an analysis of airline cost curves for us carriers ... · an analysis of airline cost curves for us...

45
Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES - 1 - An Analysis of Airline Cost Curves for US Carriers: Determining Minimum Efficient Scale Economics Honours Thesis Stanford University Economics Department Advisor: Professor Geoffrey Rothwell 17-December-2007 --- Samvit Prabhat Kanoria ---

Upload: vuquynh

Post on 06-Sep-2018

226 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 1 -

An Analysis of Airline Cost Curves for US Carriers: Determining Minimum Efficient Scale

Economics Honours Thesis

Stanford University Economics Department

Advisor: Professor Geoffrey Rothwell

17-December-2007

--- Samvit Prabhat Kanoria ---

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 2 -

Table of Contents

I. Introduction …………………… 3

II. Literature Review …………………… 4

III. Methodology …………………… 8

IV. Data …………………… 12

V. Hypotheses Tests & Results …………………… 16

VI. Conclusions …………………… 20

VII. References …………………… 24

VIII. Appendix …………………… 25

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 3 -

I. Introduction

There are few industries that have undergone as much financial struggle in the last

decade than aviation. With 110 airlines operating scheduled service in the United States,

there seems to be some overcrowding with the lion’s share of the market being split

among the major carriers – American, Southwest, United, Delta, Continental, Northwest,

US Airways, JetBlue, America West, and Air Tran – that make up about 80% of the

market, as measured by Revenue per Passenger Mile flown (see Figure I.1). Following

seven years of good profitability that stemmed from a relatively long period of world

economic prosperity between 1994 and 2000, the industry suffered a huge setback in the

post 9/11 world. Cumulative net losses of the world’s scheduled airlines amounted to

$20.3billion between 1990 and 1993, followed with a net profit of $40billion between

1995 and 2000 (Morrell 2007). There is evidence of an upswing in airlines’ profitability

following increasing demand from 2005 onwards but the longer term health of the

industry still remains unproven.

In this continually changing landscape, this paper seeks to draw on existing

economic literature on the cost curves of airlines, use updated financial performance from

the last two decades, and estimate an average-cost & output-quantity model. The general

shape of the AC-Q model is expected to give us insights into what the minimum efficient

scale in the airline industry is, and try to justify the reason for a bi-polar industry with

small regional carriers and large international ones serving similar markets. Finally, this

paper will make recommendations for further research, to improve on what is presented

herewith, and to more accurately determine the economies of scale in the airline business.

Before diving in however a sincere word of gratitude to my thesis advisor,

Professor Geoffrey Rothwell, for all his guidance and continued support during this

endeavour. Also deserving of thanks is the Bureau of Transportation Statistics who was

very prompt with its emails, and in helping me access to the data-set used in this paper.

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 4 -

II. Literature Review

Unsurprisingly, there is a lot of pre-existing literature on cost comparisons across

airlines. However, in this section, I will try and motivate the methodology used in this

paper, and use historical literature to create a benchmarked understanding of the airline

cost function.

Under the Federal Aviation Act, the Department of Transportation, enforces some

lose control over the cost categories that airlines need to report. It is important to

understand what these cost considerations are, but more importantly understand what the

drivers of efficiency really are before making comparisons across time periods and across

airlines. As O’Connor points out, flying operations includes crew wages and fuel while

direct maintenance covers the cost of labour and raw materials directly attributable to the

repair and upkeep of aircrafts. The three service categories – passenger, aircraft, and

traffic – involve the costs of cabin attendants, routine servicing by cleaning personnel,

and ticketing and baggage handling, respectively. Administrative costs are subdivided

into the self-explanatory categories of reservation and sales, advertising and publicity,

and general and administrative. Finally, a depreciation and amortization cost that

involves paying off the huge capital investment in the actual aircraft, is another cost

category.

It is important to consider what the drivers of these costs are, and how airlines

operating on similar routes have a very different cost structure (Straszheim 1969):

Plane Type, Routing & Scheduling Systems, and Stage Length – Over the two

decades preceding the 1970s, seat-mile costs1 have continuously declined with the

advent of bigger, faster planes with greater fuel efficiency and lower labour

requirements. Jet engines are able to fly 6,000 hours before engine overhaul

requirements and their 10 hour utilisation rates are 60% higher than the formerlu

used piston engines. The longer range of contemporary aircrafts including the 1 Cost Per Available Seat Mile (CASM), a commonly used unit cost used to compare airlines. CASM is expressed in cents to operate each seat mile offered, and is determined by dividing operating costs by Available Seat Miles. This number is frequently used to allow a cost comparison between different airlines. In theory, the lower the CASM the more profitable the airline should be.

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 5 -

Boeing 777-300ER and the Airbus 330 series increases the average stage length2

which decreases the number of take-offs and landings thereby allowing for easier

scheduling and lower personnel cost. Thus, a plot of direct operating costs and

stage length reflects a decreasing function (Figure II.1). A theoretical argument

can be made that suggests a rising portion of the cost curve with increasing stage

length because increasing payload must be traded off for increased fuel cost

holding but in practice few airlines operate at such excessive stage lengths.

Airline Size – A cross section comparison of international airline costs

(Straszheim 1969) suggests a decrease in costs with increasing airline size (Figure

II.2). Economies of scale are considered to be the general explanation behind this

phenomenon. But, these costs are statistically different between regional and

international carriers only for the direct operating costs already mentioned above.

No scale effects are seen with regard to indirect costs although the larger carriers

enjoy a much better negotiation position with regard to labour and fuel wages that

form the majority of these airlines’ cost (Figure II.3).

o In 1979, scheduled airlines in the US employed 330,393 people (of which

27,000 were pilots and co-pilots) at a total cost of $9.7billion. Relative to

that number, the 2007 total employee number for the six largest airlines at

311,6603 does not seem all that significant. Yet, the problems with airline

costs do not arise purely from the volume of employed labour, but in the

strengths of the unions that negotiate their wages and the working rules of

its members’ contracts. Moreover, no single labour union works to protect

all airline employees – they are very fragmented and their membership is

driven by the type of task that each airline employee fulfils. The ability of

the larger airlines to negotiate more effectively with the unions and for

smaller airlines to employ non-unionised workers is a major driver of cost

reduction.

o In 1969 jet fuel cost about 11cents per gallon which had grown to 58cents

by 1979. Fast forwarding to present times, the price of jet fuel was 40cents

2 Stage length is the length of the average flight – from takeoff to landing – of a particular airline. 3 Smart Skies Website <http://www.smartskies.org/About/Carriers/>

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 6 -

per gallon in 1999, jumped to 75cents in January of 2000 increasing its

share of total cost from 12 to 30%. Hugely volatile over a small time-

period, the price of aviation fuel reached 107cents during the summer of

2000, closing the year at 75cents. In 2004 and 2006 there were spurts of

increases too when prices reached 157cent and 223cents respectively

(Morrell 2007). Although such rapidly fluctuating oil prices has a

universal impact on all airlines, the location of refuelling and the

negotiating power with oil suppliers may have a marginal impact on the

cost economics.

A pan-industry study conducted in 1993 sheds some more insight into how

different airlines stack up on a cost-comparison basis. The results show differences that

are not significantly large but important enough in a very low-margin business.

Continental enjoyed a 12% cost competitiveness relative to American, driven largely by

labour prices. Northwest enjoyed a 5% cost advantage relative to AA, with United and

Delta coming in at about parity. A 17% lower efficiency number and 3% higher input

prices put US Air at a 20% disadvantage relative to the AA benchmark. On the

international arena, Asian carriers significantly outperformed the benchmark with

Singapore, Korean, Cathay and Thai enjoying a 12, 23, 4 and 9% advantage. The

converse was true of European carriers where British Airways, Lufthansa, Air France,

SAS and Iberia were 7, 21, 21, 42 and 32% less cost-effective than AA (Forsyth et al

2002). Over time, these cost difference remained relatively stable, but the regional

clustering of cost similarities will have an important corollary later in this paper.

There exists, in airline economics, a great difficulty in disaggregating all the

aforementioned effects and obtain true cost estimate for various airline characteristics.

Thus, as Straszheim points out, most explanations have settled for relating costs to a

single variable – usually some measure of firm size. A summary of the existing model,

whose components aggregate to the total cost function, is presented herewith. But the

basic reasoning of looking at cost purely as a function of output quantity forms the

bedrock of the econometric work of this paper too.

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 7 -

n / SM = number of stations per seat-mile (route density)

h = average passenger hop (miles)

d = average flight stage length (miles)

d / h = average flight stage length per average passenger hop (miles)

AC (d) = expected average direct operating cost per seat-mile, as a function of plane

choice and flight stage length

Sl = non flight crew scheduling

Sc = flight crew scheduling

Sa = aircraft scheduling

C / SM = flight crew (in man-years) per seat-mile

K / SM = capital expenses (cents) per seat-mile

L / SM = all other labour (man-years) per seat-mile

WP = pilot wage (dollars per year)

WL = wage of all other labour (dollars per year)

SML = -0.7885 + 1,700,000

SMn + 0.5640 AC(d) – 91.8

d1 + 50.10 WL

SMC = -0.3228 + 0.3094 AC(d) – 21.8

d1 1,300,000

SMn

ACSMc = 0.2398 + 68.694 WP

SMC Sc + 0.1889 Sc + 0.9310 AC(d) – 249.5

d1 + 3,800,000

SMn + 0.1599

SMK + 25.9WL

SML +

000,10LW

.[0.2633 + 876,400SML + 4,800,000

SMn -

0.00034h + 0.00024d + 3.4376 Sc – 0.3513hd ]

Although a detailed explanation of this model and its implications are beyond the

scope of this paper, suffice it to say that each of the cost-drivers and their impact on

airline operating costs are proven accurate by the econometric analysis of this model.

Most importantly, the inverse relationship between output quantity, and average cost, is

seen to be accurate too. A myriad of studies also confirm that the only slightly increasing

or constant returns to scale, beyond some minimum size, seem to characterise the airline

industry (Figure II.4) and that diseconomies of scale were evident only among the

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 8 -

smallest firms. Moreover, while thinking of the optimal size of the airline industry

(thereby allowing one to arrive at conclusions on minimum efficient scale), historical

data suggests a “shift downward over time” allowing smaller carriers with regional

pockets of concentration to effectively compete with the larger airlines too (Biederman

1982). In the methodology and results sections ahead, I will borrow from this finding,

and establish an AC-Q relationship of my own thereby allowing me to derive a minimum

efficient scale statistic.

III. Methodology

The manner of modelling the cost curves in the airline industry is not different

from a traditional factor model used both in the study of labour economics, and in firm

theory. An airline, like any other operational firm, faces the same production constraints

– of limited resources that involves a vector of input costs, revenues generated both

directly and indirectly from these incurred costs, and a profit stream that calculates the

difference. Moreover, in the neoclassical formulation of this model, technology can either

be input agnostic or create a skew in the equilibrium ratio of one factor of production to

another. A brief discussion of the cost function is presented herewith, in order to motivate

the more relevant topic of cost curves to which I will turn to shortly.

From Intriligator (1996) and Johnston (1997) the following cost function

methodology is devised: In the general case of a firm producing a single output from two

inputs (x1, x2), the entire set of possible outputs (y) is defined by a functional relationship

y = f (x1, x2). Therefore, the profit maximising function (π) that the firm seeks to

maximise is

max π = pf(x1, x2) – w1x1 – w2x2 with w1 and w2 being the input costs for the respective

factors of production.

A graphic representation of these constraint can be showed by the isocost, a locus

of input combinations (x1, x2) for which cost C, the total payment to both costs inputs is

constant: C = w1x1 + w2x2 = constant. And, in order to determine the geometric

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 9 -

equilibrium of the market, the other curve used is the isoquant that represents a locus of

input combinations for which the output is fixed, algebraically thought of as a production

level curve: y = f(x1, x2) = constant. (Figure III.1).

In Figure III.2, along the expansion path of increasing costs there exist multiple

points of equilibrium with a given output y from the isoquant¸ and a corresponding level

of cost C, from the isocost. The set of all possible combinations of these output-cost pairs

give rise to the notion of a cost curve.

C = C(y),

in this case the long-run total cost curve, since it represents total cost:

C = w1x1 + w2x2

where the long run is economically defined as a period in which all the factors of

production can be freely varied. A short-run cost curve is defined using an alternative

expansion path that reflects whatever factors are fixed in any particular constrained time

period. An example would be the expansion path defined by the horizontal line at x2,

where the second input is fixed at a certain level, and the other input is free to vary. The

short-run cost curve defined by y and C along such an alternative expansion path Cs(y)

must satisfy

Cs(y) ≥ C(y)

since at every point the short run cost must be higher or equal to the longer-run cost in

which all the factors are variable. Since, this is the total cost function the average costs

merely divide the total cost by the output both in the short and longer run:

AC(y) = C(y) , ACs(y) = Cs(y)

y ys

And, the marginal cost curves are defined as the derivative of the total cost function:

MC(y) = dC(y) , MCs(y) = dCs(y)

dy dys

The geometric relationship between the total, marginal, and average cost curves

are seen in the second half of Figure III.2. There are a few key relationship elements that

merit a highlight:

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 10 -

Since all inputs are flexible in the long run, the long run total cost function indicates a 0

cost at 0 output. So, C(0) = 0

Long and short term cost functions are monotonic as costs increase with increased output

The shape of the cost curve represents technological assumptions and when labour

specialization occurs

Geometrically, the average cost is the slope of a ray connecting the origin and a point on

the total cost curve, while the marginal cost is the slope of the total cost curve itself.

An algebraic estimation of the total cost curve depicted in Figure III.2 is a cubic curve where

C = a0 + a1y + a2y2 + a3y3 where a0, a1, a2, and a3 are given parameters. The average cost

curve associated with this cubic total cost curve is derived by dividing the entire equation by

output:

AC = a0 + a1 + a2y + a3y2

y

and marginal cost is given by taking the derivative of the total cost function with respect

to output

MC = a1 + 2a2y + 3a3y2

For U-shaped average an marginal cost curves as illustrated in Figure III.2, the

parameters must satisfy the restrictions:

a0 ≥ 0, a1>0, a2<0, a3>0 where a0 is the fixed cost at zero output.

Empirical studies of cost curves typically estimate a long-run curve using cross-sectional

data on firms in the industry, specifically using data on total costs, output, and other relevant

variables. Assuming that the same technology applies to all firms, that observed outputs are close

to planned outputs, and that firms are seeking to minimize costs at each planned output level, it

follows that the cost curve estimated from a scatter diagram of cost-output points represents an

accurate estimate. In the long-run case, a0 in the cubic cost curve above that represents fixed

costs vanishes to give an average cost equation of

AC = a1 + a2y + a3y2

This quadratic long-run average cost curve has been estimated for many industries. But, as

mentioned above, the estimated shape of the curve, as described in Figure III.2, is based on

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 11 -

certain technological advances, changing economies of scale, and altering effects on labour

specialization. There are several nested models of AC that can be derived from the generalized

cubic TC function.

(1) Simple Constant: k + Q0 or a1

(2) Linear: k + Q0 + Q1 or a1 + a2y

(3) Quadratic: k + Q0 + Q1 + Q2 or a1 + a2y + a3y2

(4) Inverse: Q-1 + k + Q0 or a0 y-1 + a1

(5) Inverse + Linear: Q-1 + k + Q0 + Q1 or a0 y-1 + a1 + a2y

All these nested functional forms are derived from the TC function in Intriligator and

represent the general consideration that AC = f (Q-1 + Q0 + Q1 + Q2). Specifically what the

functional relationship is, does not seem to be very clear and one might try all different

combinations of a log-log, semi-log and log-linear assumptions to fit the data accurately.

For a wide variety of industries, including manufacturing, mining, distribution, transportation,

and trade, it has been found that the long-run average cost curves are L-shaped rather than U-

shaped and this is the reason why the inverse function mentioned above becomes relevant. It is

important to understand the implications of the L-shaped curve which forms the bedrock of this

paper. As illustrated in Figure III.3, average cost initially falls sharply then reaches (or

asymptotically approaches) a certain minimum level AC0 at a critical level of output, y0, and

remains flat after this level of output. The critical level of output y0 is the minimum efficient

scale; it is the point at which there is a “knee” in the average cost curve. By calculating the

empirical constant at which the K/Q line reflects the asymptote to average cost – the lowest

possible cost achieved with the existing technology – we get an estimate of what the MES in the

airline industry is and a possible recommendation at what scale airlines ought to operate at.

In the results section, I will test the hypothesis that the inverse function better represents

the data than the quadratic function. The assumption is that quadratic function has an upturn –

representing a region of increasing AC – and, if there is indeed this upturn then there is an

optimal size to the industry or for a given firm size. However, if the generalized model is not

significantly different from the inverse function, then we assume that there is no explicit optimal

size but a region of continually decreasing or flat average costs. In this case, of the inverse

function holding true, extending Intriligator and previous literature, the minimum efficient scale

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 12 -

is that output quantity where the estimated AC is within two standard errors of the constant

asymptote.

The hypotheses that I will be testing is whether or not the general model

Q-1 + k + Q0 + Q1 + Q2 or a0 y-1 + a1 + a2y + a3y2

is significantly different from the two nested models of an inverse and a quadratic function. This

is an empirical question, to which I will now turn.

IV. Data

As discussed in the methodology section, the cost curve has two main

considerations – average cost and output quantity. In order to arrive at average cost, the total cost

function used in this paper was Total Operating Cost. This financial data was available for all US

based airlines from 1990 – 2007 on the Bureau of Transportation Statistics website4 hosted by

the U.S. Department of Transportation (DOT). Specifically, data is made available by The

Research and Innovative Technology Administration (RITA), the division that coordinates the

DOT’s research programs and is charged with advancing the deployment of cross-cutting

technologies to improve America’s national transportation system. Before calculating AC from

this TC number, the nominal dollar figures were adjusted to 1995 Dollars using the GDP deflator

figures from the Economic Report of the President. Eventually then, the cost figures are made

comparable across years by adjusting for inflation and any structural changes to economy that

are reflected in the GDP deflator numbers.

Aside from the TC measure, a quantity measure was also obtained from the Bureau of

Transportation Statistics website. In the airline industry, and specifically for passenger carriers, it

makes sense to consider two different output quantities that are capacity measures as well.

Revenue per Passenger Mile (RPM)5 – One paying passenger flown one mile. It is the

principal measure of airline passenger traffic.

Available Seat Mile (ASM) – One seat flown one mile. An airliner with 100 seats flown

1000 miles represents 10,000 ASMs. This is a capacity measure and the difference with

4 Bureau of Transportation Statistic website <http://www.transtats.bts.gov/homepage.asp> 5 Airline Glossary < http://www.avjobs.com/history/airline-glossary.asp>

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 13 -

RPM is the non-revenue generating load factor such as passengers with free tickets,

airline employees etc.

In the data that were made available, quarterly breakdowns were aggregated to

obtain yearly figures. Moreover, airline operations were separated based on the region of

service, and these data were also aggregated to obtain total costs and output quantities for all

the major carriers. Care was taken to ensure that freight-only carriers were removed from the

data set because the ASM and RPM numbers are meaningless for such carriers. The air cargo

business is completely different from the transit-passenger business and although the

RPM/ASM equivalents are Revenue per Tonne Mile (RTM) and Available Tonne Mile

(ATM), there is no evidence to suggest that the modus operandi of passenger and freight

airlines is similar in anyway.

However, the quality of the data, and hence that of the results, is made slightly

spurious because the Operating Cost number (used as a proxy for TC) includes freights and

charter operations of the airlines too. As the charter business also involves passenger

transportation, it poses less of a problem than the inclusion of freight transportation cost in

the TC number, especially since those costs are being compared against passenger traffic data

(RPM and ASM) only. There is much complexity in trying to disaggregate the passenger and

freight component of each airline’s business. Fortunately, the average figure of 80% revenues

coming from passenger traffic6 has little variance across the airlines under consideration.

Thus, this nuance is ignored and Operating Expense is considered to be effectively passenger

traffic driven. Figure IV.1 lists the universe set of all airlines studied in this paper, but data

were not available for each of these airlines in every given year.

In order to make the sampling between these years representative of structural

changes to the airline industry and the macro-economy, four years were considered – 1990,

1995, 2000 and 2005. The summary statistics of operating expenses, real AC, RPM and ASM

for these years is presented in Figure IV.2 And, although initially I had imagined running all

the tests for both quantity variables (RPM and ASM), the high correlation between these two

6 Air Transport Association – Airline Handbook, Chapter 4 < http://www.airlines.org/products/AirlineHandbookCh4.htm>

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 14 -

variables (ranging from 0.9983 in 1990 to 0.9992 in 1995) makes both these measures

virtually identical. Since RPM is a measure of the actual quantity purchased as opposed to

the quantity produced and that the cost of the marginal traveller is non-negative (additional

fuel, administrative expenses, negative utility to co-passengers etc) albeit low, the RPM

measure is favoured over the ASM measure, throughout this paper.

Purely as a first approximation to what the AC-Q plot looks like, the data for each

of the aforementioned years is plotted on a scatter-plot as seen in Figure IV.3 While the large

number of data points does not reveal anything significant as such, a pure-eye ball indicates a

downward trend – that of decreasing AC with increasing Q – similar to Figure II.4. This eye-

ball approximation will be accurately tested in the section on results, and with further

granularity in this chapter too.

In order to test the hypothesis that two nested models that of the quadratic and

inverse are substantially different from the general model, it is first essential to run the

regressions of all possible nested models. These regressions are not only essential for the

sake of achieving completeness, but the residual sum of squares for each regression (RSS)

will eventually be useful in conducting the f-tests in the subsequent chapter. The following

regressions, using standard Ordinary Least Squares (OLS), are conducted by regressing AC

on:

Q0 + Q1

Q0 + Q2

Q0 + Q3

Q-1 + Q0

Q0 + Q1 + Q2

Q0 + Q1 + Q3

Q-1 + Q0 + Q1

Q0 + Q1 + Q2 + Q3

Q-1 + Q0 + Q1 + Q2

Q-1 + Q0 + Q1 + Q3

Q-1 + Q0 + Q1 + Q2 + Q3

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 15 -

Since we really only care about the bolded equations above, i.e. the inverse, the

quadratic, and the most general model, the regression results for only these equations (for each of

the four years) is presented in Figures IV.4-7. In each of these regression results, the t-statistic

corresponding to the Q-1 independent variable is larger (i.e. “more significant”) than that

corresponding to the Q1 or Q2 variable. Of course, looking at the t-statistic is not entirely

accurate when there is more than one independent variable, but this eye-ball further leads

strengthens our conviction that the inverse function is a closer approximation to the generalised

equation than the quadratic one.

Despite these econometric results, a graphical representation of the data further

proves the eye-ball estimates mentioned above. In each of the charts depicted in Figures

IV.8-11 the following four series are plotted:

Year Actuals: AC-Q directly from the data set and scaled to make a proportionate

comparison

Year Estimates: Considering the regression parameters as depicted in Figures

IV.4-7, and the given Q from the data-set, what predicted values of AC can be

extrapolated (using the inverse relationship).

Predictive Model w/ Year Estimates: For the entire range of Q on which the data

sits, use arbitrarily incremental values of Q and back out the corresponding AC

values based on the inverse relationship, and the calculated regression parameters.

Power: Fitting a 1/Q power trend-line across the entire data set that provides an

envelope curve which theoretically, should bind all the data points above it.

Again, suffice it to say that the eye-ball estimate suggests that the inverse function

is a relatively good estimator of the data. I have not run any f-tests yet, but the graphical

approximations suggest that I am on the right track.

Aside from these simple AC-Q plots, Figures IV.12-15 contain a Log(AC)-

Log(Q) plot for each of the years too. In general, the intermediary conclusions from the data

are that the inverse function is the closest approximation to the generalised model but the f-

tests need to be conducted, to which I know turn my attention.

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 16 -

V. Hypotheses Tests & Results

In the data section, I discussed several pieces of evidence that pointed in the same

direction – the AC-Q plots and the regressions – to the inverse function being a closer mirror

of the generalised function than the quadratic one. The f-tests are a way to concretise this

assumption, and make accurate conclusions on whether the eye-ball results hold statistical

weight. Before discussing the results though, a quick word on the f-tests, and the procedure

used.

Per Gujarati, the Restricted Least Squares (RLS) procedure involves testing a model

with any number of explanatory variables and more than one linear restriction. In order to

determine whether or not the restriction is valid (i.e. if the two restricted and unrestricted

equations are effectively the same), the f-statistic is calculated using the following equation:

)/(/)(

knRSSmRSSRSS

FUR

URR

−−

=

= )/(

/)(

ˆˆˆ

2

22

kn

m

uuu

UR

URR

∑∑∑

∑uRˆ2 = Restricted Least Squares (RSS) of the restricted regression

∑uURˆ2 = RSS of the unrestricted regression

m = number of linear restrictions

k = number of parameters in the unrestricted regression

n = number of observations

This f-statistic follows the f-distribution with m, (n-k) degrees of freedom.

For all the nested regressions discussed and outlined in the Data section, the RSS is

calculated and presented in Figure V.1. Moreover, using these RSS numbers and taking into

consideration all the nested regression pairs, various combinations of restricted and

unrestricted equations are tested to check if they are statistically different from each other or

not. The findings from these f-tests are presented in Figures V.2-5 for each of the 4 time

periods. The cells that are shaded yellow represent those significant f-statistics in which the

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 17 -

restriction imposed on the unrestricted equation is statistically invalid. For example, in

looking at the first shaded cell in Figure V.2, we see that the unrestricted equation is Q-1 + Q0

+ Q1 + Q2 + Q3 and the restricted equation is Q0 + Q1 + Q2 + Q3. Therefore, the single

restriction imposed on the unrestricted equation is Q-1 = 0. But, because the f-statistic is

significant at the 95% confidence interval, we reject the null hypotheses that the restricted

and unrestricted equations are the same. The conclusion then, of an invalid restriction

(whereby Q-1 = 0), must be seen in all the other nested regressions pairs in which Q-1 is

present in the unrestricted equation, but not in the restricted case. For the data in 1990, in

every case when the f-statistic was found to be significant at the 95% level, there is the single

restriction of Q-1 = 0 further substantiating all our initial hypotheses from the data section.

Unfortunately, this is not a robust finding across all the years sampled. In 1995, no

restriction has a significant f-statistic and in 2000, in only one of the nested equations is this

restriction considered invalid. It is important to mention however that although there is no

substantial proof of the aforementioned conclusion in the 1995 and 2000 data sets, there is no

evidence to disprove the claim either. Since no other restricted variables result in significant

f-statistics, there are no other candidates to claim greater resemblance to the general model

than the inverse function. In 2005 however, all the significant f-statistics involve a restriction

on Q-1 leading to a further claim that at least in this year and in 1990, the inverse function

statistically resembles the fully generalised model more than the quadratic function does. For

1995 and 2000, this finding is not conclusive, but there is no evidence that disproves the

aforementioned claim.

Aside from proving the functional form of the average cost curve in the airline

industry, this paper was written with the idea of deriving the industry’s Minimum Efficient

Scale (MES) output quantity. Simply defined, the MES is “the smallest quantity at which the

long-run average cost curve attains its minimum point (Besanko 2002).” And, considering

that we have confidence in the inverse function as proven with the f-tests, the MES can be

backed out as well. The inverse equation that we have parameter estimates for is AC = k +

β(Q-1). In an L-shaped curve, the MES represents the kink in the curve and the AC

corresponding to that MES is the asymptotic value to which the function tends, in its limit.

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 18 -

Hence, the 95% confidence interval for the asymptotic AC, from the above

equation, is k ± 2 x s.e. (k). But, considering the fact that the average cost curve represents a

floor below which it is not possible for any airline to operate in the long run (keeping in mind

that no airline is large enough to completely dictate input prices that are either fixed by the

government, or negotiated by labour unions, or priced in an internationally competitive

market with no substitutes) it does not make sense to consider the k – 2.s.e (k) values. In

Figure V.6, all the asymptotic ACs (i.e. the base case and with 1/2 standard errors above) are

calculated for each of the years under consideration. Moreover, the corresponding Q values

are also backed out, using the inverse relationship mentioned above and the parameter

estimates for every specific year. These results are presented in Figure V.6 too with several

interesting results discussed herewith:

Asymptotic AC closely resembles Mean AC – Almost by construction, the

calculation of the asymptotic AC, based on the description above, very closely

mirrors the mean AC numbers calculated empirically from the data set. In fact, for

each of the relevant years the Mean AC, as observed empirically, lies within the

lower bound of the asymptotic AC and the upward bound found by adding two

standard errors to the asymptotic AC number. Averaging across the four years, the

asymptotic band is seen to be between $46 - $56m at the 95% confidence interval

with the aforementioned restriction that prevents the AC from being below the

asymptote. The mean AC number for the entire period is $53m which fits smack in

the middle of the predicted range.

Little difference in AC across airlines – At $53m, the mean AC number is only

slightly different from the median number of $43m. Considering this, it seems that

there is an almost universal-cost constraint faced by all airlines that serve the US

passenger market. This finding is exactly in line with pre-existing historical finding as

discussed in the Literature Review section. The largest variance between costs

competitiveness was the 20% between US Airways and American. The median

number found here is about 23% different from the calculated mean. The three largest

costs of an airlines’ operating business are labour, fuel, and aircrafts each of which

are highly negotiated either by governments, unions or large corporations. Needless

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 19 -

to say (and as the literature suggests), volume discounts certainly help create a

decreasing cost curve with increasing size. But, these costs advantages are not

substantial and several experienced diseconomies of scale for the larger carriers,

make their cost structures not wholly different from that of the smaller regional

airlines. Thus, the data show little difference between the mean and median AC

numbers.

Expected MES mimics median, not mean Q – Reverse calculating the inflection

point quantity, assuming an L-shaped AC-Q plot and an inverse function, yields a

minimum efficient scale number ranging from 2,010 – 4,020m RPM. In comparison,

across the time period studied, the mean output at which airlines operate is a

staggering >10x different at 58,972m RPM. At first, this huge discrepancy seems to

indicate that the inverse function is a poor mechanism to derive the industry’s

minimum efficient scale number. But, it is important to keep in mind just how skewed

this average number really is. There are six major national carriers in the US with an

RPM >40,000m and these airlines – American, United, Delta, Continental, Southwest

and Northwest – constitute over 65% of the market share. All the other carriers are

significantly smaller and serve either a combination of route-pairs or have a regional

geographical footprint. The 6-carrier RPM average is 280,505m clearly outstripping

the mean number, and that of the regional carriers too. In order to determine whether

or not the average quantity number is heavily skewed or not, the median values across

the time frame are also calculated. Median RPM is 9,650m which is less than one-

quarter of the average quantity number mentioned earlier. Considering the dual-sized

nature of the US market, where few large gorillas co-exist along with much smaller

regional carriers, this difference between the mean and median quantity numbers

makes complete sense.

Implications of relatively small MES – The upward bound on the MES number is

4,020m and with certain assumptions of the US aviation market, I am able to estimate

an MES fleet size number too. About 64% of passengers fly <1000miles on an

average flight (Huang 2000), so I have roughly estimated the number of miles per

passenger per flight to be 800miles. This number is corroborated with the Bureau of

Transportation Statistics that says the average passenger trip-length was 868miles in

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 20 -

20047. The MTC estimates that there will be 134 seats on average daily flight by 2010.

So, for present-day estimates I have used a 130 seat number for the average aircraft,

which is expected to fly at about 65% capacity8 thereby reducing the number of

revenue paying passengers per flight to about 85. Dividing the RPM number by the

number of daily passenger miles (365 x 800 x 85) we get the number of daily flights

that an airline must operate to be at MES, at 161. At 800miles per flight, the average

flying time, accounting for landing delays due to air traffic clearance delays, is about

two hours. And, aircraft utilisation is estimated to be 10 hours per day; reasonable

considering the best-in-class JetBlue does about 12.5 hours, and Southwest at 11.7

claims it is 14% higher than industry average. Therefore, the total fleet size

requirement, to achieve minimum efficient scale, is a meagre 8 aircrafts! This

surprising result is not un-conditional however; it merits further explanation and

greater investigation, to which I shall now turn.

VI. Conclusions

The key findings of this research and its consequent implications have already been

discussed toward the end of the previous section. As a conclusion though, it would be

pertinent to elaborate on them in slightly further detail, lay open the possibilities for

future research, and summarize the main arguments made thus far.

Almost all historic economic literature suggests that scale has a decreasing effect

on average cost, both in the transportation industry generally and in aviation specifically.

Using graphical methods as first approximations, followed through with regressions and

f-tests, this conclusion was seen to be valid in the US passenger airline market in years

1990, and 2005. The research was conducted by modelling all possible functional forms

of the output quantity, using revenue per passenger mile as the measure, on the average

cost of airline operations. The inverse functional form was seen to most closely resemble

7 http://www.bts.gov/press_releases/2005/bts012_05/html/bts012_05.html 8 Load factor in September, 2007 is 76.8% but historically, this is a busy month for travel, and airline data has been looking brighter for 2007 that any year post-9/11. Considering that this MES evaluation has been averaged since 1990-2005, a more conservative load factor number is essential to consider. <http://www.airtransportnews.aero/article.pl?categ=&id=7969>

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 21 -

the generalised model relative to the quadratic functional form, the latter of which would

denote clear eventual diseconomies of scale. Since, the inverse functional form was

shown (with complete certainty for 1990 and 2005) to hold true, the implication was that

there was no upward sloping part of the AC curve when plotted against Q, as the

quadratic functional form might suggest. Thus, there is no single equilibrium output

quantity that is potentially profit maximising for an airline carrier. Once minimum

efficient scale is achieved, adding greater capacity may only increase management risk of

operational failure without substantially reducing cost but there is no evidence of

impending diseconomies either.

From the data set, procured from the Bureau of Transportation Statistics, the

derived MES was found to be a fleet size of 8 aircrafts. This is a relatively low barrier to

entry in the already competitive airline market, and may actually provide an explanation

as to why 110 airlines actually choose to fly in the American skies. The general estimate

of this fleet size number is believable considering previous literature on the dual-sized

nature of the airline industry and empirical evidence that suggests such co-existence of

large-small airlines even today. However, the specific estimate ought to be viewed with

some degree of scepticism. Firstly, the data set only includes half of the total airlines

under operations and the smallest ones, arguably with the highest cost, are completely left

out. Their presence in the data set would change the results. Secondly, I had mentioned

how the Operating Cost number was not exactly accurate since it took into consideration

charter and freight services of the airline too. The difficulty of isolating only scheduled

passenger operations for the airline introduces an added degree of artificiality to the result.

Thirdly, the asymptotic constant (k) was assumed to provide a lower bound to the costs

faced by all airlines. Individual firm effects were not considered in the model that may

have resulted in specific airlines operating below this artificially created boundary.

Finally, although firm size has the single most significant effect on AC (Section II) there

are several other factors such as aircraft type and route selection that have a differential

impact on AC too, and therefore on the MES calculation.

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 22 -

The low barriers to entry however, create several interesting opportunities for the

future of US aviation. A speculative result of my own is for large international carriers

such as Lufthansa, and British Airways to possibly create subsidiary organisations that

remain detached from the parent company but operate only specific routes either in a

third-party country or internationally to their own hub-destination. This is exactly what

Virgin American has done – using its existing expertise from Virgin Atlantic, the

partially owned American subsidiary operates only on specific lucrative routes in the US.

Part of the brand name is carried, but the operational costs are completely distinct. With a

dozen aircrafts, this model might actually prove to be profitable in the longer run.

Although it is impossible right now, considering the presence of only sixth freedom

regulation, this low MES could allow for airlines to create more Special Purpose Vehicles

(SPVs) that service alternative international routes without tapping into the pre-existing

network and create additional scheduling difficulties. The key difference here is that a

larger airline’s expansion does not have to increase the size of the existing network – it

can modularise its airline operations based on geography to create separate regional

clusters with airlines that operate with their own P&Ls. Increasing network size creates

added complications and increases risk without much benefit, if the airline is already

operating on the asymptotic part of the average cost curve.

There are several further areas of research that could build upon the existing work:

Demographic Concentration – Rather than thinking of areas of service as

specific geographical regions, this research could be used to test if airlines

serving specific a demography (such as old age people or the business

traveller) would face similar cost curves and low scale requirements.

Charter & Freight Services, Other Countries – A natural extension of the

existing research would be to use a similar procedure to establish the size

recommendation for freight and charter airlines too. Moreover, this paper

is solely for US based airlines but the methodology can be applied to

international carriers in other regional clusters too. In order to increase the

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 23 -

accuracy of results, more frequent sampling (i.e. adding more years to the

data set) of a more complete set of airlines would be required.

Different Cost and Quantity Measures – This paper used Average

Operating Cost and RPM data, but there are several other measures such

as fleet size, number of aircrafts, unit-seat-mile costs etc that ought to be

modelled too, and the conclusions of this paper verified. Moreover, cost

and quantity are both vector functions, and individual input-pairs (such as

regressing number total wage cost on number of employees) may help to

disaggregate specific input-effects too, once adjusted for with the omitted

variable bias.

Firm Specific Effects – This paper aggregates data for all US airlines, but

a clustering of this research for a given size of aircrafts will increase the

accuracy of the results. For individual airlines, this model could be used

for a comparative statics prediction of their own cost structure. It is

beyond the scope of this paper to discuss individual firm performance,

relative to the benchmark, but this study can easily be extended in that

direction. Instead of cross-sectional data, an individual firm could use its

own time-series data with a similar methodology for its own cost

allocation and resource planning.

Overall, the scope of airline cost curve and MES research is massive. This paper has

merely scratched the surface with its two main conclusions. Firstly, that US based airlines

experience an inverse cost function for their passenger operations. And, secondly, the barrier

to entry from a fleet standpoint, as measured by minimum efficient scale, is relatively small.

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 24 -

VII. References

Besanko, David A. and Ronald R. Braeutigam. Microeconomics: an integrated approach. New Jersey: John, Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2002. Biederman, Paul. The US Airline Industry. New York: Praeger, 1982. Forsyth, Peter, et al. Air Transport. Northhampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing, 2002. Gujrati, Damodar N.. Basic Economics: Third Edition: Mc.Graw-Hill, Inc., 1995. Intriligator, Michael D., et al. Econometric Models, Techniques, and Applications. New Jersey: Prentice Hall-Inc,1996. James, George W.. Airline Economics. Lexington: Lexington Books, 1982. Johnston, John. Econometric Methods. : McGraw Hill, Inc., 1984. Morrell, Peter S.. Airline Finance. Burlington: Ashgate, 2007. O'Connor, William E.. An Introduction to Airline Economics. New York: Praeger Publishers, 1985. Straszheim, Mahlon R. The International Airline Industry. Washington DC: The Brookings Institution, 1969. Online Resources Airline Handbook Chapter. -1 2005. . 14 Dec. 2007. <http://www.airlines.org/products/AirlineHandbookCh4.htm>. Airline Glossary. -1 2004. . 14 Dec. 2007. <http://www.avjobs.com/history/airline-glossary.asp>. MTC -- Planning -- Regional Airport. -1 2004. . 14 Dec. 2007. <http://www.mtc.ca.gov/planning/air_plan/air_plan_forecasts.htm#operations>. RITA | BTS | Transt. -1 2007. . 14 Dec. 2007. <http://www.transtats.bts.gov/homepage.asp>. Sheng-Chen Alex Huang, "An Analysis of Air Passenger Average Trip Lengths and Fare Levels in US Domestic Markets" (February 1, 2000). Institute of Transportation Studies. Working Papers. <http://repositories.cdlib.org/its/papers/triplengths>

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 25 -

American15%

Southwest12%

United12%

Delta11%

Continental8%

Northwest7%

US Air5%

JetBlue4%

America West4%

Air Tran3%

Other19%

AmericanSouthwestUnitedDeltaContinentalNorthwestUS AirJetBlueAmerica WestAir TranOther

6 major carriers all have an annual RPM of >40bn

VIII. Appendix

Figure I.1: US Airline market share, RPM basis Oct-06 to Sep-07

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 26 -

Figure II.1: Direct Operating Cost Estimates for Selected Aircrafts, US Domestic Experience, 1965 (Straszheim 1969)

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 27 -

Figure II.2: Average Operating Costs of Sample of Carriers, by Seat-Miles Flown and by Cost Component, 1962 – (Straszheim 1969)

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 28 -

Some Principal Cost Categories in 1983, Majors and Nationals

Labour46%

Fuel31%

Depreciation & Amortization

9%

Traffic Commissions9%

Interest Expense5%

LabourFuelDepreciation & AmortizationTraffic CommissionsInterest Expense

Source: Air Transport Association of America (O'Connor)

Figure II.3: Major cost categories for US-based carriers

Figure III.4: Average Unit Costs by Airline Size, Domestic Airlines – 1980 (Biederman 1982)

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 29 -

Figure III.1: Expansion Paths for the Firm (Intriligator 1996)

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 30 -

\

Figure III.2: Cost Curves & Equilibrium Levels of Output (Intriligator 1996)

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 31 -

Figure III.3: Estimated Average Cost Curve (Intriligator 1996)

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 32 -

Air Wisconsin Airlines CorpAirTran Airways CorporationAlaska Airlines Inc.Allegiant AirAloha Airlines Inc.America West Airlines Inc.American Airlines Inc.American Eagle Airlines Inc.ATA Airlines d/b/a ATAAtlantic Southeast AirlinesCasino ExpressChampion AirComair Inc.Continental Air Lines Inc.Continental MicronesiaDelta Air Lines Inc.Expressjet Airlines Inc.Falcon Air ExpressFrontier Airlines Inc.GoJet Airlines, LLC d/b/a United ExpressHawaiian Airlines Inc.Horizon AirJetBlue AirwaysMesa Airlines Inc.Mesaba AirlinesMiami Air InternationalMidwest Airline, Inc.North American AirlinesNorthwest Airlines Inc.Omni Air ExpressPace AirlinesPinnacle Airlines Inc.Primaris Airlines Inc.PSA Airlines Inc.Ryan International AirlinesSkywest Airlines Inc.Southwest Airlines Co.Spirit Air LinesSun Country Airlines d/b/a Mn AirlinesTrans States AirlinesUnited Air Lines Inc.US Airways Inc.USA 3000 Airlines Figure IV.1: List of all Airlines Considered

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 33 -

Legend: (1) v1 – Airline names (2) y_xxxx_rea~x: Real Operating Expense for the given year, scaled (3) y_xxxx_real~d: Real AC, scaled (4) y_xxxx_rpm_d: Scaled RPM The scaling is an effort to make sure that all the variables have means that are within one tenth power of each other, thereby making comparisons across them easier and meaningful. Figure IV.2: Summary Statistics

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 34 -

AC-Q (Select Data Points)

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160

Scaled Q (RPM)

Scal

ed A

C (O

pEx

/ RPM

) in

2005

$

1990

2000

2005

1995

Figure IV.3: AC-Q Scatter Plot for all relevant years

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 35 -

Figure IV.4: Key Regression Results for 1990

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 36 -

Figure IV.5: Key Regression Results for 1995

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 37 -

Figure IV.6: Key Regression Results for 2000

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 38 -

Figure IV.7: Key Regression Results for 2005

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 39 -

0

50

100

150

200

250

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000

Q

AC

Predictive Mode w/ 1990 Estimates

1990 Estimates

1990 Actuals

Power (Predictive Mode w/ 1990 Estimates)

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000

Q

AC

Predictive Mode w/ 1995 Estimates

1995 Estimates

1995 Actuals

Power (Predictive Mode w/ 1995Estimates)

Figure IV.8: AC-Q Plot & Predictive Model (1990)

Figure IV.9: AC-Q Plot & Predictive Model (1995)

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 40 -

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

500

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000 4500

Q

AC

Predictive Mode w/ 2000 Estimates

2000 Estimates

2000 Actuals

Power (Predictive Mode w/ 2000 Estimates)

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

200

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000 4500 5000

Q

AC

Predictive Mode w/ 2005 Estimates

2005 Estimates

2005 Actuals

Power (Predictive Mode w/ 2005 Estimates)

Figure IV.10: AC-Q Plot & Predictive Model (2000)

Figure IV.11: AC-Q Plot & Predictive Model (2005)

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 41 -

Log-Log Plot - 1990

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500

Log Q

Log

AC

Log-Log Plot for 1995

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000

Log Q

Log

AC

Figure IV. 12: Log(AC)-Log(Q) Plot for 1990

Figure IV. 13: Log(AC)-Log(Q) Plot for 1995

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 42 -

Log-Log Plot for 2000

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

4

4.5

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000

Log Q

Log

AC

Log-Log Plot for 2005

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000 4500

Log Q

Log

AC

Figure IV. 14: Log(AC)-Log(Q) Plot for 2000

Figure IV. 15: Log(AC)-Log(Q) Plot for 2005

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 43 -

RSS by regressing AC on Q Q2 Q3 Qinv Q_Q2 Q_Q3 Qinv_Q Q_Q2_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q2 Qinv_Q_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q31990 17904.68 18657.31 18913.57 10712.19 16801.93 17273.59 10590.01 14170.93 10471.39 10539.57 9823.761995 19187.42 20379.56 20716.26 18345.53 17287.62 17932.94 17483.03 15422.75 16552.31 16918.01 15232.702000 16660.50 16926.50 17032.37 16070.15 16298.63 16389.99 15963.73 16051.64 15864.46 15889.99 15790.042005 9654.49 9719.70 9730.50 7769.53 9487.68 9573.13 7769.16 9100.05 7754.79 7764.60 7678.06

1990 Restricted Unrestricted RSS(r) RSS(ur ) n m k F (n-k) Comp. F-stat Significant?Q Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 17904.676 9823.7622 19 3 4 2.2566 15 3.29 NQ2 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 18657.307 9823.7622 19 3 4 2.3673 15 3.29 NQ3 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 18913.566 9823.7622 19 3 4 2.4030 15 3.29 NQinv Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 10712.185 9823.7622 19 3 4 0.4147 15 3.29 NQ_Q2 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 16801.933 9823.7622 19 2 4 3.1149 15 3.68 NQ_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 17273.593 9823.7622 19 2 4 3.2346 15 3.68 NQinv_Q Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 10590.007 9823.7622 19 2 4 0.5427 15 3.68 NQ_Q2_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 14170.929 9823.7622 19 1 4 4.6015 15 4.54 YQ Q_Q2 17904.676 16801.933 19 1 2 1.0470 17 4.45 NQ Q_Q3 17904.676 17273.593 19 1 2 0.5992 17 4.45 NQ Qinv_Q 17904.676 10590.007 19 1 2 6.9451 17 4.45 YQ Q_Q2_Q3 17904.676 14170.929 19 2 3 1.6683 16 3.63 NQ Qinv_Q_Q2 17904.676 10471.394 19 2 3 3.3213 16 3.63 NQ Qinv_Q_Q3 17904.676 10539.568 19 2 3 3.2908 16 3.63 NQ2 Q_Q2 18657.307 16801.933 19 1 2 1.6906 17 4.45 NQ2 Q_Q2_Q3 20379.556 14170.929 19 2 3 2.4372 16 3.63 NQ2 Qinv_Q_Q2 16926.5 10471.394 19 2 3 3.0509 16 3.63 NQ3 Q_Q3 18913.566 17273.593 19 1 2 1.4740 17 4.45 NQ3 Q_Q2_Q3 18913.566 14170.929 19 2 3 2.0060 16 3.63 NQ3 Qinv_Q_Q3 18913.566 10539.568 19 2 3 3.5420 16 3.63 NQinv Qinv_Q 10712.185 10590.007 19 1 2 0.1939 17 4.45 NQinv Qinv_Q_Q2 10712.185 10471.394 19 2 3 0.1798 16 3.63 NQinv Qinv_Q_Q3 10712.185 10539.568 19 2 3 0.1289 16 3.63 NQ_Q2 Q_Q2_Q3 16801.933 14170.929 19 1 3 2.5054 16 4.49 NQ_Q2 Qinv_Q_Q2 16801.933 10471.394 19 1 3 6.0284 16 4.49 YQ_Q3 Q_Q2_Q3 17273.593 14170.929 19 1 3 2.8739 16 4.49 NQ_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q3 17273.593 10539.568 19 1 3 6.2375 16 4.49 YQinv_Q Qinv_Q_Q2 10590.007 10471.394 19 1 3 0.1792 16 4.49 NQinv_Q Qinv_Q_Q3 10590.007 10539.568 19 1 3 0.0762 16 4.49 N

1995 Restricted Unrestricted RSS(r) RSS(ur ) n m k F (n-k) Comp. F-stat Significant?Q Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 19187.415 15232.699 27 3 4 1.5802 23 3.3 NQ2 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 20379.556 15232.699 27 3 4 1.9362 23 3.3 NQ3 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 20716.256 15232.699 27 3 4 2.0294 23 3.3 NQinv Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 18345.525 15232.699 27 3 4 1.3009 23 3.3 NQ_Q2 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 17287.617 15232.699 27 2 4 1.3670 23 3.42 NQ_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 17932.935 15232.699 27 2 4 1.7316 23 3.42 NQinv_Q Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 17483.029 15232.699 27 2 4 1.4802 23 3.42 NQ_Q2_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 15422.752 15232.699 27 1 4 0.2834 23 4.28 NQ Q_Q2 19187.415 17287.617 27 1 2 2.4753 25 4.24 NQ Q_Q3 19187.415 17932.935 27 1 2 1.6345 25 4.24 NQ Qinv_Q 19187.415 17483.029 27 1 2 2.2207 25 2.24 NQ Q_Q2_Q3 19187.415 15422.752 27 2 3 2.3545 24 3.4 NQ Qinv_Q_Q2 19187.415 16552.307 27 2 3 1.6480 24 3.4 NQ Qinv_Q_Q3 19187.415 16918.006 27 2 3 1.4193 24 3.4 NQ2 Q_Q2 20379.556 17287.617 27 1 2 3.7929 25 4.24 NQ2 Q_Q2_Q3 20379.556 15422.752 27 2 3 2.9187 24 3.4 NQ2 Qinv_Q_Q2 20379.556 16552.307 27 2 3 2.2536 24 3.4 NQ3 Q_Q3 20716.256 17932.935 27 1 2 3.3589 25 4.24 NQ3 Q_Q2_Q3 20716.256 15422.752 27 2 3 3.0663 24 3.4 NQ3 Qinv_Q_Q3 20716.256 16918.006 27 2 3 2.2002 24 3.4 NQinv Qinv_Q 18345.525 17483.029 27 1 2 1.1753 25 4.24 NQinv Qinv_Q_Q2 18345.525 16552.307 27 2 3 1.1730 24 3.4 NQinv Qinv_Q_Q3 18345.525 16918.006 27 2 3 0.9338 24 3.4 NQ_Q2 Q_Q2_Q3 17287.617 15422.752 27 1 3 2.5889 24 4.26 NQ_Q2 Qinv_Q_Q2 17287.617 16552.307 27 1 3 1.0208 24 4.26 NQ_Q3 Q_Q2_Q3 17932.935 15422.752 27 1 3 3.3594 24 4.26 NQ_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q3 17932.935 16918.006 27 1 3 1.3583 24 4.26 NQinv_Q Qinv_Q_Q2 17483.029 16552.307 27 1 3 1.2777 24 4.26 NQinv_Q Qinv_Q_Q3 17483.029 16918.006 27 1 3 0.7756 24 4.26 N

Figure V.1: RSS results for each nested regression

Figure V.2: F-test results for 1990

Figure V.3: F-test results for 1995

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 44 -

2000 Restricted Unrestricted RSS(r) RSS(ur ) n m k F (n-k) Comp. F-stat Significant?Q Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 16660.499 15790.037 31 3 4 0.4702 27 2.96 NQ2 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 16926.5 15790.037 31 3 4 0.6043 27 2.96 NQ3 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 17032.369 15790.037 31 3 4 0.6565 27 2.96 NQinv Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 16070.147 15790.037 31 3 4 0.1569 27 2.96 NQ_Q2 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 16298.633 15790.037 31 2 4 0.4213 27 3.35 NQ_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 16389.985 15790.037 31 2 4 0.4942 27 3.35 NQinv_Q Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 15963.734 15790.037 31 2 4 0.1469 27 3.35 NQ_Q2_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 16051.644 15790.037 31 1 4 0.4400 27 4.21 NQ Q_Q2 16660.499 16298.633 31 1 2 0.6299 29 4.18 NQ Q_Q3 19187.415 16389.985 31 1 2 4.2281 29 4.18 YQ Qinv_Q 19187.415 15963.734 31 1 2 4.8723 29 4.18 YQ Q_Q2_Q3 19187.415 16051.644 31 2 3 2.2880 28 3.34 NQ Qinv_Q_Q2 19187.415 15864.46 31 2 3 2.4246 28 3.34 NQ Qinv_Q_Q3 19187.415 15889.989 31 2 3 2.4060 28 3.34 NQ2 Q_Q2 16926.5 16298.633 31 1 2 1.0757 29 4.18 NQ2 Q_Q2_Q3 16926.5 16051.644 31 2 3 0.7236 28 3.34 NQ2 Qinv_Q_Q2 16926.5 15864.46 31 2 3 0.8784 28 3.34 NQ3 Q_Q3 17032.369 16389.985 31 1 2 1.0937 29 4.18 NQ3 Q_Q2_Q3 17032.369 16051.644 31 2 3 0.8061 28 3.34 NQ3 Qinv_Q_Q3 17032.369 15889.989 31 2 3 0.9390 28 3.34 NQinv Qinv_Q 16070.147 15963.734 31 1 2 0.1920 29 4.18 NQinv Qinv_Q_Q2 16070.147 15864.46 31 2 3 0.1792 28 3.34 NQinv Qinv_Q_Q3 16070.147 15889.989 31 2 3 0.1570 28 3.34 NQ_Q2 Q_Q2_Q3 16298.633 16051.644 31 1 3 0.4243 28 4.2 NQ_Q2 Qinv_Q_Q2 16298.633 15864.46 31 1 3 0.7459 28 4.2 NQ_Q3 Q_Q2_Q3 16389.985 16051.644 31 1 3 0.5780 28 4.2 NQ_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q3 16389.985 15889.989 31 1 3 0.8542 28 4.2 NQinv_Q Qinv_Q_Q2 15963.734 15864.46 31 1 3 0.1741 28 4.2 NQinv_Q Qinv_Q_Q3 15963.734 15889.989 31 1 3 0.1293 28 4.2 N

2005 Restricted Unrestricted RSS(r) RSS(ur ) n m k F (n-k) Comp. F-stat Significant?Q Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 9654.487 7678.0634 43 3 4 2.6613 39 2.84 NQ2 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 9719.704 7678.0634 43 3 4 2.7307 39 2.84 NQ3 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 9730.4986 7678.0634 43 3 4 2.7421 39 2.84 NQinv Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 7769.5325 7678.0634 43 3 4 0.1530 39 2.84 NQ_Q2 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 9487.6778 7678.0634 43 2 4 3.7193 39 3.23 YQ_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 9573.1317 7678.0634 43 2 4 3.8602 39 3.23 YQinv_Q Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 7769.1595 7678.0634 43 2 4 0.2286 39 3.23 NQ_Q2_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q2_Q3 9100.0484 7678.0634 43 1 4 6.0942 39 4.08 YQ Q_Q2 9654.487 9487.6778 43 1 2 0.7084 41 4.08 NQ Q_Q3 9654.487 9573.1317 43 1 2 0.3455 41 4.08 NQ Qinv_Q 9654.487 7769.1595 43 1 2 8.0065 41 4.08 YQ Q_Q2_Q3 9654.487 9100.0484 43 2 3 1.1486 40 3.23 NQ Qinv_Q_Q2 9654.487 7754.7912 43 2 3 3.9354 40 3.23 YQ Qinv_Q_Q3 9654.487 7764.5997 43 2 3 3.9150 40 3.23 YQ2 Q_Q2 9719.704 9487.6778 43 1 2 0.9787 41 4.08 NQ2 Q_Q2_Q3 9719.704 9100.0484 43 2 3 1.2751 40 2.84 NQ2 Qinv_Q_Q2 9719.704 7754.7912 43 2 3 4.0432 40 2.84 YQ3 Q_Q3 9730.4986 9573.1317 43 1 2 0.6631 41 4.08 NQ3 Q_Q2_Q3 9730.4986 9100.0484 43 2 3 1.2958 40 3.23 NQ3 Qinv_Q_Q3 9730.4986 7764.5997 43 2 3 4.0407 40 3.23 YQinv Qinv_Q 7769.5325 7769.1595 43 1 2 0.0020 41 4.08 NQinv Qinv_Q_Q2 7769.5325 7754.7912 43 2 3 0.0379 40 3.23 NQinv Qinv_Q_Q3 7769.5325 7764.5997 43 2 3 0.0127 40 3.23 NQ_Q2 Q_Q2_Q3 9487.6778 9100.0484 43 1 3 1.6342 40 4.08 NQ_Q2 Qinv_Q_Q2 9487.6778 7754.7912 43 1 3 7.3058 40 4.08 YQ_Q3 Q_Q2_Q3 9573.1317 9100.0484 43 1 3 1.9767 40 4.08 NQ_Q3 Qinv_Q_Q3 9573.1317 7764.5997 43 1 3 7.5567 40 4.08 YQinv_Q Qinv_Q_Q2 7769.1595 7754.7912 43 1 3 0.0740 40 4.08 NQinv_Q Qinv_Q_Q3 7769.1595 7764.5997 43 1 3 0.0235 40 4.08 N

Figure V.4: F-test results for 2000

Figure V.5: F-test results for 2005

Economics Honours Thesis Kanoria, Samvit P. Airline Cost Curves & MES

- 45 -

Q (AC+1s.e.)

Q (AC+2s.e) Mean AC Median AC Mean Q Median Q

26.15 13.07 50.07 36.07 597.61 134.8434.96 17.48 55.31 40.33 568.08 35.0669.00 34.50 51.72 42.47 648.48 91.9730.69 15.35 54.50 52.96 544.71 124.12

1990199520002005

k s.e.(k ) β s.e.(β) Asymp. ACAsymp. AC +

1s.e.Asymp. AC +

2s.e.

1990 39.39478 6.404639 167.4645 43.97627 39.39 45.80 52.201995 46.55871 6.560328 229.3714 104.4104 46.56 53.12 59.682000 45.79524 5.74216 396.2312 259.6505 45.80 51.54 57.282005 51.74434 2.265038 69.51408 21.46668 51.74 54.01 56.27

Asymp. ACAsymp. AC +

1s.e.Asymp. AC +

2s.e.Q

(AC+1s.e.)

Scaled Averages 45.87 51.12 56.36 40.20Un-scaled Averages (in millions) 46$ 51$ 56$ 4,020

Q (AC+2s.e) Mean AC Median AC Mean Q Median Q

20.10 52.90 42.96 589.72 96.502,010 53$ 43$ 58,972 9,650

Scaled AveragesUn-scaled Averages (in millions)

Figure V.6: MES Calculations & Results