors of

the industry are taken by one central office.

Next, we proposed that there are differences in rent-seeking behavior of

bureaucrats across nations and these differences affect the growth rate of firms. We

analyzed this in two stages. First we investigated the differences across nations and then

tested the overall model to how the growth rate of firms get affected.

We found that significant differences exist in rent-seeking behavior of bureaucrats

across nations. Specifically, we found Uruguay to be the least corrupt followed by Brazil,

Argentina, and Paraguay. Our results are similar to the CPI index, which rates Paraguay

to be the most corrupt followed by Argentina, Brazil, and Uruguay. Interestingly, we

found that little over three-quarters of the respondents from structured interviews felt that

the corruption level in their country is creating competitive disadvantage when compared

with other Mercosur nations. When comparing the results from the structured interviews

92

with the results of the statistical analysis we found, once again, that respondents from

Paraguay feel that corruption in their country is more than in other Mercosur nations.

These results, again, are comparable to available corruption indices.

While investigating the impact of differences in rent-seeking behavior across

nations on growth rate ROI, we found that this effect is significant. Our overall model

shows that if a firm is situated in Uruguay then it is more likely to have higher growth

rate as compared to the firms located in other Mercosur nations. On the other end, if a

firm is located in Paraguay then it is more likely to have lowest growth when compared

with firms in other Mercosur nations. Firms in Brazil and Argentina lie in between these

two extremes of the continuum.

In terms of the global competitiveness of the firms, our results suggest that the

firms in Mercosur nations are at disadvantaged position due to corruption in the region.

To understand the issues involved we need to look at regional factors. Treisman (2000)

and Gaviria (2002) pointed out probable causes of corruption. These causes come from

the three domains: Political environment, Rules and Regulations, and Historical and

Cultural factors.

In this chapter, we dwelt upon the discussion of the results. Finally, we move onto

the last chapter on implications, limitations, and future research directions.

93

Chapter 6

IMPLICATIONS, LIMITATIONS, AND FUTURE RESEARCH

DIRECTIONS

6.1 Contribution and Implications

Measuring corruption in itself is a difficult task. Various corruption indices are

available. However, we demonstrated the problems associated with these indices. In this

study, we developed an index to measure the level of corruption. This index is based on

rigorous statistical analysis, which showed the reliability of index. We also showed the

validity of index. This has an interesting contribution for managers and academicians.

Most of the corruption indices are at the generic level. The index developed in this study

is useful for managers to understand the level of corruption in their own industry. Based

on the output of this, they can take actions in the interest of their firm and industry as a

whole. Academicians can use this survey to measure the level of corruption at the

industry or firm level. As pointed out by our results, we must understand the firm level

impact of corruption. The index developed in this study will be very useful in future

research studies.

Almost all the researchers investigated the impact of corruption at the

macroeconomic level in terms of GDP growth rate, level of investments, and distribution

of resources. Our study departs from the traditional way of research done on the impact

of corruption. We hypothesized that corruption do have significant impact at the firm

level. Our results showed that the corruption level impacts rate of growth of firms. This

94

proves a very important point highlighted in this research that firms should be aware of

level of corruption in their industry and corruption impacts their competitive position

adversely in national and international markets. The research also suggests that there is

no change in the perception of corruption in the Mercosur region and level of corruption

in the region is hampering the growth rate of firms. Hence, there is a need to understand

the causes of corruption.

The output of this research has important implications for policy formation at

national and international levels, as well as for multinational firms operating in

environments where corruption often influences governmental and business relations. As

our results show that corruption is persistent in the region. Therefore, as rightly found by

McAdam and Rummel (2004), anti-corruption campaigns must be sustained to be

effective. Although we did not find differences in the rent-seeking approach of

bureaucrats across industry sectors, respondents said that the corruption in their industry

is higher than in other industries. Government can ensure that officials be posted on the

rotation basis so that the level and frequency of bribes come down. On the other hand,

government can make the system transparent by starting in E-governance initiatives.

Research has proved that making the system transparent reduces the corruption.

6.2 Limitations

As every research work has its limitations, the results of this study should also be

interpreted in light of several limitations, with some of the limitations providing

opportunities to pursue further work in the field.

95

This study adopted a cross-sectional data collection method even though the

corruption level in a country might change from time to time. The cost and time

limitations left no choice with the researcher but to adopt a cross-sectional data collection

method.

The generalizability of the study findings is also an issue as we have collected

data from the computer industry only. In future, to understand the issues involved in

corruption in Mercosur nations, the data should be collected across industries.

We have used perceptual measures for measuring corruption. Such ratings are

subjective; therefore, it is interesting to investigate the patterns they show. However,

these perceptual measures are highly susceptible to quirks and biases of the respondents.

Another limitation of this study is the endogeneity of variables; therefore, we

recommend that the interpretation results should be considered in the light of this

limitation. We suggest alternative methods in the future research directions to overcome

this limitation.

The need to obtain ROI from data sources exogenous to the test instrument

created a limitation to the study based on the exclusion of firms privately owned and

firms publicly owned but did not have readily available information regarding earnings or

assets. This limitation affects the representative nature of the data; only firms large

enough to have public records regarding their financial position are included in the study.

96

As a result, micro-capital firms that may be in the start-up phase of business operations

were functionally excluded from the study. This likely created a variable impact on the

data from the different Mercosur nations, with some nations potentially having a business

climate favoring public ownership and disclosure of financial information, while other

nations favor private ownership.

Another limitation in the study is the multiplicity of factors that can affect ROI

other than corruption. The computer industry is relatively volatile; the development and

deployment of new technologies in an environment characterized by rapid change drives

this volatile nature. As a result, an innovative product or service delivery method can

increase ROI even in a corrupt environment. Conversely, poor business management

could result in a lower ROI even in a less corrupt environment. The study is based on the

assumption that in a large sampling, these additional variables will likely cancel each

other out through an indirect averaging process. Based on this assumption, no attempt

was made to include an instrumental variable in the model to account for these factors.

6.3 Future Research Directions

We have not gone on to investigate the causes of corruption. There is an urgent

need to understand and investigate why corruption is persistent in the Mercosur region.

We suggest that future research should investigate the causes of corruption in detail. For

example, future research should inculcate the political environment, rules and

regulations, and historical and cultural differences

97

Future studies should include the time series collection of data on the perception

of corruption. This will help identify the changes in corruption level in a country or

industry. The output of this type of research will provide insightful view on causes and

consequences of corruption. When completed, the governments and businesses will be in

right position to take up the appropriate actions to weed out the corruption.

Further, there is a need to investigate the issues involved in firm characteristics.

This field of research will progress further if the researchers are able to identify which

firms are more susceptible to corruption. For example, which of the firm’s characteristics

like size, history, and customer base make firm indulge into corrupt practices.

In our research, we used the perceptions of business people. We recommend that

future research should include perceptions of government officials also. However, note

that for this purpose, we need to develop a separate scale and the methodology involved

would be very different from the methodologies used in existing studies.

To overcome the problem of endogeneity, we suggest that future research work

should use path analysis approach or structural equations modeling framework.

6.4 Conclusion

Research on the impact of corruption on economic growth focused on

macroeconomic level. None of the studies investigated the firm level effect. To fill this

void, we proposed that corruption does have significant effect on growth rate of firms.

98

Our results showed that the level of corruption in a nation adversely affects the growth

rate of firms. We also demonstrated that the firms are at disadvantaged position due to the

corruption in their nation and industry; hence, there is a need on firms’ part to make the

anti-corruption efforts sustained to weed out the corruption.

Our results showed that there are no differences in rent-seeking behavior of

bureaucrats across industry sectors. However, we also found that the corruption in the

computer industry is higher than other industries. This compels that the future research

should investigate, one the impact of firm characteristics and two, the business

environment of the industry. The results of our study indicate that there are significant

differences in rent-seeking behavior of bureaucrats across nations, which impact the

growth rate of ROI. The analysis of structured interviews indicates to a very limited

extent the changes in corruption levels over the period of time. To deal with the menace

of corruption, we need to work on identifying the causes of corruption.

99

REFERENCES

2003 Annual Report. Economic Freedom Network. Retrieved online April 27, 2004:

http://www.freetheworld.com/2003/1EFW2003ch1.pdf.

Antwi, Adarkway and John Adams (2003). Rent-Seeking Behavior And Its Economic

Costs In Urban Land Transformations in Accra, Ghana. Urban Studies, 40(10),

2083-2098.

Assane, Dieto and Abbas Grammy (2003). Institutional Framework And Economic

Development: International Evidence. Applied Economics. 35(17), 1811-1817.

Burgeut, Roberto and Yeon-Koo Che (2004). Competitive Procurement With Corruption.

Rand Journal of Economics, 35(1), 50-69.

Churchill, G.A. (1994), Marketing Research Methodological Foundations 6th ed. Dryden.

Cliff, A. D. and Ord, J.K, (1973). “Spatial Auto Correlation”. Sage Publications, London.

Colombatto, Enrico (2001). Discretionary Power, Rent-Seeking, and Corruption, ICER

Working Paper, Retrieved online April 1, 2004

http://www.icer.it/docs/wp2001/EC24-01.pdf.

Cooper, D.R. and Emory, C.W. (1995). Business Research Methods. 5th Edition, Irwin.

Corruption: Causes, Consequences and Agenda For Further Research (1998). Finance &

Development 35(1), 11-13.

Corruption Monitoring System. Coalition 2000. Retrieved online April 27, 2004:

http://www.online.bg/coalition2000/eng/monitor.htm#2.

Coupet, Ernst (2003). Investment and Corruption: A Look At Causality. Journal of

Academy of Business And Environment. 1(2), 34-43.

100

De Soto, Hernando (2002). The Other Path: The Economic Answer to Terrorism. New

York: Basic Books.

Di Tella, Rafael and Ernesto Schargrodsky (2003). The Role of Wages and Auditing

During a Crackdown On Corruption in the City of Buenos Aires. Journal of Law

and Economics 65, 269-292.

Dixit, Avinash (2003). Trade Expansion and Contract Enforcement. Journal of Political

Economy 111,(6), 1293-1317.

Easterly, William (2001). The Elusive Quest For Growth. Cambridge MA: MIT Press

Fisman, Raymond and Roberta Gatti (1999). Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence

Across Countries. The World Bank. Retrieved online April 19, 2004:

documents/fisman.pdf.http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/publicfinance/documents/fi

sman.pdf.

Fletcher, Stanley (1999). Preparing For The 1999 WTO Agricultural Round. American

Journal of Agricultural Economics 81(5), 1157-1168.

Galenternick, Mery (2003). Mighty-ducks: How A University Project Nurtured by

Government Funding and Protection Sparked Brazil’s High-Tech Industry. Latin

Trade 11 (7), 57-58.

Ganuza, Jose-Juan and Esther Hauk (2004). Economic Integration and Corruption: The

Corrupt Soul of the European Union. Universitat Pompeu Fabra. Retrieved online

November 1. 2004: http://www.anti-corr.ru/an_plc/CEU.pdf.

Gaviria, Alejandro (2002). Assessing the effects of corruption and crime on firm

performance: evidence from Latin America. Emerging Markets Review 3, 245-

268.

101

Geddes, Richard (1997). Ownership, Regulation and Managerial Monitoring In The

Electric Utility Industry. Journal of Law and Economics 40(1), 261-288.

Goodman, Joshua (2004). Uruguay Massala: Software Jobs Of The Future Are Going to

End Up Somewhere. Latin Trade, 12 (1), 28-2.

Gray, Cheryl W. and Kaufmann, Daniel (1998). Corruption and Development. Finance &

Development, March.

Gujarati, D. (2003). Basic Econometrics. 4th edition. McGraw-Hill.

Hutchcroft, Paul D (1997). The Politics of Privilege: Assessing the Impact of Rents,

Corruption and Clientelism on Third World Development.” Political Studies

45(3), 639-668.

Kahn, Mushtaqh and K.S. Jomo, Eds (2000). Rents, Rent-Seeking And Economic

Development in Asia: Theory and Evidence. Cambridge: Cambridge University

Press.

Kaufman, Daniel and Shang Wei (1999). Does Grease Money Speed Up The Wheels of

Commerce? Policy Research Paper 2254, World Bank. Retrieved online May 18,

2004: http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/pdf/grease.pdf.

King, Damien and S. Handa (2003). The Welfare Effects of Balance of Payments

Reform: A Macro-Micro Simulation Of the Cost of Rent-Seeking. Journal of

Development Studies 39(3), 101-127.

La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer and Robert W. Vishney

(1998). Law and Finance. Journal of Political Economy 106(1), 1113-1155.

102

Lambsdorff, Johann (2002). Framework Document 2002: Background Paper To the 2002

Corruption Perception Index. Transparency International. Retrieved online April

27, 2004: http://www.transparency.org/cpi/2002/dnld/cpi2002.methodology.pdf.

Mauro, Paolo (1995). Corruption and Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(3),

681-712.

“The Persistence of Corruption and Slow Economic Growth.” IMF Working Paper

WP/02/213, November 2002. Retrieved online May 3, 2004:

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2002/wp02213.pdf.

Mbaku, John (1999). The Relevance of the State in African Development. Journal of

Asian and African Studies 34(3), 298-331.

McAdam, Peter and Rummel, Ole, (2004). Corruption: a non-parametric analysis.

Journal of Economic Studies 31(6), 509-523.

McCarthy, B. and J. Hagan (2001). When Crime Pays: Capital, Competence, and

Criminal Success. Social Forces 79(3), 1035-1061.

Murphy, Kevin, Andrei Shleifer and Robert W. Vishny (1993). Why Is Rent-Seeking So

Costly to Growth? The American Economic Review 83(2), 409-414.

Nunnally, J.C. (1978). Psychometric Theory, 2nd edition, New York: McGraw-Hill

Publishing Company.

Odland, John. (1988). Spatial Autocorrelation. Sage Publications, Newbury Park.

Piracy in Paraguay. AdTI Issue Brief No. 173, July 1999. Retrieves online May 25, 2004:

http://www.adti.net/Piracy_in_Paraguay.html.

Rosenberg, Tina (2003), “The Taint of the Greased Palm” The New York Times, Vol. 28.

103

Safavian, Michael, Douglas Graham and Claudio Gonzalez-Vega (2001). Corruption and

Microenterprises in Russia. World Development 29(7), 1215-1229.

Shleifer, Andrei and Robert W. Vishny (1993). Corruption. The Quarterly Journal of

Economics 108(3), 599-617.

Treisman, Daniel, (2000). The causes of corruption: a cross-national study. Journal of

Public Economics, 27, 399–457.

Tulloch, G, (1980). Efficient Rent Seeking, in J. M. Buchanan, R. D. Tollison and G

Tulloch (Eds), 87-112, Toward a Theory of the Rent Seeking Society, College

Station, Texas A&M University Press.

Wilhelm, Paul G (2002). International validation of the Corruption Perceptions Index.

Journal of Business Ethics 35(13), 177-189.

Velasco, Pablo (2001). The Mineral Industries of Paraguay and Uruguay. U.S. Geological

Survey Minerals Yearbook. Retrieved online May 18, 2004:

http://minerals.usgs.gov/minerals/pubs/country/2001/pamyb01.pdf.

104

APPENDICES

Appendix 1

Transparency International Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI) 2003

Country

rank Country CPI 2003 score

Surveysused

Standard deviation

High-low range

1 Finland 9.7 8 0.3 9.2 - 10.0 2 Iceland 9.6 7 0.3 9.2 - 10.0

Denmark 9.5 9 0.4 8.8 - 9.9 3 New Zealand 9.5 8 0.2 9.2 - 9.6 5 Singapore 9.4 12 0.1 9.2 - 9.5 6 Sweden 9.3 11 0.2 8.8 - 9.6 7 Netherlands 8.9 9 0.3 8.5 - 9.3

Australia 8.8 12 0.9 6.7 - 9.5 Norway 8.8 8 0.5 8.0 - 9.3 8 Switzerland 8.8 9 0.8 6.9 - 9.4 Canada 8.7 12 0.9 6.5 - 9.4 Luxembourg 8.7 6 0.4 8.0 - 9.2 11 United Kingdom 8.7 13 0.5 7.8 - 9.2 Austria 8.0 9 0.7 7.3 - 9.3 14 Hong Kong 8.0 11 1.1 5.6 - 9.3

16 Germany 7.7 11 1.2 4.9 - 9.2 17 Belgium 7.6 9 0.9 6.6 - 9.2

Ireland 7.5 9 0.7 6.5 - 8.8 18 USA 7.5 13 1.2 4.9 - 9.2 20 Chile 7.4 12 0.9 5.6 - 8.8

Israel 7.0 10 1.2 4.7 - 8.1 21 Japan 7.0 13 1.1 5.5 - 8.8 France 6.9 12 1.1 4.8 - 9.0 23 Spain 6.9 11 0.8 5.2 - 7.8

25 Portugal 6.6 9 1.2 4.9 - 8.1 26 Oman 6.3 4 0.9 5.5 - 7.3

Bahrain 6.1 3 1.1 5.5 - 7.4 27 Cyprus 6.1 3 1.6 4.7 - 7.8 29 Slovenia 5.9 12 1.2 4.7 - 8.8

Botswana 5.7 6 0.9 4.7 - 7.3 30 Taiwan 5.7 13 1.0 3.6 - 7.8 32 Qatar 5.6 3 0.1 5.5 - 5.7

Estonia 5.5 12 0.6 4.7 - 6.6 33 Uruguay 5.5 7 1.1 4.1 - 7.4 Italy 5.3 11 1.1 3.3 - 7.3 35 Kuwait 5.3 4 1.7 3.3 - 7.4 Malaysia 5.2 13 1.1 3.6 - 8.0 37 United Arab Emirates 5.2 3 0.5 4.6 - 5.6

39 Tunisia 4.9 6 0.7 3.6 - 5.6 40 Hungary 4.8 13 0.6 4.0 - 5.6

Lithuania 4.7 10 1.6 3.0 - 7.7 41 Namibia 4.7 6 1.3 3.6 - 6.6 Cuba 4.6 3 1.0 3.6 - 5.5 Jordan 4.6 7 1.1 3.6 - 6.5 43 Trinidad and Tobago 4.6 6 1.3 3.4 - 6.9 Belize 4.5 3 0.9 3.6 - 5.5 46 Saudi Arabia 4.5 4 2.0 2.8 - 7.4 Mauritius 4.4 5 0.7 3.6 - 5.5 48 South Africa 4.4 12 0.6 3.6 - 5.5

105

Costa Rica 4.3 8 0.7 3.5 - 5.5 Greece 4.3 9 0.8 3.7 - 5.6 50 South Korea 4.3 12 1.0 2.0 - 5.6

53 Belarus 4.2 5 1.8 2.0 - 5.8 Brazil 3.9 12 0.5 3.3 - 4.7 Bulgaria 3.9 10 0.9 2.8 - 5.7 54 Czech Republic 3.9 12 0.9 2.6 - 5.6 Jamaica 3.8 5 0.4 3.3 - 4.3 57 Latvia 3.8 7 0.4 3.4 - 4.7 Colombia 3.7 11 0.5 2.7 - 4.4 Croatia 3.7 8 0.6 2.6 - 4.7 El Salvador 3.7 7 1.5 2.0 - 6.3 Peru 3.7 9 0.6 2.7 - 4.9

59

Slovakia 3.7 11 0.7 2.9 - 4.7 Mexico 3.6 12 0.6 2.4 - 4.9 64 Poland 3.6 14 1.1 2.4 - 5.6 China 3.4 13 1.0 2.0 - 5.5 Panama 3.4 7 0.8 2.7 - 5.0 Sri Lanka 3.4 7 0.7 2.4 - 4.4 66 Syria 3.4 4 1.3 2.0 - 5.0 Bosnia & Herzegovina 3.3 6 0.7 2.2 - 3.9 Dominican Republic 3.3 6 0.4 2.7 - 3.8 Egypt 3.3 9 1.3 1.8 - 5.3 Ghana 3.3 6 0.9 2.7 - 5.0 Morocco 3.3 5 1.3 2.4 - 5.5

70

Thailand 3.3 13 0.9 1.4 - 4.4 76 Senegal 3.2 6 1.2 2.2 - 5.5 77 Turkey 3.1 14 0.9 1.8 - 5.4

Armenia 3.0 5 0.8 2.2 - 4.1 Iran 3.0 4 1.0 1.5 - 3.6 Lebanon 3.0 4 0.8 2.1 - 3.6 Mali 3.0 3 1.8 1.4 - 5.0

78

Palestine 3.0 3 1.2 2.0 - 4.3 India 2.8 14 0.4 2.1 - 3.6 Malawi 2.8 4 1.2 2.0 - 4.4 83 Romania 2.8 12 1.0 1.6 - 5.0 Mozambique 2.7 5 0.7 2.0 - 3.6 86 Russia 2.7 16 0.8 1.4 - 4.9 Algeria 2.6 4 0.5 2.0 - 3.0 Madagascar 2.6 3 1.8 1.2 - 4.7 Nicaragua 2.6 7 0.5 2.0 - 3.3 88 Yemen 2.6 4 0.7 2.0 - 3.4 Albania 2.5 5 0.6 1.9 - 3.2 Argentina 2.5 12 0.5 1.6 - 3.2 Ethiopia 2.5 5 0.8 1.5 - 3.6 Gambia 2.5 4 0.9 1.5 - 3.6 Pakistan 2.5 7 0.9 1.5 - 3.9 Philippines 2.5 12 0.5 1.6 - 3.6 Tanzania 2.5 6 0.6 2.0 - 3.3

92

Zambia 2.5 5 0.6 2.0 - 3.3 Guatemala 2.4 8 0.6 1.5 - 3.4 Kazakhstan 2.4 7 0.9 1.6 - 3.8 Moldova 2.4 5 0.8 1.6 - 3.6 Uzbekistan 2.4 6 0.5 2.0 - 3.3 Venezuela 2.4 12 0.5 1.4 - 3.1

100

Vietnam 2.4 8 0.8 1.4 - 3.6 Bolivia 2.3 6 0.4 1.9 - 2.9 Honduras 2.3 7 0.6 1.4 - 3.3 Macedonia 2.3 5 0.3 2.0 - 2.7 Serbia & Montenegro 2.3 5 0.5 2.0 - 3.2 Sudan 2.3 4 0.3 2.0 - 2.7 Ukraine 2.3 10 0.6 1.6 - 3.8

106

Zimbabwe 2.3 7 0.3 2.0 - 2.7

106

Congo, Republic of the 2.2 3 0.5 2.0 - 2.8 Ecuador 2.2 8 0.3 1.8 - 2.6 Iraq 2.2 3 1.1 1.2 - 3.4 Sierra Leone 2.2 3 0.5 2.0 - 2.8

113

Uganda 2.2 6 0.7 1.8 - 3.5 Cote d’Ivoire 2.1 5 0.5 1.5 - 2.7 Kyrgyzstan 2.1 5 0.4 1.6 - 2.7 Libya 2.1 3 0.5 1.7 - 2.7 118 Papua New Guinea 2.1 3 0.6 1.5 - 2.7 Indonesia 1.9 13 0.5 0.7 - 2.9 122 Kenya 1.9 7 0.3 1.5 - 2.4 Angola 1.8 3 0.3 1.4 - 2.0 Azerbaijan 1.8 7 0.3 1.4 - 2.3 Cameroon 1.8 5 0.2 1.4 - 2.0 Georgia 1.8 6 0.7 0.9 - 2.8

124

Tajikistan 1.8 3 0.3 1.5 - 2.0 Myanmar 1.6 3 0.3 1.4 - 2.0 129 Paraguay 1.6 6 0.3 1.2 - 2.0

131 Haiti 1.5 5 0.6 0.7 - 2.3 132 Nigeria 1.4 9 0.4 0.9 - 2.0 133 Bangladesh 1.3 8 0.7 0.3 - 2.2

107

Appendix 2

CPI and EMI Irregular Payments Comparison, Sample Data

EFI CPI Argentina 4.7 2.5 Austria 8.1 8 Bang 2.5 1.3 Bolivia 7.5 7.6 Bolivia 3.7 2.3 Botswana 6.9 5.7 Brazil 6.2 3.9 Bulgaria 7.4 3.9 Canada 8.6 8.7 Chile 8.1 7.4 China 6.7 3.4 Costa Rica 5.6 4.3 Croatia 5.7 3.7 Czech. 5.1 3.9 Denmark 9.4 9.5

Multiple R 0.882566R Square 0.778923Adjusted R Square 0.7605Standard Error 0.867622Observations 14

108

Appendix A

Methodology

A.1 Development of Questionnaire

The test instrument for this study is in the form of a survey questionnaire

functioning to operationalize the variables under study. The questionnaire was developed

based on a literature review, which revealed the methodologies used by previous

researchers as well as the techniques used to operationalize the concepts associated with

corruption when investigating both macroeconomic and microeconomic phenomenon.

The study’s dependent variable is the return on investment (ROI) of the firms with

participating managers. The independent variables consist of the perceptions of the

various managers participating in the study of the level of existing corruption and its

impact on the operations of the firm. Because the study focuses on the computer industry

in the Mercosur, certain concepts and constructs within the survey questionnaire are

specific to the Mercosur nations.

Face validity of the survey questionnaire was determined by means of peer

review, indicating that the constructs were understandable. Because of the multi-lingual

context of this study, the process of establishing face validity occurred in English,

Spanish, and Portuguese. Native speakers of all three languages established face validity.

Peer review by academics involved in the areas of economics and sociology established

content and construct validity. A pilot test of the survey questionnaire conducted in the

summer of 2004 in the Mercosur nations established criterion validity.

109

Diachronic and synchronic reliability for the survey questionnaire were estimated

to be relatively low due to the nature of the study, which focuses on a single industry in a

relatively short time interval that can be viewed as a discrete moment in time. Diachronic

reliability refers to the stability of observations over time. Because the perceptions

regarding the impact of corruption on a firm in a microeconomic context are subject to a

large number of variables not directly measured by the test instrument, the perception of

corruption by an individual or a group of individuals in the same industry sector will

likely reflect the conditions of corruption at the moment. As a result, a test-and-retest

methodology, in which there is a significant amount of time between the testing, is likely

to produce differing results. This suggests that the data produced by the administration of

the test instrument will likely reflect perceptions at a given moment in time. Although we

assumed that synchronic reliability would be low due to sample’s size, it is likely to be

higher than diachronic reliability.

Synchronic reliability refers to the similarity of observations within the same time

frame. The research examined the perceptions of corruption in an industry sector; the

respondents were assumed to be similarly situated with respect to participation in the

industry though dissimilarly situated with respect to both their segment of the industry

and their home country of operations. The research also examined the same phenomenon

in the form of perceptions of corruption in the industry regardless of the specific position

of the respondent in the industry or the geographic location of the respondent.

110

A.2 Interview Data

The researcher, in person, conducted interviews of managers in the computer

industry in the Mercosur nations during the summer of 2004. The purpose of the

interviews was to gather additional data regarding corruption not revealed in the survey

questionnaire. It used a structured interview approach using closed-ended questions for

the majority of the interview process to minimize bias due to interaction between the

interviewer and interviewee. The closed-ended questions were useful for determining

frequencies, intensities of perceptions, and degrees of involvement. The interview

process also used open-ended questions at the end of the interview to obtain additional

information that may have been overlooked by the research in developing the closed-

ended questions.

The open-ended questions were thus intended to elicit additional information from

interviewees that supported a more in-depth analysis of the findings produced by more

quantitative types of research methods. In effect, the responses from open-ended

questions provided background information regarding the more subjective aspects of

perceptions towards corruption and its impact on the economic process in a broad

cultural, political, and business context. Open-ended questions are useful for exploratory

research that elicits information regarding positions regarding subjective issues such as

corruption. Additionally, the responses produced by open-ended questions can provide

some degree of guidance for the direction of future research by identifying factors not yet

considered in the design of formal research.

111

The following closed ended questions were used in the structured interview

format:

1. Do requests from officials for payments along with those required by regulations create a competitive disadvantage when compared to firms in other Mercosur nations?

2. Do requests from officials for payments along with those required by regulations create a competitive disadvantage in the global market?

3. Do you perceive requests from officials for payments along with those required by regulations as more or less than in other industries?

4. Do you perceive requests from officials for payments along with those required by regulations as increasing, decreasing, or about the same as in the past?

5. Do you think that requests from officials for payments in addition to those required by regulations as more, less, or about the same in your country when compared to other Mercosur nations?

To a large degree, the closed-ended questions were intended to elicit information

that could corroborate the data gathered through the survey test instrument. At the same

time, these inquiries should create a wider perspective regarding subjective factors such

as competitive advantage. In general, the closed-ended questions were anticipated to

produce a yes or no response. The interviewees, however, were not discouraged from

elaborating on their response.

The open-ended questions consisted of the following:

1. Considering the various areas of operation - building construction, employment, importing or exporting - of your industry’s firm, in what area is a request from an official for payments other than those required by regulations most likely to occur?

112

2. Do you believe that government policies and officials support your industry by removing barriers to commerce?

3. Do you believe that your industry would be more prosperous if government operations were more closely supervised or regulated?

4. Are you aware of any experiences of other firms resulting in the firm suffering economic harm from requests from officials for payments in addition to those required by regulations?

The following interview methodology called for recording each interview for

verification and transcription of the findings. In the closed-end portion of the interview,

the interviewer did not attempt to interact with the interviewee to either encourage or

discourage elaboration on the responses. In the open-ended portion of the interview, the

interviewer asked follow-up questions, the nature of which depends on the interviewees’

initial responses. The objective for the open-ended portion of this process was to elicit as

much information as the interviewee was willing to give regarding the issue of

corruption, even if the response strayed from the question’s intent.

The sampling methodology used for the interview was the random stratified

method. In this method, the entire population will be fit into mutually exclusive

subgroups or strata; the interviewees were selected at random from each stratum. The

strata used was based on the segments of the industry to obtain some degree of

representative sampling from each of the general segments with the objective of

maximizing the heterogeneity of the sample. In addition, there was some degree of

stratification based on the geographic location of the firm, because the researcher had

access only to a few geographic locations in the Mercosur nations. As a result, the

113

geographic stratification represented a limitation in the methodology used in the study;

the results of the interview process were qualified according to the actual geographic

stratification. Although it would be ideal to include only those individuals in the sample

population for the interview process that have completed the survey test instrument to

facilitate comparison between the survey and interview results, the interview process had

incorporated some individuals who did not complete the survey test instrument. To some

degree, this could provide broader qualitative information regarding perceptions of the

interviewees.

A.3 External Data

Because the study is designed to correlate the actual performance of firms in the

computer industry with the perceptions of corruption of the managers of firms, the data

collection procedure required access to external data regarding the performance of the

firm. This created an inherent limitation in the data-gathering process, as only managers

from firms with publicly available financial information could be included in the study.

This selection criterion excluded private firms that did not make such information

available. It also required some degree of pre-screening of respondents to insure that they

were employed by a firm that made the information available.

A.4 Data Collection Methodology

Because the study requires a relatively large number of respondents from a single

industry to meet the objectives for confidence and reliability, three separate data

collection methodologies were developed. The first methodology involved data collection

114

in person in the Mercosur nations during the Summer of 2004 and involved a chain

referral approach. The second data collection methodology was used in the Fall of 2004

and involved the use of email solicitation of participants from the computer industry in

the Mercosur nations. This methodology is viable due to the nature of the computer

industry, where virtually all firms have an internet presence, and managers are

accustomed to using email and the internet for communications. The third methodology

involved contacting either by telephone or by mail firms identified through physical

business directories, which were collected for each Mercosur nation during the summer

of 2004 and winter break of 2005, when the researcher traveled to the Mercosur nations.

While each of these methodologies have limitations in the sampling techniques that can

introduce error into the findings, they were deemed to be the most appropriate for use

with the inherent constraints of data collection from international sources over a widely

disbursed geographic area.

A.5 Data Collection in the Mercosur Nations

Because of the sensitive nature of the subject matter of the study that involved

investigation into corruption, initial contact was made with academics and industry

groups in the Mercosur nations to establish credibility in the industry. The general

procedure was to contact a key individual in various universities, ministries and industry

associations, explain the nature of the study, and solicit their assistance in obtaining

referrals. In addition, several senior managers from computer related firms in Brazil were

approached directly. Although this process was relatively time consuming, it resulted in

115

the study obtaining referrals to individuals in the computer industry who agreed to

participate in the study.

Because of the use of chain referral method of sampling, the ideal of achieving

proportionate random sampling of the study population was not achieved for the data

collected in the study’s initial phase. There was also a significant possibility that the

independence of the sampling would be compromised due to peer pressure placed on

respondents urging them to participate in the study. The primary concerns at this point in

the study was establishing sufficient contacts within the computer industry to support an

effective data gathering process. Additionally, an adequate number of respondents were

needed to conduct a pilot test to ensure that the survey questionnaire was predictive of the

concepts that it intended to measure. The chain referral method was necessary for an

outsider to the industry to access the sample population, given the sensitive nature of the

subject under study. Thus, the data gathered for the pilot test had a diminished level of

independence.

An additional limitation of this method of sampling is the strong likelihood that

some firms and individuals would be overlooked due to their lack of association with the

referring entity. The likely result is the exclusion of a significant portion of the sample

population from the sample; as a result, this can have a negative impact on the confidence

level of the study.

A.6 Pilot Study Analysis

The initial weeks of the field research period involved conducting the pilot study

to verify that the survey questionnaire test instrument was predictive and whether any

116

modifications of the test instrument would be necessary for the study’s main portion. The

pilot study was a critical component of the research, verifying that the data collection

methods were feasible and that the data could be used in the study’s econometric model.

The data used in the pilot test was gathered during the summer research period from the

administration of the survey questionnaires to 72 respondents in the Mercosur nations.

The outcome of the pilot study indicated that the survey questionnaire was predictive;

modifications would not be necessary prior to the dissemination of the questionnaire to

respondents for the study’s main portion. It further established that the data produced by

the survey questionnaire could function as a proxy measure for the impact of corruption

on the activities of individual firms and establish the independent variables of the study.

Finally, the pilot test established a correlation between the independent variables and the

dependent variable of return on assets (ROI), which was data collected from sources

exogenous to the survey questionnaire. Computation of ROI is the net income of the firm

divided by the total assets of the firm.

A concern during the initial phase of the data collection period was the possibility

of self-selection bias, which occurs when a relatively small number of possible

respondents participate in a survey type of study. This tends to skew the findings towards

the perspective of those individuals who choose to participate in a study, which may not

reflect the whole population. This is a non-sampling type of error that can occur for a

variety of reasons, including the perception of the respondents that their anonymity

would not be preserved in the research process. The response rate during the pilot study

phase of the research was relatively high at 79%. This reduced the level of concern

117

regarding the impact of self-selection bias on the findings. This indicated that there was

no need to alter the methods used to solicit participation in the study, including the

content of the solicitation letter that would be sent to perspective respondents in the

future via the internet.

The high percentage of respondents willing to participate in the study also

demonstrated that the method used to sample the population was viable, as it would likely

produce a sufficient number of participants to support a study conducted on a larger

scale. Email solicited 38 of the respondents in the pilot study by using a description of the

study and mentioning that the researcher was referred to the potential respondent by a

trade association or other manager that supported the aims and objectives of the study. At

this stage of the data gathering process, the primary concern was obtaining a sufficient

number of respondents to support a large-scale study. Issues such as the bias that can

occur using a chain referral method of solicitation were believed to be minimal due to the

intent to use a random solicitation process based on the internet listings of firms in the

computer industry.

The pilot study focused on establishing the criterion validity of the survey

questionnaire before deemed suitable for dissemination to a wider sample population. A

prerequisite for establishing criterion validity was determining reliability, which is the

extent to which the measure yields consistent results when applied repeatedly. Face

validity and content validity were established prior to the survey instrument’s gathering

the data for the pilot study. The design of the survey questionnaire was both postdictive

118

and concurrent - it asked respondents to provide information regarding their perceptions

and experiences that occurred in the past and their perceptions and experiences at the

current time. Criterion validity in this research was relatively important due to the

development of variations from the preexisting measures used by other researchers to

quantify the subjective concept of corruption and perceptions of the level of corruption.

In this study, the predictor variables were the responses to the various questions

contained in the survey questionnaire regarding perceptions of corruption and the

criterion variable was ROI.

To accomplish the regression analysis, the raw data produced by the survey

questionnaire had to be coded; this provided an opportunity to develop the coding frame

to be used for the study’s main part. The coding frame was based on the structure of the

survey questionnaire that provided structure in terms of the segment of the computer

industry of the respondent and the pre-coded nature of the questions asked of the

respondent. Exogenous information supporting the coding was the nation of origin of the

respondent and the ROI. As a result, the data produced during the pilot study could be

coded in terms of the industry segment and the nation of origin to determine whether

these variables produced any difference in outcome. During the coding process, an

unanticipated difficulty arose due to few respondents from the semiconductor, computer

supply, and other categories established to identify the segment of the computer industry.

As a result, the pilot study analysis did not include industry segment analysis, confining

itself to overall analysis and analysis by nation of the respondents. Table A.1 shows the

119

distribution of industry segments produced from the pilot study data; Table A.2 shows the

number of respondents from each of the four Mercosur nations.

Table A.1: Industry Data

Software Computer Mfg.

Computer Supply

Peripheral Mfg.

Semi-conductor Mfg

Networking or Other Other

16 17 6 12 3 18 0

Table A.2: Respondents from the Mercosur Nations

Brazil Argentina Paraguay Uruguay 33 26 6 7

The pilot study required establishing whether there were regression correlations

between the level of corruption perceived by the respondents and the ROI. ROI is

sometimes termed return on assets (ROA) with the two designations often used

interchangeably. The ROI was the dependent variable of the study. The relationship

between the perception of corruption, and the ROI was the foundation of the study’s

theoretical premise that firms operating in a more corrupt environment will have a lower

growth rate of ROI than firms operating in a less corrupt environment. Determining the

growth rate of the ROI required the averaging of the reported rate of growth for firms

over the previous three years. Collecting this data independently from the survey test

questionnaire was relatively time-consuming due to the need to identify the sources of

data for the firms with managers participating in the study. To simplify the regression

analysis, the rates of growth were rounded to the nearest .5%. Table A.3 shows the ROI

and the number of respondents within each of the ROI categories.

Table A.3: ROI and Respondents ROI -2% -0.25% 1% 2.50% 3% 4% 9% # of Respondents 6 14 8 9 16 8 11

120

The correlations between different variables are shown in table A.4. We found

that the responses resulted into high correlation between different variables used to

measure the level of corruption.

Table A. 4: Correlations between different variables

ROI Q_2 Q_3 Q_4 Q_5 Q_6 Q_7 Q_8 ROI 1 -.553(**) -.657(**) -.702(**) -.562(**) -.426(**) -.180 .733(**) . .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .131 .000 72 72 72 72 72 72 72 72Q_2 -.553(**) 1 .735(**) .785(**) .707(**) .536(**) .655(**) -.698(**) .000 . .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 72 72 72 72 72 72 72 72Q_3 -.657(**) .735(**) 1 .730(**) .667(**) .658(**) .558(**) -.759(**) .000 .000 . .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 72 72 72 72 72 72 72 72Q_4 -.702(**) .785(**) .730(**) 1 .723(**) .568(**) .581(**) -.780(**) .000 .000 .000 . .000 .000 .000 .000 72 72 72 72 72 72 72 72Q_5 -.562(**) .707(**) .667(**) .723(**) 1 .665(**) .616(**) -.803(**) .000 .000 .000 .000 . .000 .000 .000 72 72 72 72 72 72 72 72Q_6 -.426(**) .536(**) .658(**) .568(**) .665(**) 1 .628(**) -.721(**) .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 . .000 .000 72 72 72 72 72 72 72 72Q_7 -.180 .655(**) .558(**) .581(**) .616(**) .628(**) 1 -.594(**) .131 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 . .000 72 72 72 72 72 72 72 72Q_8 .733(**) -.698(**) -.759(**) -.780(**) -.803(**) -.721(**) -.594(**) 1 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 . 72 72 72 72 72 72 72 72

** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).

Because of the high and significant correlations between different variables of

corruption, we performed factor analysis to see whether there is any underlying construct.

Table A.5 shows the result of factor analysis.

121

Table A.5: Factor Analysis Communalities

Initial ExtractionQ_2 1.000 .743Q_3 1.000 .742Q_4 1.000 .762Q_5 1.000 .763Q_6 1.000 .638Q_7 1.000 .594Q_8 1.000 .818

Extraction Method: Principal Component Analysis.

Total Variance Explained

Initial Eigenvalues Extraction Sums of Squared

Loadings Component Total

% of Variance

Cumulative % Total

% of Variance

Cumulative %

1 5.059 72.275 72.275 5.059 72.275 72.2752 .557 7.951 80.226 3 .482 6.885 87.111 4 .341 4.865 91.976 5 .223 3.185 95.161 6 .191 2.730 97.891 7 .148 2.109 100.000

Extraction Method: Principal Component Analysis.

Component Matrix(a)

Component 1 Q_2 .862Q_3 .861Q_4 .873Q_5 .873Q_6 .798Q_7 .771Q_8 -.904

Extraction Method: Principal Component Analysis. a 1 components extracted.

122

There exists an underlying construct measured by the seven questions of the scale,

the Corruption Level. Henceforth, for the purpose of analysis, we will use this Corruption

Level as the variable indicating level of corruption as perceived by the respondents.

Next, we performed the regression analysis with Corruption Level as independent

variable impacting ROI. The results are shown in table A.6.

Table A.6: Regression Analysis with ROI as dependent variable and Corruption

Level as independent variable

Variables Entered/Removed(b)

Model Variables Entered

Variables Removed Method

1

Corruption Level . Enter

a All requested variables entered. b Dependent Variable: ROI

Model Summary

Model R R

Square

Adjusted R

Square

Std. Error of the

Estimate 1 .650(a) .422 .414 .0245341

a Predictors: (Constant), Corruption Level

ANOVA(b)

Model Sum of Squares Df

Mean Square F Sig.

Regression .031 1 .031 51.178 .000(a)

Residual .042 70 .001

1

Total .073 71 a Predictors: (Constant), Corruption Level

b Dependent Variable: ROI

123

Coefficients(a)

Unstandardized Coefficients

Standardized

Coefficients

Model B Std.

Error Beta t Sig. (Constant) .027 .003 9.319 .0001 Corruption

Level -.021 .003 -.650 -7.154 .000

a Dependent Variable: ROI

The results of regression analysis suggest that the model is significant and

explains 42.2% of the variation in ROI. Based on the outcome of the pilot study, no

changes were made in the survey questionnaire as the preliminary findings of the pilot

study tended to support the research model that a higher rate of corruption results in a

lower rate of growth for firms in the computer industry.

A.7: Data Collection through the Internet

The data collection strategy is functionally bifurcated, which is due to the nature

of the study in which the data sources are located at a significant distance from the

researcher. The first stage of data collection involved the use of in-person contact with

respondents and the development of a chain referral system in the Mercosur nations. This

approach generated approximately 40% of the total number of respondents required for

the study. The second and third stages of data collection involved direct solicitation of

participation from managers of computer firms in the Mercosur nations by means of the

internet, and by physical business directories collected in the Mercosur nations.

124

The internet data collection strategy was intended to introduce a greater degree of

randomness into the data collection process to reduce the impact of a lack of

independence in the sampling obtained by means of referrals. The members of the study

population were identified based on online business directories, internet listings, and

other internet-based advertising or promotional sites. Another way to introduce a greater

degree of randomness into the data collection process to reduce the impact of a lack of

independence in the sampling obtained by means of referrals, involved contacting either

by telephone or by mail firms identified through physical business directories. These

business directories were collected for each Mercosur nation during the summer of 2004

and winter break of 2005, when the researcher traveled to the Mercosur nations. Because

of the nature of the study that required access to public information regarding the

financial performance of the firm, identifying the firms also required a determination of

sources of information regarding financial performance. Firms identified from the various

data sources that lacked such information were excluded from participating.

Following identification of the firms and their email addresses, members of the

firm were contacted directly to solicit participation. This strategy was successful in

attracting a relatively high response rate from the individuals solicited for participation in

the study. The high response rate may have been due to the nature of the study, with

considerable interest among managers in the Mercosur nations regarding the impact of

corruption on business operations. Another factor influencing the high response rate was

the identification of the study in the subject line of the email solicitation as an academic

and confidential need for data on the industry. This was necessary to reduce the

125

possibility that the members of the study population did not delete the solicitation before

reading it.

The content of the solicitation email followed the same fundamental structure as

the solicitation procedure for respondents using mail or other means. It contained a cover

letter explaining the purpose of the study, its value for academic research, its value to the

specific industry under study, and an assurance of confidentiality. It also contained

information regarding various individuals and trade associations that support the study to

establish credibility. The solicitation also briefly outlined the expectations from the

respondent regarding filling out and returning by email the relatively short survey

questionnaires. The email solicitations were sent to the sample population in Spanish or

Portuguese in accordance with the country in which the respondent was located. The

introductory materials also noted that the study was based in the United States.

The data collection methodology for the email solicitation called for the

distribution of the survey questionnaire to the individuals who agreed to participate in the

study shortly after receiving consent. A short time frame between receiving consent to

participate and the distribution of the survey questionnaire was deemed important for

insuring that the respondents did not forget that they agreed to participate in the study.

The data collection plan allowed ten days for the return of the completed questionnaire,

and a follow-up email was sent to non-respondents to remind them to fill out the

questionnaire. A second questionnaire was sent to the non-respondents along with the

reminder in the event that they had deleted the original transmission of the questionnaire.

126

The process of solicitation of the firms and mangers to participate in the study

was time consuming during the initial preparation of materials, but various computer

programs could automate the process. The solicitation materials were automatically

customized for the specific respondent, which involved the insertion of a name and

address. The process of tracking incoming completed questionnaires, matching the

questionnaires with the firm’s financial data, and the generation of reminders for the

respondents that failed to fill out the survey questionnaires was also automated. The

manual processes were limited to the entry of data into the various coding frames upon

the return of a completed survey questionnaire. This automation of processes helped to

realize the significant advantages of the internet data collection methodology due to its

rapid speed and relatively low cost.

The sampling strategy was required to compensate for the disproportionate size of

the computer industry in Brazil and Argentina when compared to Paraguay and Uruguay.

Because of this disproportionate size, a random sampling of the study population would

produce overall findings more likely to reflect the conditions and perceptions in the two

larger nations, which would dominate the total data. The strategy adopted to compensate

for this issue was the use of the disproportionate stratified sampling method that draws a

disproportionate number of samples from certain strata when compared to other strata.

When the total number of responses exceeded the minimum number necessary to support

the desired confidence interval and level, the random selection process used to select the

127

samples for the study contained a factor to create a disproportionate representation from

the two smaller Mercosur nations.

The use of the bifurcated data collection process that used both chain referrals and

random selection via the internet also compensated for the sampling difficulty associated

with collection of data via the internet of firms without a website or email capacity. This

problem represented an inherent structural flaw in the methodology, where members of

the sample population that could not be reached through the internet would be excluded

from the study. Because the study involved the computer industry, however, this

structural flaw was likely to have had minimal impact on the data collection process.

Nonetheless, the use of the chain referral method for some of collection of data could

potentially access members of the study population lacking access to internet resources.

128

Appendix B: Correlations Between all variables Table B.1: Correlation between different variables

ROI Uruguay Brazil Argentina Paraguay Software Com_Man Com_Supp Semc_Man Networki Periph Others Corruption

Level 1 -.492(**) -.188(**) .409(**) .358(**) .008 .040 -.001 .007 -.003 -.027 -.024 -.960(**) . .000 .000 .000 .000 .845 .345 .991 .870 .947 .525 .576 .000

ROI 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560

-.492(**) 1 -.412(**) -.303(**) -.120(**) -.066 -.046 -.029 .052 .105(*) .032 -.043 .476(**) .000 . .000 .000 .004 .118 .280 .488 .215 .013 .453 .306 .000

Uruguay 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560

-.188(**) -.412(**) 1 -.612(**) -.242(**) .059 -.028 .012 -.027 -.080 -.021 .079 .185(**) .000 .000 . .000 .000 .164 .501 .786 .528 .058 .616 .061 .000

Brazil 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560

.409(**) -.303(**) -.612(**) 1 -.179(**) -.005 .042 .021 -.009 .011 .019 -.077 -.399(**) .000 .000 .000 . .000 .902 .323 .614 .840 .786 .650 .070 .000

Argentina 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560

.358(**) -.120(**) -.242(**) -.179(**) 1 -.008 .048 -.019 -.010 -.019 -.041 .049 -.347(**) .000 .004 .000 .000 . .841 .255 .662 .817 .656 .330 .244 .000

Paraguay 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560

.008 -.066 .059 -.005 -.008 1 -.159(**) -.181(**) -.173(**) -.162(**) -.163(**) -.174(**) -.003

.845 .118 .164 .902 .841 . .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .947 Software 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560

.040 -.046 -.028 .042 .048 -.159(**) 1 -.168(**) -.160(**) -.150(**) -.151(**) -.161(**) -.041

.345 .280 .501 .323 .255 .000 . .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .328 Com_Man 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560

-.001 -.029 .012 .021 -.019 -.181(**) -.168(**) 1 -.183(**) -.171(**) -.172(**) -.184(**) .009 .991 .488 .786 .614 .662 .000 .000 . .000 .000 .000 .000 .836

Com_Supp 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560

.007 .052 -.027 -.009 -.010 -.173(**) -.160(**) -.183(**) 1 -.163(**) -.164(**) -.175(**) -.007

.870 .215 .528 .840 .817 .000 .000 .000 . .000 .000 .000 .867 Semc_Man 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560

-.003 .105(*) -.080 .011 -.019 -.162(**) -.150(**) -.171(**) -.163(**) 1 -.153(**) -.164(**) -.008 .947 .013 .058 .786 .656 .000 .000 .000 .000 . .000 .000 .858

Networki 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560

-.027 .032 -.021 .019 -.041 -.163(**) -.151(**) -.172(**) -.164(**) -.153(**) 1 -.165(**) .038 .525 .453 .616 .650 .330 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 . .000 .370

Periph 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560

-.024 -.043 .079 -.077 .049 -.174(**) -.161(**) -.184(**) -.175(**) -.164(**) -.165(**) 1 .011 .576 .306 .061 .070 .244 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 . .803

Others 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560

-.960(**) .476(**) .185(**) -.399(**) -.347(**) -.003 -.041 .009 -.007 -.008 .038 .011 1 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .947 .328 .836 .867 .858 .370 .803 .

Corruption Level 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560 560

** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed). * Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed).

129

Appendix C

Questionnaire

1. Please circle the response that best describes your firm’s industry:

software computer manufacturing

computer supply semiconductor manufacturing

networking or other services peripheral manufacturing

Other (please specify) ____________________________________

2. In the past year, events have resulted in payments to officials that were in addition to

payments required by regulations.

Strongly Strongly Disagree Disagree Agree Agree (1) (2) (3) (4)

3. In the past year, more than one official has asked for payments in addition to payments

required by regulations.

Strongly Strongly Disagree Disagree Agree Agree (1) (2) (3) (4)

4. Over the past three years, it has been difficult to commence projects due to the need to

make payments to officials other than those required by regulations.

Strongly Strongly Disagree Disagree Agree Agree (1) (2) (3) (4)

130

5. Estimating the impact of payments to officials other than those required by regulations

is an important part of project planning.

Strongly Strongly Disagree Disagree Agree Agree (1) (2) (3) (4)

6. If a firm refuses to make payments to officials other than those required by regulations,

it damages the firm’s competitive position.

Strongly Strongly Disagree Disagree Agree Agree (1) (2) (3) (4)

7. It is difficult to take full advantage of the Mercosur trading arrangements due to

difficulties with bureaucrats in other Mercosur nations that require payments other than

those required by regulations.

Strongly Strongly Disagree Disagree Agree Agree (1) (2) (3) (4)

8. The amounts of payments other than those required by regulations made to officials in

other Mercosur nations exceed the amount in my home nation.

Strongly Strongly Disagree Disagree Agree Agree (1) (2) (3) (4)