bid-function envelopes or how to estimate capitalization

60
Bid-Function Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization ECN741, Urban Economics Professor Yinger

Upload: rangle

Post on 23-Feb-2016

27 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Bid-Function Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization . ECN741, Urban Economics Professor Yinger. Lecture Outline Methodological Challenges Examples Recent Publications My Cleveland Application. Outline . Methodological Challenges 1.Functional form 2.Defining School Quality ( S ) - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Bid-Function Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

ECN741, Urban EconomicsProfessor Yinger

Page 2: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Lecture Outline Methodological Challenges

Examples

Recent Publications

My Cleveland Application

Outline

Page 3: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Methodological Challenges 1. Functional form

2. Defining School Quality (S)

3. Controlling for neighborhood traits

4. Controlling for housing characteristics

Challenges

Page 4: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Functional Form As discussed in previous classes, simply

regressing V on S (with or without logs) is not satisfactory.

Regressing ln{V} on S and S2 is pretty reasonable—but cannot yield structural coefficients.

To obtain structural coefficients, one must use either nonlinear regression or the Rosen 2-step method (with a general form for the envelope and a good instrument for the 2nd step). Both approaches are difficult!

Challenges

Page 5: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Defining School Quality Most studies use a test score measure.

A few use a value-added test score.

A few use a graduation rate.

Some use inputs (spending or student/teacher ratio).

A few use both, but the use of multiple output measures is rare (but sensible!).

Challenges

Page 6: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Neighborhood Controls Data quality varies widely; some studies have many

neighborhood controls.

Many fixed-effects approaches are possible to account for unobservables, e.g.:

Border fixed effects (cross section)

Neighborhood fixed effects (panel)

Another approach is to use an instrumental variable.

Challenges

Page 7: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Border Fixed Effects Popularized by Black (1999); appears in at least

16 studies.

Define elementary school attendance zone boundary segments.

Define a border fixed effect (BFE) for each segment, equal to one for housings within a selected distance from the boundary.

Drop all observations farther from boundary.

Challenges

Page 8: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Border Fixed Effects, 2

School

House Sale

Boundary Segment

Challenges

Page 9: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Border Fixed Effects, 3 The idea is that the border areas are like

neighborhoods, so the BFEs pick up unobservables shared by houses on each side of the border.

But bias comes from un-observables that are correlated with S; by design, BFEs are weakly correlated (i.e. take on the same value for different values of S).

Challenges

Page 10: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Border Fixed Effects, 4 BFEs have three other weaknesses:

They shift the focus from across-district differences in S to within-district differences in S, which are smaller and less interesting.

They require the removal of a large share of the observations (and could introduce selection bias).

They ignore sorting; that is, they assume that neighborhood traits are not affected by the fact that sorting leads to people with different preferences on either side of the border bid.

Challenges

Page 11: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

BFE and Sorting Two recent articles (Kane et al. and Bayer et al.) find

significant differences in demographics across attendance-zone boundaries.

Bayer et al. then argue that these demographic differences become neighborhood traits and they include them as controls.

I argue that these differences are implausible as neighborhood traits, but are measures of demand—which do not belong in an hedonic. As Rosen argued long ago, the envelope is not a function of

demand variables.

Including demand variables re-introduces the endogeneity problem and changes the meaning of the results.

Challenges

Page 12: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Other Fixed Effects Other types of fixed effects are possible, e.g.,

Tract fixed effects (with a large sample or a panel)

School district fixed effects (with a panel).

House fixed effects (with a panel).

These approaches account for some unobservable factors, but may also introduce problems.

Challenges

Page 13: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Problems with Fixed Effects They all limit the variation in the data for estimating

capitalization.

School district fixed effects, for example, imply that the coefficient of S must be estimated based only on changes in S.

They may account for demand factors, such as income, that should not be included in a hedonic.

Because household and tract income are highly correlated, including tract dummies effectively controls for household income, resulting in the same problems as those caused by BFEs.

My interpretation is not popular. Economists seem to prefer more controls even if they do not make

theoretical sense.

Challenges

Page 14: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

The IV Approach With omitted variables, the included explanatory

variables are likely to be correlated with the error term.A natural correction is to use an instrumental variable—and

2SLS.

However, credible IVs are difficult to find. For example, the well-known 2005 Chay/Greenstone article

in the JPE estimates a hedonic for clean air using a policy announcement as an instrument.

But many studies (some mentioned below) show that announcements affect house values so the C/G instrument fails the exogeneity test.

Challenges

Page 15: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Controlling for Housing Traits A housing hedonic requires control variables

for the structural characteristics of housing.

Because housing, neighborhood, and school traits are correlated, good controls for housing traits are important (but surprisingly limited in many studies).

Challenges

Page 16: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Housing Traits, 2 If good data on housing traits are available, one

strategy for a cross-section is to estimate the hedonic in two stages.

Stage 1: Define fixed effects for the smallest observable neighborhood type (e.g. block group or tract); regress V on housing traits and these FE’s—with no neighborhood traits.

Stage 2: Use the coefficients of the FE’s as the dependent variable in a second stage with neighborhood traits on the right side; the number of observations equals the number of neighborhoods.

Challenges

Page 17: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Housing Traits, 3 This approach has two advantages:

The coefficients of the housing traits cannot be biased due to missing neighborhood variables.

The second stage need not follow the same form as the first, so this approach adds functional-form flexibility.

Note that the standard errors in this stage must be corrected for heteroskedasticity.The coefficient of each FE is based on a different

number of observations.

Challenges

Page 18: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Selected Recent Examples

Bayer, Ferriera, and MacMillan (JPE 2007)

Clapp, Nanda, and Ross (JUE 2008)

Bogin (Syracuse dissertation 2011), building on Figlio and Lucas (AER 2004)

Yinger (working paper 2012)

Recent Studies

Page 19: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

B/F/M B/F/M have census data from the San

Francisco area. They estimate a linear hedonic with

BFE’s, pooling sales and rental data. They find that adding the BFE’s cuts the

impact of school quality on housing prices. They find that adding neighborhood income

cuts the impact of school quality even more.

Recent Studies

Page 20: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

B/F/M Hedonic

Recent Studies

Page 21: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

B/F/M Problems They estimate a linear hedonic, which rules

out sorting (in an article about sorting!) and is inconsistent with their own bid functions.

They control for neighborhood income (implausible theoretical basis).

They have only 3 housing traits and 3 other location controls (+ BFE’s).

One neighborhood control (density) is a function of the dependent variable; I guess they never took urban economics!

Recent Studies

Page 22: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

C/N/R They use a panel of housing transactions in

Connecticut between 1994 and 2004 They use tract fixed effects to control for

neighborhood quality. They look at math scores and cost factors

(e.g. student poverty) They find that tract fixed effects lower the

estimate of capitalization even below its level with income and other demographics.

Recent Studies

Page 23: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

C/N/R Hedonic

Recent Studies

Page 24: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

C/N/R Problems They use a semi-log form with only one term

for S, which rules out sorting. They control for neighborhood demographics

and tract FEs, which raises the same issue as B/F/M: Should demand variables be included?

They have only 4 housing traits and 2 non-demand neighborhood traits.

They include fraction owner-occupied, which appears to be endogenous.

Recent Studies

Page 25: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Bogin The Florida school accountability program hands

out “failing” grades to some schools. The Figlio/Lucas paper (AER 2004) looks at the impact of this designation on property values.

The national No Child Left Behind Act also hands out “failing” grades. The 2011 Bogin essay looks at the impact of this designation on property values around Charlotte, North Carolina.

In both cases, the failing grades are essentially uncorrelated with other measures of school quality.

Recent Studies

Page 26: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Bogin 2 Bogin finds that a failing designation lowers property values

by about 6%.

This effect peaks about 7 months after the announcement and fades out after one year.

Bogin also provides a clear interpretation of results with this “change” set-up.

Because of possible re-sorting, the change in house values cannot be interpreted as a willingness to pay.

A failing designation might change the type of people who move into a neighborhood.

Consider the following figure:

Recent Studies

Page 27: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Bogin 3

Recent Studies

Page 28: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Estimates with a Derived Envelope Finally, I would like to present some results for both the hedonic

and the underlying bid functions from the application of the method I have developed using data from a large metropolitan area.

This method has several advantages:

It avoids the endogeneity problem in the Rosen 2-step approach.

It avoids inconsistency between the bid functions and their envelope (the hedonic equation).

It includes most parametric forms for a hedonic as special cases.

It allows for household heterogeneity.

It leads to tests of key sorting theorems.

A New Approach

Page 29: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

My Envelope The form derived in my last lecture:

and X(λ) is the Box-Cox form.

A starting point is a quadratic form, which corresponds to μ = -∞ and σ3 = 1

A New Approach

132

( ) ( )( )10

2 2

1ˆ EP C S S

1 2 3 2 31 ; (1 ) / ; 1/ ;

Page 30: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

The Brasington Data All home sales in Ohio in 2000, with

detailed housing characteristics and house location; compiled by Prof. David Brasington.

Matched to:◦ School district and characteristics◦ Census block group and characteristics◦ Police district and characteristics◦ Air and water pollution data

I focus on the 5-county Cleveland area and add many neighborhood traits.

A New Approach

Page 31: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

My Two-Step Approach Step 1: Estimate the envelope using my

functional form assumptions to identify the price elasticity of demand, μ.

◦ Step 1A: Estimate hedonic with neighborhood fixed effects

◦ Step 1B: Estimate PE{S, t} for the sample of neighborhoods with their coefficients from Step 1A as the dependent variable.

Step 2: Estimate the impact of income and other factors (except price) on demand.

A New Approach

Page 32: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Neighborhood Fixed Effects Start with Census block groups containing

more than one observation.

Split block-groups in more than one school district.

Total number of “neighborhoods” in Cleveland area sub-sample: 1,665.

A New Approach

Page 33: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Step 1A: Run Hedonic Regression with Neighborhood Fixed Effects

Dependent variable: Log of sales price in 2000.

Explanatory variables: ◦ Structural housing characteristics.◦ Corrections for within-neighborhood variation in

seven locational traits.◦ Neighborhood fixed effects.

22,880 observations in Cleveland subsample.

A New Approach

Page 34: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Table 1. Variable Definitions and Results for Basic Hedonic with Neighborhood Fixed Effects

Variable Definition Coefficient Std. ErrorOne Story House has one story - 0.0072 0.0050Brick House is made of bricks 0.0153*** 0.0052Basement House has a finished basement 0.0308*** 0.0050Garage House has a garage 0.1414*** 0.0067Air Cond. House has central air conditioning 0.0254*** 0.0055

Fireplaces Number of fireplaces 0.0316*** 0.0038Bedrooms Number of bedrooms - 0.0082*** 0.0028Full Baths Number of full bathrooms 0.0601*** 0.0042Part Baths Number of partial bathrooms 0.0412*** 0.0041Age of House Log of the age of the house - 0.0839*** 0.0032House Area Log of square feet of living area 0.4237*** 0.0086

Lot Area Log of lot size 0.0844*** 0.0037Outbuildings Number of outbuildings 0.1320*** 0.0396Porch House has a porch 0.0327*** 0.0073Deck House has a deck 0.0545*** 0.0053Pool House has a pool 0.0910*** 0.0180Date of Sale Date of house sale (January 1=1, December

31=365) 0.0002*** 0.0000

A New Approach

Page 35: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Table 1. Variable Definitions and Results for Basic Hedonic with Neighborhood Fixed

Effects

Variable Definition Coefficient Std. ErrorCommute 1a Employment wtd. commuting dist. (house-CBG), worksite 1 - 0.0952*** 0.0272

Commute 2a Employment wtd. commuting dist. (house-CBG), worksite 2 - 0.0991*** 0.0321

Commute 3a Employment wtd. commuting dist. (house-CBG), worksite 3 - 0.1239*** 0.0302

Commute 4a Employment wtd. commuting dist. (house-CBG), worksite 4 - 0.1012*** 0.0295

Commute 5a Employment wtd. commuting dist. (house-CBG), worksite 5 - 0.0942*** 0.0344

Dist. to Pub. Schoola Dist. to nearest pub. elementary school in district (house-CBG) - 0.0032 0.0061

Elem. School Scorea Average math and English test scores of nearest pub. elementary school relative to district (house-CBG)

0.0170 0.0197

Dist. to Private School Distance to nearest private school (house-CBG) - 0.0168*** 0.0057

Distance to Hazard Dist. to nearest environmental hazard (house-CBG) 0.0332*** 0.0082

Distance to Eriea Dist. to Lake Erie (if < 2; house-CBG) - 0.0021** 0.0010Distance to Ghettoa Dist. to black ghetto (if < 5; house-CBG) - 0.1020*** 0.0331

Distance to Airporta Dist. to Cleveland airport (if < 10; house-CBG) 0.0259** 0.0122

Dist. to CBG Center Distance from house to center of CBG - 0.0239*** 0.0074

Historic Districta In historic district on national register (house-CBG) 0.0120 0.0178

Elderly Housinga Within 1/2 mile of elderly housing project (house-CBG) - 0.0327* 0.0194

Family Housinga Within 1/2 mile of small family housing project (house-CBG) 0.0836** 0.0403

Large Hsg Projecta Within 1/2 mile of large family housing project (>200 units; house-CBG) - 0.0568** 0.0257

High Crime Distance to nearest high-crime location (house-CBG) 0.0701*** 0.0246

A New Approach

Page 36: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Step 1B: Run Envelope Regression

Dependent variable: coefficient of neighborhood fixed effect.

Explanatory variables: ◦ Public services and neighborhood amenities◦ Commuting variables◦ Income and property tax variables◦ Neighborhood control variables

A New Approach

Page 37: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

School Variables Variable Definition ----------------------------------------------------Elementary Average percent passing in 4th grade in nearest

elementary school on 5 state tests (math, reading, writing, science, and citizenship) minus the district average (for 1998-99 and 1999-2000).

High School The share of students entering the 12th grade who pass all 5 tests (= the passing rate on the tests, which reflects students who do not drop out, multiplied by the graduation rate, which indicates the share of students who stay in school) averaged over 1998-99 and 1999-2000.

Value Added A school district's sixth grade passing rate (on the 5 tests) in 2000-2001 minus its fourth grade passing rate in 1998-99.

Minority Teachers The share of a district’s teachers who belong to a minority group

A New Approach

Page 38: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Cleveland and East Cleveland

The Cleveland School District is unique in 2000 because:

◦ It was the only district to have private school vouchers

◦ It was the only district to have charter schools (except for 1 in Parma).

◦ The private and charter schools tend to be located near low-performing public schools.

The East Cleveland School District is unique in 2000 because◦ It received a state grant for school construction in 1998-2000

that was triple the size of its operating budget.

◦ No other district in the region received such a grant.

A New Approach

Page 39: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Table 2. Descriptive Statistics for Key Variables  Mean Std. Dev. Minimum Maximum

CBG Price per unit of Housing 84835.68 23331.25 32215.83 345162.50

Relative Elementary Scorea 0.3148 0.0894 0.0010 0.6465High School Passing Rate 0.3197 0.2040 0.0491 0.7675Elementary Value Addeda 24.0021 9.4164 1.0000 49.6000

Share Minority Teachersb 0.1329 0.1548 0.0010 0.6146Share Non-Black in CBGb 0.8022 0.3226 0.0010 1.0000Share Non-Hispanic in CBG 0.9623 0.0810 0.3673 1.0000Weighted Commuting Distance 13.2046 7.4567 7.2660 39.5236

Income Tax Ratec 0.0091 0.0012 0.0075 0.0100School Tax Rate 0.0309 0.0083 0.0172 0.0643City Tax Rated 0.0578 0.0140 0.0227 0.1033Tax Break Rated 0.0330 0.0121 0.0047 0.0791No A-to-S 0.1339 0.3407 0.0000 1.0000Not a City 0.1393 0.3464 0.0000 1.0000Crime Lowhigh 0.0252 0.1569 0.0000 1.0000Crime Highlow 0.1291 0.3354 0.0000 1.0000Crime Highhigh 0.1934 0.3951 0.0000 1.0000Crime Hotspot1 0.0126 0.1116 0.0000 1.0000Crime Hotspot2 0.0354 0.1849 0.0000 1.0000Crime Hotspot3 0.0847 0.2785 0.0000 1.0000Crime Hotspot4 0.2667 0.4423 0.0000 1.0000

A New Approach

Page 40: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Table 3. Definitions for Tax, Commuting, Crime, Pollution, and Ancillary School Variables

Variable DefinitionIncome Tax Rate School district income tax rateSchool Tax Rate*** School district effective property tax rateCity Tax Rate Effective city property tax rate beyond school taxTax Break Rate* Exemption rate for city property taxNo A-to-S Dummy: No A/V dataNot a City CBG not in a cityCommute 1*** Job-weighted distance to worksitesCommute 2** (Commute 1) squaredCrime Lowhigh*** Low property, high violent crimeCrime Highlow** High property, low violent crimeCrime Highhigh*** High property and violent crimeCrime Hotspot1*** CBG within ½ mile of crime hot spotCrime Hotspot2* CBG ½ to 1 mile from crime hot spotCrime Hotspot3*** CBG 1 to 2 miles from crime hot spotCrime Hotspot4*** CBG 2 to 5 miles from crime hot spotVillage** CBG receives police from a villageTownship*** CBG receives police from a townshipCounty Police*** CBG receives police from a countyCity Population*** Population of city (if CBG in a city)City Pop. Squared*** City population squared/10000City Pop. Cubed*** City population cubed/100002

City Pop. to 4th*** City pop. to the fourth power/100003

Smog*** CBG within 20 miles of air pollution cluster Smog Distance** (Smog) × Distance to cluster (not to the NW)Near Hazard*** CBG is within 1 mile of a hazardous waste siteDistance to Hazard*** Distance to nearest hazardous waste site (if <1)Value Added 1*** School district's 6th grade passing rate on 5 state tests in 2000-01 less its 4th grade rate in 1998-99Value Added 2*** (Value Added 1) squaredMinority Teachers 1 Share of district's teachers from a minority groupMinority Teachers 2* (Minority Teachers 1) squaredRel. Elem. Cle. 1*** Average 4th grade passing rate on 5 state tests in nearest elem. school minus district average (1998-99 and

1999-2000) for Cle. and E. Cle. onlyRel. Elem. Cle. 2*** (Rel. Elem. Cle. 1) squaredCleveland SD Dummy for Cleveland & E. Cleveland School DistrictsNear Public CBG is within 2 miles of public elem. schoolDistance to Public* (Near Public) × Distance to public schoolNear Private CBG is within 5 miles of a private schoolDistance to Private (Near Private) × Distance to private school

A New Approach

Page 41: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Table 4. Definitions for Other Geographic Controls

Variable DefinitionLakefront*** Within 2 miles of Lake ErieDistance to Lake (Lakefront) × (Distance to Lake Erie)Snowbelt 1*** (East of Pepper Pike) × (Distance to Lake Erie)Snowbelt 2*** (Snowbelt 1) squaredGhetto CBG in the black ghettoNear Ghetto CBG within 5 miles of ghetto centerNear Airport CBG within 10 miles of Cleveland airportAirport Distance (Near Airport) × (Distance to airport)Local Amenities*** No. of parks, golf courses, rivers, or lakes within ¼ mile of CBGFreeway CBG within ¼ mile of freewayRailroad CBG within ¼ mile of railroadShopping CBG within 1 mile of shopping centerHospital CBG within 1 mile of hospitalSmall Airport CBG within 1 mile of small airportBig Park*** CBG within 1 mile of regional parkHistoric District CBG within an historic districtNear Elderly PH CBG within ½ mile of elderly public housingNear Small Fam. PH*** CBG within ½ mile of small family public housingNear Big Fam. PH*** CBG within ½ mile of large family public housing (>200 units)Worksite 2** Fixed effect for worksite 2Worksite 3*** Fixed effect for worksite 3Worksite 4* Fixed effect for worksite 4Worksite 5 Fixed effect for worksite 5Geauga County Fixed effect for Geauga CountyLake County*** Fixed effect for Lake CountyLorain County*** Fixed effect for Lorain CountyMedina County Fixed effect for Medina County

 

A New Approach

Page 42: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Table 3A. Results for Ancillary School Variables

Variable Definition Coefficient Std. ErrorValue Added 1 School district's 6th grade passing

rate on 5 state tests in 2000-2001 minus its 4th grade passing rate in 1998-99

0.0120*** 0.0039

Value Added 2 (Value Added 1) squared - 0.0002*** 0.0001

Minority Teachers 1

Share of district's teachers from a minority group

0.3379 0.2177

Minority Teachers 2

(Minority Teachers 1) squared - 0.7334* 0.3967

Rel. Elem. Cle. 1 Average 4th grade passing rate on 5 state tests in nearest elementary school minus district average (1998-99 and 1999-2000) for Cleveland and E. Cleveland only

- 1.5045*** 0.4066

Rel. Elem. Cle. 2 (Rel. Elem. Cle. 1) squared 1.8398*** 0.4951

Cleveland SD Dummy for Cleveland & E. Cleveland School Districts

0.1414 0.2232

A New Approach

Page 43: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Table 5A. Specification Tests and Results for Key School Variables

Variable Linear Quadratic

Nonlinear Estimation of μ’s with σ3 = 1

Nonlinear Estimation of

μ’s, Various σ3’sRelative Elementary Score First Term 0.1268** 0.2448 0.0022*** - 0..0034

(0.0581) (0.2480) (0.0008) (0..0041) Second Term - - 0.2086 89.4295 0.3161

(0.3584) (163.9870) (0.2099) μ -∞ -∞ - 0.3694*** - 0.8141***

(0.1342) (0.687) σ3 ∞ 1 1 1/5High School Passing Rate

First Term 0.4826*** - 0.0862 0.2168*** 0.7375***(0.0600) (0.2631) (0.0339) (0.0692)

Second Term - 0.6049** ~ 1.3087** 0.4636***(0.2849) (0.5294) (0.1758)

μ -∞ -∞ - 0.7564*** - 1.0752** (0.2762) (0..4899)

σ3 ∞ 1 1 5

A New Approach

Page 44: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

A New Approach

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6

Envelope for Relative Elementary Score

Quadratic Envelope Full Nonlinear Envelope Bid Function

Relative Test Score in Nearest Elementary School

log{

PE}

Page 45: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

A New Approach

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8

Envelope for High School Passing Rate

Quadratic Envelope Full Nonlinear Envelope Bid Function

High School Passing Rate in School District

log{

PE}

Page 46: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Estimated Impacts

The Impact of Amenities on Housing Prices (Along Envelope)Change in Price of House Due to Raising

the Amenity from:

AmenitySelected Value of Amenity

Minimum to Selected Value

Selected Value to Maximum

Relative Elementary Score 0.100 15.8% 6.7%High School Passing Rate 0.221 -3.5% 32.6%

A New Approach

The Impact of Amenities on Housing Bids (Along Illustrated Bid Function)Change in Price of House Due to Raising the Amenity

from:Amenity Minimum to Maximum ValueRelative Elementary Score* 7.5%High School Passing Rate 17.7%* Minimum set at 0.1.

Page 47: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Conclusions, Theory The envelope derived in my paper:

◦ Is based on a general characterization of household heterogeneity.

◦ Makes it possible to estimate demand elasticities (and program benefits) from the first-step equation—avoiding endogeneity.

◦ Ensures consistency between the envelope and the underlying bid functions.

◦ Sheds light on sorting.

A New Approach

Page 48: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Conclusions, Empirical Results

Willingness to pay for some aspects of school quality can be estimated with precision.◦ The price elasticity of demand for high school

quality is about -1.0 and housing prices are up to 30% higher where high school passing rates are high than where they are low.

The theory of sorting is strongly supported in some cases.◦ Household types with steeper bid functions for high

school quality tend to live where school quality is higher.

A New Approach

Page 49: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Conclusions, Empirical, Continued Household seem to care about several dimensions

of school quality, but precise demand parameters cannot be estimated in many cases.◦ The price elasticity and other parameters cannot be

precisely estimated for relative elementary scores.

◦ Results for elementary value added suggest a relationship that is too complex for current specifications; parents appear concerned about schools with low starting scores even when they improve.

◦ Results for percent minority teachers indicate that many households prefer teacher diversity, which calls for a specification different from any used up to now.

A New Approach

Page 50: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Tests for Normal Sorting

Once the envelope has been estimated, one can recover its slope with respect to S, which is a function of income and other demand variables (for S and H).

The theory says that the income coefficient is (-θ/μ - γ).

◦ Normal sorting requires this coefficient to be positive.

◦ Recall that the amenity price elasticity, μ, is negative.

A New Approach

Page 51: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Direct and Indirect Tests

Direct and indirect tests are possible.

◦ A direct test looks at the income coefficient controlling for all other observable demand determinants.

◦ An indirect test says that normal sorting for S may arise indirectly through the correlation between S and other amenities (and the impact of income on these other amenities).

◦ Based on the omitted variable theorem, the indirect test comes from the sign of the income term in a regression omitting all other demand variables.

A New Approach

Page 52: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

A New Approach

Table 6. Tests for Normal Sorting

Type of Test

Relative Elementary

ScoreHigh School Passing Rate

Indirect Test

Income Coefficient 0.0702 0.8243***

Standard Error (0.0479) (0.0471) Observations 1222 1113 Conclusion Inconclusive Support

Direct Test

Income Coefficient 0.0218 0.5088***

Standard Error (0.0855) (0.0759) R-squared 0.0254 0.2796 Observations 1222 1113 Conclusion Inconclusive Support

Page 53: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Conclusions, Normal Sorting

Normal sorting is neither supported nor rejected for relative elementary school.

Normal sorting is strongly supported for high school quality.

So normal sorting appears to be strong across districts if not within them.

A New Approach

Page 54: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Capitalization

Page 55: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Capitalization

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

Envelope for Share Non-Black

Quadratic Envelope Split EnvelopeFull Nonlinear Envelope Bid Function

Share Non-Black in CBG

log{

PE}

Page 56: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Capitalization

0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

Envelope for Share Non-Hispanic

Quadratic Envelope Split EnvelopeFull Nonlinear Envelope Bid Function

Share Non-Hispanic in CBG

log{

PE}

Page 57: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

The Impact of Amenities on Housing Prices

Change in Price of House Due to Raising the Amenity from:

AmenitySelected Value of Amenity

Minimum to Selected Value

Selected Value to Maximum

Share Non-Black 0.166 -4.1% 25.6%Share Non-Hispanic 0.493 -12.0% 30.8%

Capitalization

Page 58: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Conclusions, Empirical, Continued

Preferences for neighborhood racial and ethnic composition are diverse.◦ Some households (the majority) prefer all-white

neighborhoods.

◦ But some prefer majority-black neighborhoods.

◦ Results for Hispanic neighborhoods are similar but less precise.

◦ I cannot link these results to the race/ethnicity of a household.

Capitalization

Page 59: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

A New Approach

Table 6. Tests for Normal Sorting

Type of TestRelative

Elementary ScoreHigh School Passing Rate

Share Non-Black

Share Non-Hispanic

Indirect Test

Income Coeff. 0.0702 0.8243*** 0.5088*** 0.1934***

Standard Error (0.0479) (0.0471) (0.0678) (0.0227) Observations 1222 1113 1468 1651 Conclusion Inconclusive Support Support Support

Direct Test

Income Coeff. 0.0218 0.5088*** 0.4111*** 0.0320

Standard Error (0.0855) (0.0759) (0.1321) (0.0325) R-squared 0.0254 0.2796 0.2726 0.4485 Observations 1222 1113 1468 1651 Conclusion Inconclusive Support Support Inconclusive

Page 60: Bid-Function  Envelopes or How to Estimate Capitalization

Table 1. Fixed Effects in StudiesTime Dimension Level of Fixed Effects

District or Attendance Zone

Neighborhooda School District Border Attendance Zone Border House

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)One-Year n.a. Controls for unobserved

neighbor-hood traits; can only pick up the impact of  within-district variation in S.

Controls for unobserved neighborhood traits shared across district boundary; requires strong assumptions about similarity across border; cuts observations; does not account for sorting (e.g., Crone).

Controls for unobserved neighborhood traits shared across zone boundary; can only pick up the impact of within-district variation in elementary S; requires control for within-district variation in high school S; cuts observations; does not account for sorting (e.g., Leech and Campos).

n.a.

Multi-Year Controls for unobserved district (zone) traits; identifies effect based on time-variation in S or changes in district (zone) boundaries (e.g., Reback, Dills).

Controls for unobserved neighbor-hood traits; identifies effect based on time-variation in S (e.g., Clapp et al.).

Controls for unobserved neighborhood trends shared across district boundary; requires strong assumptions about similarity across border; cuts observations; does not account for sorting (e.g., Dhar and Ross).

Controls for unobserved neighborhood trends shared across zone boundary; can only pick up the impact of within-district variation in elementary S; requires control for within-district variation in high school S; cuts observations; does not account for sorting (e.g., Black, Kane et al., Bayer et al.).

Controls for all time-invariant variables; identifies all coefficients based on time variation; selection problem (e.g., Figlio and Lucas, Ries and Somerville).

a Although studies may have different definitions of neighborhoods, the boundaries of a neighborhood meant in this table are smaller than attendance zones.

Capitalization