assessing fiscal sustainability

34
Assessing Fiscal Sustainability Teresa Ter-Minassian Director, Fiscal Affairs Department International Monetary Fund January 2004

Upload: ricky

Post on 12-Jan-2016

49 views

Category:

Documents


4 download

DESCRIPTION

Assessing Fiscal Sustainability. Teresa Ter-Minassian Director, Fiscal Affairs Department International Monetary Fund January 2004. Overview of the Presentation. Defining fiscal sustainability Specific considerations Biases against sustainable fiscal policies - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

Teresa Ter-MinassianDirector, Fiscal Affairs Department

International Monetary Fund

January 2004

Page 2: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

2

Overview of the Presentation

Defining fiscal sustainability Specific considerations Biases against sustainable fiscal policies

IMF framework for assessing sustainability Description of the sustainability template Application of template and stress testing Eventual extension to low-income countries

Page 3: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

3

Fiscal Sustainability

Literature presents different concepts of fiscal sustainability; but they all stress intertemporal solvency constraints.

Solvency Today’s government debt must be matched by an excess

of future primary surpluses over primary deficits in present value terms.

In practice, there are limits to the magnitude of policy adjustment that a borrower is willing or able to undertake.

Thus, it is important to view solvency in relation to an adjustment path that is economically, socially, and politically acceptable, so that default is not a preferred option.

Page 4: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

4

Fiscal Sustainability (cont’d)

The most accepted operational criterion requires—with current policies and prospects for the relevant exogenous variables—the public debt to be constant (or declining) over the medium-term in relation to GDP.

The primary gap measures the improvement required in the primary balance to ensure the convergence of the public debt to a stationary level over a relevant time horizon.

Page 5: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

5

Fiscal Sustainability (cont’d)

Ceteris paribus, the primary gap is higher the higher the average real interest rate (expressed in domestic currency) on the public debt and the lower the real rate of growth of GDP.

Fiscal sustainability assessments are complex. They involve judgments about future developments in hard-to-predict variables such as interest rates, exchange rates, and real GDP growth rates.

Page 6: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

6

Fiscal Sustainability (cont’d)

Fiscal sustainability assessments typically focus on a medium-term (5-7 years) horizon. However:

It may be advisable to extend this horizon further if a country faces major fiscal pressures over the longer term, e.g., on account of demographic trends or other clearly identifiable factors, such as the depletion of natural resources, climate changes, etc.

Even if medium-term solvency appears reasonably assured, a country may face short-term liquidity constraints. This is especially the case if the average maturity of the public debt is relatively short, and refinancing requirements are correspondingly large.

Page 7: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

7

Fiscal Sustainability (cont’d)

While the focus of fiscal sustainability assessments tends to be on the gross public debt, to the extent possible it is desirable to take into account in the assessment: any liquid financial assets of the

government; and any significant contingent liabilities

related to, e.g., explicit and implicit government guarantees and pending judicial actions against the government.

Page 8: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

8

Comparison of Public Debt Levels in Emerging Market and Industrial

Economies

All emerging markets

Asia

Latin America

Middle East & Africa

Transition countries

0 20 40 60 80

Industrial countries

All emerging markets

Asia

Latin America

Middle East & Africa

Transition countries

0 100 200 300 400

Source: WEO September 2003. Unweighted averages.

Public Debt (ratio to revenue; average, 1992–2002)

External Public Debt (percent of total debt; average, 1992–2002)

1 2

Industrial countries 2

Public debt in emerging market economies is now higher than in industrial countries as a share of GDP, and is significantly higher as a share of government revenue. External debt also accounts for a higher proportion of public debt in emerging markets.

1992 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 2000 01 02 55

60

65

70

75

80 Public Debt (percent of GDP)

Industrial countries

Emerging markets

Page 9: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

9

Debt Default and Public Debt Ratios

Comparison of Key Indicators of Public Debt (percent)

0

100

200

300

400

500

0

20

40

60

80

100

120 Defaulters

Debt/revenues Debt/GDP Share of external Broad debt/total debt money/GDP

Source: WEO September 2003. Data are an average of 1998–2002. Defaulters refer to countries that have defaulted

Nondefaulters

1

1

Left scale Right scale Right scale Right scale

Default often reflects illiquidity. Sometimes (e.g., Argentina), default occurs when the government is still capable of servicing the debt in the short term, but views the primary adjustment required to ensure longer-term sustainability as too costly.

0–20 20–40 40–60 60–80 80–100 100+ Public debt/GDP

0

10

20

30

40 Distribution of Public Debt Ratios in the Year Before a Default

Share of all defaults 0

Page 10: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

10

Why do Governments Pursue Unsustainable Fiscal Policies?

If unsustainable fiscal behaviors lead to crises so frequently, why do governments pursue them, often for extended periods of time?

Political economy factors: Voters tend to overestimate the benefits of public

spending programs, and to underestimate their costs;

Voters, and therefore politicians, try to shift the cost of public spending to future generations;

Distributional conflicts hamper tax and expenditure reforms needed to improve the fiscal position;

Politicians have high discount rates especially when term limits prevent their re-election.

Page 11: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

11

Why do Governments Pursue Unsustainable Fiscal Policies? (cont’d)

Market factors: Because of delays or asymmetries in

information, markets often do not penalize unsustainable fiscal behavior early enough;

Markets may also bet on bailouts (e.g., from strong neighboring countries, regional blocks, or international financial institutions); and

The narrowness and underdevelopment of domestic capital markets may push governments to borrow excessively in foreign currencies and/or with short maturities.

Page 12: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

12

Why do Governments Pursue Unsustainable Fiscal Policies? (cont’d)

Institutional factors: Weak budgetary institutions can be major

determinants of inadequate fiscal performance:

Antiquated procedures, lack of internal controls in tax administration;

Poor budget management systems and practices; Overbloated, underpaid and under-trained civil

service; Lack of transparency in the management of public

resources; Lack of accountability of public managers.

Page 13: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

13

IMF Sustainability Framework

Assessing debt sustainability has become a central element of the work of the IMF. This encompasses both the assessments of external and fiscal sustainability.

These assessments are complemented

by analyses of balance sheet vulnerabilities for the private (financial and non-financial) and public sectors.

Page 14: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

14

Sustainability Assessments are Inherently Probabilistic

Any assessment of sustainability is probabilistic in nature, as the debt dynamics depend on uncertain macroeconomic and fiscal developments and on future movements in asset prices and returns.

Thus, one should think of sustainability assessments as analyses of the probability that debt dynamics become unstable. This points to a need for stress testing by considering:

1. Alternative scenarios; and2. Standard error bands around the baseline.

Page 15: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

15

Applications of the Framework for Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

In countries with moderately high indebtedness – the framework can help identify vulnerabilities far enough in advance so that policy corrections can be implemented.

In countries on the brink, or in the midst, of a crisis – the framework can be used to examine the plausibility of the debt-stabilizing dynamics articulated in the authorities’ policies.

In the aftermath of a default – the framework can be used to examine the sustainability of alternative options for debt restructuring.

Page 16: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

16

IMF Sustainability Framework The framework includes templates for the

analysis of both external and fiscal sustainability, in four main blocks: a variety of indicators of debt and debt

service; the baseline medium-term projections (with

particular attention to ensuring the consistency of these projections and greater clarity about the assumptions);

a set of stress tests for deviations from the baseline; and

a set of alternative scenarios using different assumptions.

Page 17: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

17

Framework Templates

The templates have several functions: Illustrate the realism of the existing projections

by laying bare the assumptions that underlie the projected debt dynamics.

Show the evolution of a country’s debt burden over the medium term under the baseline projections of growth, interest rates, and fiscal deficits.

Provide upper-bound estimates of the likely evolution of the debt stock, showing whether the debt burden remains reasonable under a variety of plausible macroeconomic shocks.

Page 18: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

18

Disaggregation of effects

The templates model separately the effects of growth, real interest rate, and exchange rate movements on public debt and debt service ratios, to assess their relative importance in terms of the evolution of the indicators and also for the stress tests.

Page 19: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

19

Key Macroeconomic and Fiscal Assumptions

Real GDP growth Inflation rate (GDP deflator) Average nominal interest rate on

public debt Nominal appreciation/depreciation Primary balance Growth in real primary public spending

Page 20: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

20

Alternative scenarios

Attempt to answer the following questions:

What if history (for growth, inflation, interest rates, primary balance) repeats itself?

What if there is “no policy change” in terms of the primary balance?

What if there is a country-specific shock that results in a downward step adjustment (one standard deviation) in GDP growth?

What if market expectations or consensus forecasts (where available) are used to project the medium term?

Page 21: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

21

Bound testsUsing the baseline scenario as a starting point,

consider the following shocks: Separate adverse two-standard deviation shock

lasting two years to the real interest rate, the real growth rate, and the primary balance.

A combined shock: the real interest rate, real growth rate, primary balance, and exchange rate are simultaneously subject to a one-standard deviation shock.

Two different exogenous shocks: A 30 percent depreciation; An increase in debt ratio by 10 percent of GDP,

reflecting e.g. the recognition of implicit or explicit contingent liabilities.

Page 22: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

22

Bound Tests Calibration

The magnitude of the individual shocks (two standard deviations) assumed in the stress tests was calibrated to mimic movements in growth, interest rates, and the U.S dollar value of the GDP deflator observed in the run-up to previous debt crises.

The two-year one-standard deviation combined shock is also very much consistent with the historical evidence on debt crises.

The resulting upper bounds of the debt ratio that are derived from the bound tests correspond to approximately a 95 percent confidence interval.

Page 23: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

23

Additional Features of the Framework

The template presents a measure of the constant “steady state” primary surplus that stabilizes the debt ratio at its value at the end of the projection horizon. This indication of the needed fiscal adjustment effort can be cross-checked against a country’s historical performance, to gauge policy implementation credibility.

The framework also tracks gross financing needs, as a simple way of assessing roll-over risk.

Page 24: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

Table --. Country: Public Sector Debt Sustainability Framework, 1998-2008(In percent of GDP, unless otherwise indicated)

Actual Projections1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

Debt-stabilizingI. Baseline Projections primary

balance 11/1 Public sector debt 1/ 28.7 27.3 42.2 44.8 54.4 50.9 54.9 50.8 48.9 48.0 49.5 50.5 50.6 49.2 47.7 46.1 44.5 0.9

o/w foreign-currency denominated 19.6 20.6 27.7 27.7 36.8 35.7 39.0 36.1 39.2 38.8 39.0 39.2 38.7 37.7 36.7 35.5

2 Change in public sector debt -1.3 14.9 2.6 9.6 -3.5 4.0 -4.1 -1.9 -0.9 1.5 1.0 0.0 -1.4 -1.5 -1.6 -1.63 Identified debt-creating flows (4+7+12) -3.7 10.6 -1.5 -5.7 -4.8 5.5 -4.0 -4.4 -0.7 5.9 0.3 -0.5 -1.4 -1.5 -1.7 -1.74 Primary deficit -3.5 -2.2 -4.4 -10.3 -5.2 -1.9 -1.6 -0.7 -0.7 0.2 -0.3 -1.2 -1.9 -2.0 -2.0 -2.05 Revenue and grants 23.1 22.8 22.8 21.8 22.0 20.0 20.4 21.0 21.0 21.8 22.5 21.7 21.4 21.2 21.1 21.06 Primary (noninterest) expenditure 19.7 20.6 18.4 11.6 16.8 18.1 18.8 20.4 20.2 22.0 22.2 20.5 19.5 19.2 19.1 19.07 Automatic debt dynamics 2/ -0.2 12.8 2.9 4.6 0.3 7.4 -2.3 -3.8 0.0 5.7 0.6 0.6 0.4 0.5 0.3 0.38 Contribution from interest rate/growth differential 3/ -0.2 -0.8 -5.0 3.8 -0.5 -0.6 -1.1 -4.0 1.7 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.4 0.5 0.3 0.39 Of which contribution from real interest rate 0.3 0.3 -7.0 5.5 2.5 1.5 0.6 -1.2 1.5 1.0 1.6 2.3 2.4 2.4 2.2 2.2

10 Of which contribution from real GDP growth -0.5 -1.1 2.0 -1.7 -2.9 -2.1 -1.7 -2.8 0.2 -0.4 -0.9 -1.7 -1.9 -1.9 -1.9 -1.811 Contribution from exchange rate depreciation 4/ 0.0 13.6 7.9 0.8 0.8 8.0 -1.2 0.2 -1.7 5.1 ... ... ... ... ... ...12 Other identified debt-creating flows 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.013 Privatization receipts (negative) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.014 Recognition of implicit or contingent liabilities 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.015 Other (specify, e.g. bank recapitalization) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.016 Residual, including asset changes (2-3) 5/ 2.4 4.3 4.1 15.3 1.3 -1.5 -0.1 2.5 -0.1 -4.4 0.7 0.5 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1

Public sector debt-to-revenue ratio 1/ 118.1 185.2 196.6 249.2 231.8 275.0 249.2 232.6 228.9 227.2 224.8 233.0 229.9 225.1 218.9 211.7

Gross financing need 6/ 6.0 7.2 7.7 14.2 15.6 18.3 18.6 16.2 17.0 17.3 17.2 16.4 15.8 15.3 14.8 14.3in billions of U.S. dollars 24.4 30.1 22.0 47.2 62.7 76.9 89.3 94.1 106.2 109.9 10-Year 10-Year 106.3 106.1 107.8 110.6 113.0 115.6

Historical Standard ProjectedKey Macroeconomic and Fiscal Assumptions Average Deviation Average

Real GDP growth (in percent) 2.0 4.4 -6.2 5.2 6.8 5.0 3.6 6.6 -0.3 0.9 2.8 3.9 1.9 3.5 4.1 4.1 4.2 4.3 3.7Average nominal interest rate on public debt (in percent) 7/ 11.0 9.7 14.2 49.1 24.6 19.6 17.2 10.1 9.7 6.9 17.2 12.5 7.8 7.8 8.1 8.2 8.1 8.2 8.0Average real interest rate (nominal rate minus change in GDP deflator, in percent) 1.5 1.4 -23.7 18.3 6.9 4.3 1.8 -2.0 3.3 2.3 1.4 10.4 3.4 5.0 5.1 5.3 5.1 5.2 4.9Nominal appreciation (increase in US dollar value of local currency, in percent) 0.3 -41.7 -30.3 -2.7 -2.9 -18.1 3.7 -0.6 4.7 -11.3 -9.9 15.6 ... ... ... ... ... ... ...Inflation rate (GDP deflator, in percent) 9.5 8.3 37.9 30.7 17.7 15.3 15.4 12.2 6.4 4.6 15.8 10.7 4.4 2.8 3.0 3.0 3.0 3.0 3.2Growth of real primary spending (deflated by GDP deflator, in percent) 8.1 9.5 -16.3 -34.0 55.3 12.9 7.7 15.6 -1.0 9.4 6.7 23.0 3.0 -4.1 -1.0 2.3 3.5 3.9 1.3Primary deficit -3.5 -2.2 -4.4 -10.3 -5.2 -1.9 -1.6 -0.7 -0.7 0.2 -3.0 3.1 -0.3 -1.2 -1.9 -2.0 -2.0 -2.0 -1.6

Debt-stabilizingII. Stress Tests for Public Debt Ratio primary

A. Alternative Scenarios balance 10/

A1. Key variables are at their historical averages in 2004-08 8/ 50.5 47.3 43.7 40.0 36.3 32.7 -0.1A2. Primary balance under no policy change in 2004-08 50.5 50.6 49.2 47.7 46.1 44.5 0.9A3. Country-specific shock in 2004, with reduction in GDP growth (relative to baseline) of one standard deviation 9/ 50.5 50.6 49.2 47.7 46.1 44.5 0.9A4. Selected variables are consistent with market forecast in 2004-08 50.5 50.6 49.2 47.7 46.1 44.5 0.9

B. Bound Tests

B1. Real interest rate is at historical average plus two standard deviations in 2004 and 2005 50.5 58.9 67.1 66.1 64.8 63.5 1.2B2. Real GDP growth is at historical average minus two standard deviations in 2004 and 2005 50.5 57.1 65.2 67.7 70.1 72.5 1.4B3. Primary balance is at historical average minus two standard deviations in 2004 and 2005 50.5 54.8 58.5 57.2 55.8 54.4 1.1B4. Combination of 2-4 using one standard deviation shocks 50.5 57.6 65.2 64.0 62.7 61.3 1.2B5. One time 30 percent real depreciation in 2004 10/ 50.5 69.1 68.1 67.0 65.8 64.5 1.3B6. 10 percent of GDP increase in other debt-creating flows in 2004 50.5 60.6 59.4 58.2 56.8 55.3 1.1

1/ Indicate coverage of public sector, e.g., general government or nonfinancial public sector. Also whether net or gross debt is used.2/ Derived as [(r - g - g + r]/(1+g++g)) times previous period debt ratio, with r = interest rate; = growth rate of GDP deflator; g = real GDP growth rate; = share of foreign-currency denominated debt; and = nominal exchange rate depreciation (measured by increase in local currency value of U.S. dollar).3/ The real interest rate contribution is derived from the denominator in footnote 2/ as r - π (1+g) and the real growth contribution as -g.4/ The exchange rate contribution is derived from the numerator in footnote 2/ as (1+r). 5/ For projections, this line includes exchange rate changes.6/ Defined as public sector deficit, plus amortization of medium and long-term public sector debt, plus short-term debt at end of previous period. 7/ Derived as nominal interest expenditure divided by previous period debt stock.8/ The key variables include real GDP growth; real interest rate; and primary balance in percent of GDP.9/ The implied change in other key variables under this scenario is discussed in the text. 10/ Real depreciation is defined as nominal depreciation (measured by percentage fall in dollar value of local currency) minus domestic inflation (based on GDP deflator). 11/ Assumes that key variables (real GDP growth, real interest rate, and primary balance) remain at the level in percent of GDP/growth rate of the last projection year.

Page 25: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

25

Retrospective Debt Sustainability Analysis in Four Capital Account

Crises

The sustainability framework has been applied retrospectively to the crises in Argentina (1999), Brazil (1998), Mexico (1995), and Turkey (1999), to see whether actual outcomes would fall within the stress test range.

Page 26: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

Retrospective Debt Sustainability Analysis

(Public debt, in percent of GDP)

Argentina

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

1999 2000 2001

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100Brazil

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

1998 1999 2000 2001

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

Mexico

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

Sensitivity Range Actual Baseline

Turkey

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

1999 2000 2001

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

Page 27: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

27

Results of Retrospective Analysis

The 2001 debt ratio in Argentina turned out to be slightly above the upper bound of the stress test range. If the projection had been extended to 2002, the debt ratio would have moved far beyond the upper bound of the stress test range.

For Turkey, the outcome for 2001 was well above the upper bound of the stress test range, despite the beneficial impact of stronger fiscal adjustment and lower real interest rates than expected.

Page 28: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

28

Results of Retrospective Analysis (cont’d)

The post-crisis debt ratio in Brazil was at the upper end of the stress test range, despite a better-than-expected post-crisis fiscal adjustment and lower-than-expected real interest rates. An unanticipated large real depreciation was the main contributor.

In Mexico, the outturn in 1995 was above the one-year-ahead program baseline projection, because of a larger real depreciation, higher real interest rates, and slower growth than anticipated, and because of the securitization of contingent and unfunded liabilities. Nevertheless, the outturn was within the stress test range.

Page 29: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

29

What the Template Will Not Do...

The framework presents only the implications of alternative scenarios. It does not provide probabilities of debt crises: this is left for the user to determine.

Early warning models are being developed, but still need to be fine tuned in terms of the balance between failing to identify crises and generating false alarms.

The template does not indicate what level of debt is too high.

However, a recent IMF empirical study suggests that there is an appreciable increase in the conditional probability of a crisis (to about 15-20 percent) when the external debt level rises over 40 percent of GDP.

The framework does not contain information at the level of detail needed to fully capture balance sheet mismatches, which have had a significant impact on debt financeability (liquidity) in recent debt crises.

Page 30: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

30

Balance Sheet Vulnerabilities are also Important

Attention needs to be paid to:

Liquidity mismatches in terms of the maturity structure of assets and liabilities;

Currency denomination mismatches between assets and liabilities;

Capital structure mismatches, including possible overreliance on borrowing relative to equity (such as FDI);

Intersectoral imbalances, such as overreliance on the domestic banking system as a holder of government paper. This would weaken banks’ balance sheets in a restructuring situation and would add to contingent liabilities for the government in the case of a bail-out.

Page 31: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

31

Where has this framework been applied so far?

To date, this framework has been applied to most countries with access to private financial markets, as well as all users of IMF resources (except PRGF countries).

Work is underway to extend the framework to low-income countries (including PRGF), though there are likely to be some modifications, as the issues are somewhat different.

Page 32: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

32

Issues Relating to Possible Extension of Framework to Low-Income

Countries

Most financing to LICs comes from bilateral donors and international financial institutions.

Debt of LICs tends to be on fixed and concessional terms, implying longer repayment periods.

In order to meet the Millennium Development Goals, many LICs are likely to require substantial external financing in the period ahead.

Thus, the issue of how much additional debt these countries can afford to accumulate is of critical importance.

Page 33: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

33

Issues Relating to Possible Extension of Framework to Low-Income Countries

(cont’d)

The serviceability of the debt in LICs depends more on the willingness of official creditors and donors to provide net transfers through concessional loans and grants than on market sentiment (as reflected in interest rate spreads).

Vulnerabilities may be more acute both on the external and domestic sides (e.g., narrowness of production and export bases; policy deficiencies, poor governance, weak institutions, inadequate debt management, political developments with adverse economic consequences such as civil war and social strife).

Page 34: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability

34

Possible Considerations in Extending the Framework to Low-Income Countries

Focus on an NPV measure of debt (rather than the nominal stock), given that borrowing is in large part on concessional terms;

Look at the ratios of NPV of debt to GDP, exports and revenue, to address issues of narrowness of base.

Similarly for debt service, look at the ratio of debt service to exports and to revenue.

Extend the projection period due to the typically longer maturity of concessional debt.

Consider the quality of a country’s policies and institutions in assessing debt sustainability.