27 protectionism, free trade and preferential trade (p. ruiz nÁpoles)

Upload: alejandroaraujo

Post on 03-Jun-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    1/62

    PROTECTIONISM, FREE TRADE AND PREFERENTIAL TRADE:THE MEXICAN EXPERIENCE

    by

    Pablo Ruiz Npoles

    Graduate Program in Economics,Faculty of Economics, Universidad Nacional Autnoma de Mxicoemail: [email protected] Visiting Professor at Facultad Latinoamericana de Ciencias Sociales,sede Mxico email: [email protected]

    1

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    2/62

    PROTECTIONISM, FREE TRADE AND PREFERENTIAL TRADE:THE MEXICAN EXPERIENCE

    Pablo Ruiz Npoles

    JEL Classification : D57, F43, L60, and O54.Key words: free trade, exports, growth, employment.

    Abstract

    This paper is a theoretical and applied analysis of free trade policies and protectionism.

    First, the evolution of free trade theories, vis--vis protectionist ideas, is described, starting

    from the classical economists, their assumptions and implications for attaining welfare

    Pareto optimality, full employment and growth. Secondly, a structural analysis of the

    Mexican economys performance in three successive but different periods, regarding trade

    policies for the last thirty-five years is presented. I conclude that extreme free-trade policies

    have not been good for economic stability, growth and employment creation in Mexico.

    2

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    3/62

    I NTRODUCTION

    The Heckscher-Ohlin (H-O) theorem, based on a General Equilibrium model, and the

    Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) doctrine are considered the two pillars of the neoclassical

    theory of international trade (Krueger, 1983), despite strong criticism from both theoretical

    and empirical perspectives. The neoclassical theory of trade claims that free trade and

    exchange rate flexibility are a means for achieving trade balance and Pareto optima in

    production and consumption. These ideas belong to mainstream economics , which has been

    taught as the leading economic paradigm in graduate schools of economics, political

    economy and other social disciplines at all major universities around the world for the last

    four or five decades. In contrast, active trade policies (protectionism) and fixed or regulated

    exchange rates prevailed in most countries, developed and underdeveloped, for most of the

    twentieth century. It was in the late seventies and early eighties when liberalism started to

    prevail in economic policy both domestically, by reducing government expenses and

    regulation, and internationally, by reducing tariffs and eliminating non-tariff barriers to

    trade in goods and services.

    However, neo-liberal policies have had mixed economic results. While they have

    stopped inflation and reduced fiscal deficits, they have not produced economic growth, full

    employment, and in some cases, not even balanced trade. This has particularly affected

    underdeveloped countries, which have suffered from a lack of economic growth,

    widespread unemployment, growing poverty and social inequality since long before these

    policies were applied by their governments. Their situation seems to have worsened rather

    than improved due to the application of said liberal policies in the last twenty years.

    In Mexico, in the middle of the recession that resulted from the 1982 foreign debt

    and foreign exchange crises, the government initiated a process of trade liberalization as

    3

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    4/62

    part of a set of liberal policies aimed at reducing state intervention in the economy. After

    forty years of being a highly closed economy, there was an opening of the Mexican

    economy as a result of a set of free market policies. The process, which was gradual in the

    beginning, accelerated in the mid 1980s when Mexico joined GATT, and it peaked when

    Mexico joined the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) in 1994.

    The package of liberal measures was promoted in Mexico and in other developing

    countries by the US government, the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund

    (Sachs, 1988, p.77). The same type of reforms were also applied in certain Latin American

    countries in the eighties and the nineties, under the assumption that mere deregulation

    constituted the structural change needed to correct a distorted economy and increase the

    level of employment and wages (Weller, 2000, p.13). These liberal policies, based on

    exports, were recommended as a new strategy both for recovery and for growth (Sachs,

    1988). The set of policies were in line with the Washington Consensus (Moreno-Brid, et

    al ., 2004-5).

    This change in development strategy in favor of trade liberalization and state

    downsizing is the most significant event in Mexicos economic history in the last five

    decades. It is also recognized that NAFTA was a main cause of the spike in exports and

    foreign direct investment (FDI) that has taken place in Mexico. The effects of NAFTA after

    ten years in effect have been thoroughly studied by experts, with both favorable and

    unfavorable evaluations from the Mexican perspective (see, for example, Blecker, 2006;

    Moreno-Brid et al ., 2005; Puyana and Romero, 2005; Romalis, 2005; Casares and Sobarzo,

    2004; Weintraub, 2004).

    Some experts have interpreted NAFTAs role in Mexico as a corollary of the

    Washington Consensus set of liberalization, deregulation and privatization measures that

    4

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    5/62

    were adopted by the Mexican government (Blecker, 2006). This is not necessarily the case,

    because while unrestricted, unilateral free trade has been part of trade liberalization policies

    in most of Latin America, a three-country preferential trade area like NAFTA has different

    operating rules, with different effects on trading partners.

    When looking at the various trade policies in perspective, one may rightfully ask

    how much they have helped the Mexican economy, considering three different policy

    phases: protected trade, unilateral trade, and preferential trade agreements, such as NAFTA.

    Thus, some of the questions that may arise are: what were the economic and political aims

    of the liberal policies, and of NAFTA, for Mexico? And how well have these aims been

    reached? We wish to know what if anything went wrong with the various liberal policies.

    In this paper we try to address some of these questions by analyzing the

    performance of the Mexican economy over three successive periods during the last 35

    years: protected trade (1970-1981), unilateral free trade (1982-1993), and the preferential

    trade agreement, NAFTA, (1994-2005). 1 In the first section we present the main theoretical

    arguments in favor of free trade versus protectionism. In particular, we analyze two aspects:

    (1) the benefits of free trade and its beneficiaries, and (2) the conditions for Pareto

    optimality under free trade. In the second section we present selected data on the Mexican

    economy relating a key variable, exports, with other important aggregated variables:

    product, employment and imports. The purpose is to compare economic results in the three

    periods mentioned.

    I. FREE TRADE VERSUS PROTECTIONISM : SOME THEORETICAL ARGUMENTS

    1. Free trade arguments of the classical economists

    1 Notice that protectionist policies were in effect in Mexico for about forty years, from the late forties to themid-eighties.

    5

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    6/62

    When Adam Smith criticized the protectionist ideas of the Mercantilists in 1776, 2 his main

    argument based on logical reasoning inspired by rationalism was that foreign trade must

    be balanced rather than positive for any given country, and that this outcome should be

    obtained by free trade between trading partners, and not by state intervention through the

    establishment of taxes or other restraints on imports. Smith also postulated that when the

    trade balance is positive in any given period, currency (gold and silver) accumulates, so all

    kinds of goods are not imported and thus, consumption and investment are hindered in

    order to reach higher levels, which should only be determined by a countrys productive

    capacity as well as by free competition, i.e. laissez faire, laissez passer (Smith, 1937, pp.

    398-423).

    The basis for the above arguments was that for Smith free trade within a nation

    free competition is the only mechanism that guarantees the optimal use of each

    individuals abilities which, in turn, leads to the optimal public benefit, the invisible hand

    argument. When this principle is applied to nations, rather than to individuals, it means that

    free trade between nations leads to the highest attainable level of production for the trading

    countries considered as a group, that is, the world (Smith, 1937, pp.423-4).

    Ricardo criticized the Mercantilists ideas too, but on different grounds. For him it

    was not through trade that economies grow, because, he argued, foreign trade does not by

    itself create any value at all; what a country imports is equal in value to what it exports, and

    both flows are always balanced in value terms, since whenever a balance is due, it was

    always paid with gold or silver which at the time played the role of both money and

    commodities. But for Ricardo there is an important exception to this argument, and that is

    2 The protectionist practices prevailed in England since long before Thomas Muns ideas in the seventeenthcentury, until the nineteenth century.

    6

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    7/62

    when a countrys imports are wage goods, and they may be obtained cheaper abroad than at

    home through foreign trade. These imports, in particular, would allow the profit rate to

    increase without raising prices in all areas of production in the home country, which

    stimulates accumulation and consequently growth, without affecting real wages (Ricardo,

    1973, pp.77-80).

    Ricardos theory of trade is based on the explicit assumption that there is no

    mobility of factors of production between countries, so it cannot be assumed that factor

    prices (or rates) are equal between countries, and consequently trade advantages cannot be

    established on the basis of absolute price comparisons, but rather on the basis of relative

    prices within each country. If free trade between any two countries were established on the

    basis of relative advantages, after an initial process of Humes price-specie flow

    movements, a balanced trade in commodities would eventually be reached, with benefits

    for both countries. Curiously, in his famous two-country, two-commodity example, the

    least productive country would benefit the most. In Ricardos argument, the highest level of

    productivity, which means the lowest prices for both goods, can only be reached through

    economic integration , i.e. , free factor mobility between trading countries (Ricardo, 1973,

    pp.81-83).

    2. The neoclassical free trade theory

    Neoclassical theory followed Smith and Ricardo in advocating free trade, both within and

    between countries, but classical theories were adapted to fit in the marginal analysis

    framework. Within this framework, international or interregional trade is a special case of a

    more general theory of trade: the theory of supply and demand. Foreign trade would be the

    particular case in which there is no mobility of factors of production between regions or

    countries, whatever the cause may be (natural, cultural or political). The crucial effect of

    7

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    8/62

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    9/62

    At the end of the nineteen century, thanks to the works of, among others, Pareto,

    Marshall, Edgeworth and Pigou, 6 neoclassical economics today regarded as mainstream

    economics began to consider the benefits of trade mainly from the point of view of

    welfare .7 Thus, starting from a theoretical situation of a country in autarky and equilibrium,

    the alternative of trade with other countries, either regulated or free trade, is to be evaluated

    by how much welfare is lost and how much welfare is gained. In a classless microeconomic

    analysis of static autarky versus with-trade situations, the only possible winners and losers

    of welfare are consumers, producers and the government. There are usually two types of

    analyses: general equilibrium and partial equilibrium. The closed economy assumptions

    are: variable costs, perfect competition (equilibrium), full employment and full mobility of

    factors between sectors. By further assuming the immobility of factors between countries,

    the with-trade economy results in full employment, balanced trade, equilibrium, expanded

    consumption and partial specialization of production, if there is a relative price change.

    a) General Equilibrium and the benefits of Trade

    The two goods, two factor, small country model, like the one shown in Figure 1, is

    traditionally considered a good approach to illustrate the general equilibrium effects of

    trade. There are two possibilities: autarky and trade.

    Autarkys equilibrium is at the tangency of the production possibilities (or

    transformation) curve between good X and good Y , with the domestic price line p* at Q. The

    meaning of this equilibrium is that the quantities of X and Y ( X p and Y p) produced and

    consumed are the same, supply and demand are satisfied simultaneously, all factors of

    production are being fully utilized, and a community indifference curve is also tangent to

    6 See Arrow & Scitovsky (1969) and Corden (1974).7 All American and European textbooks on international trade deal with trade policy from this viewpoint (seeHeller, 1968; Sdernsten, 1970; Kindleberger, 1973; Markusen et al .,1995; Krugman & Obstfeld, 2005).

    9

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    10/62

    that point, so that producers and consumers are at their best according to the Pareto

    criterion. 8

    Figure 1Open economy General Equilibrium

    Source: Markusen, et al. , 1995, p.55

    Now, if we move from autarky to free trade two possibilities may occur: (1) the

    countrys price ratio will be the same as the trading partners, and these prices are

    represented by the price line p*, or (2) the trading partners price ratio is different from the

    home countrys, so a new price ratio is established between trading partners, and this

    implies a movement along the transformation curve to another production position.

    Case (1) is described in Figure 1 where there is no price line change, but with-trade

    consumption takes place at point C , reaching a higher community indifference curve. In

    other words, all the benefits from free trade go to consumers; thereby social welfare is

    optimized. The same mixed product ( X and Y ) is produced domestically, a part of it is

    domestically consumed (segments 0 X p and 0 Y c), the remaining part of Y (segment Y c

    Y p) is exchanged for the imported part of the X good consumption (segment X p X c). This

    case describes precisely the gains from exchange under free trade conditions. With-trade

    optimization conditions for general equilibrium are defined as:

    8 A situation is efficient or Pareto-optimal if it is impossible to make one person better off except by makingsomeone else worse off (Layard and Walters, 1978, p. 7).

    10

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    11/62

    Producer optimization: MRT = p x* / p y*

    Consumer optimization: MRS = p x* / p y*

    Trade balance: p x( X c X p) + p y*(Y c Y p) = 0

    where: MRT = Marginal Rate of Transformation (in production); MRS = Marginal Rate of

    Substitution (in exchange); p x* = foreign price of good X ; p y* = foreign price of good Y .

    In Figure 2 we have case (2) in which there is a price line change, moving the

    production point from A (autarky production of X and Y ) to Q t with-tax-trade production

    and to Q f , with-free-trade production, points. It shows that the new price line shifts

    production in the direction of partial specialization for the home country in good Y

    production. This clearly favors the expansion of consumption to a higher indifference curve

    tangent to the new price line p* at point C f . By geometry, exports and imports can be

    exchanged at world prices, keeping trade in balance. A tariff imposed on the imported good

    would reduce the level of consumption of both X and Y , although this level would be higher

    than in autarky, as shown in Figure 2, by means of community indifference curves U t and

    U f , for social utility with tariff trade and with free trade, respectively.

    In this case free trade is better than autarky and better than protected trade. It is

    better in the welfare sense that the economy is, with free trade, at a maximum point of

    efficiency , both in production and in consumption. The imposition of an import tariff to one

    of the goods produced, imported and consumed, good X in this model as shown in Figure 2,

    hinders movement further along the transformation curve, that is, from Q t to Q f , so as to get

    more specialized on the greater comparative advantage good. It also prevents attaining the

    highest possible indifference curve at U f . Domestic production of good X is, in this case,

    stimulated by a tariff on its imports.

    11

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    12/62

    Figure 2Transformation Curve and Price Ratios

    Autarky, Protected and Free Trade

    Source: Markusen, et al. , 1995, p. 247.

    By construction, the transformation curve of a two-good, two-factor, general

    equilibrium model, like the one above, assumes full employment of the two factors of

    production along all its points, and since the curve depicts the greatest possible mixed

    production of both goods, any point on it is Pareto-optimal. The movement from autarky to

    free trade is one along the transformation curve, so it does not imply any increase in total

    production but rather a change, from one production line to the other, without getting full

    specialization in either one. It is clear, therefore, that the improvement caused by this

    change affects consumption entirely: a country may consume more of one good or of both,

    by means of trading, than was previously the case under autarky. This is the meaning of

    efficiency : each trading country, through a change in its domestic price ratio, will end up

    producing and exporting the good which it produces best, in exchange for the good it does

    not; full employment of both factors does not change at all. If we assume in this change that

    12

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    13/62

    prices move between trading countries to reflect reciprocal demand conditions, and they

    always match with domestic supply conditions, equilibrium is maintained. Therefore, free

    trade seems to be, in theory, a static all win game, as far as countries involved are

    concerned. 9

    As we see it, there are two ways of measuring efficiency. On the one hand, if the

    question is viewed from the subjective angle, it needs a community indifference curve map

    for estimating consumption optimization after trade. But building up a community

    indifference curve map requires interpersonal comparisons of preferences. This issue has

    been seriously questioned, and is the subject of an endless debate, with no concrete results

    (see Arrow & Scitovsky, 1969, Parts IV and V). On the other hand, gains in efficiency can

    also be viewed as obtaining some goods relatively cheaper with free trade than without it.

    The reason for this is that under free trade, they are either produced more efficiently at

    home, or imported by exchanging them for efficiently produced export goods. Free trade is

    supposed to make home producers in general more competitive by lowering their input

    costs and by breaking up domestic monopolies. Trade policies have, from the point of view

    of efficiency, two simultaneous targets: production and consumption. If we cannot establish

    the best consumption point for all possible levels of efficient production and trade and we

    cant without a social utility function then we cannot be sure that free trade consumption is

    Pareto-optimal. However, as long as the maximum efficiency in production is reached by

    free trade, Pareto optimality is achieved. This has one particular implication: the increase of

    social welfare derived from the increase in total production (the increase in employment,

    the equalization of net social products and the equalization of domestic prices to marginal

    costs) (Kaldor, 1938, p. 551).

    9 Exactly as stated in Smith and Ricardos free trade theories (see infra ).

    13

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    14/62

    On the other hand, as far as welfare is concerned, besides efficiency there is the

    question of equity . This can be viewed from factor income distribution. For this distribution

    to be considered Pareto-optimal, the distribution of income between factors of production

    with free trade must be better, or at least as good as that which existed under autarky. If, in

    the movement from autarky to free trade, one of the factors reduces its real income at the

    expense of the other, then the free trade situation cannot be regarded as Pareto-optimal. In a

    famous 1941 article, Wolfgang Stolper and Paul Samuelson demonstrated in a two-good,

    two-factor model that free trade necessarily harms the relative scarce factors real income

    while favoring the others (Stolper and Samuelson, 1970, p.261). However, the argument is

    qualified by pointing out that the harm inflicted by free trade to one factor is less than the

    gain of the other; that is, the real income of the abundant factor is relatively increased, so

    instead of ceasing trade, it is better to compensate the suffering factor (Stolper and

    Samuelson, 1970, p. 267). 10

    If, in case (2) illustrated in Figure 2, we look at the change in production from A to

    Q f along the transformation curve, we see an increase in the production of Y and a decrease

    in the production of X . If this change occurs due to comparative advantages, it means a

    movement from scarce factor-intensive good X towards the abundant factor-intensive good

    Y . This increased utilization of the relatively abundant, and therefore cheaper, factor of

    production will necessarily make its price go up and, since we are assuming full

    employment and equal factor prices across sectors, real income increases for the abundant

    factor in both lines of production at the expense of the other factor. There is a change in

    income distribution in favor of the pre-trade abundant factor. In the case of many countries

    10 A subsidy for the suffering factor is thereby justified as a compensation for making the owner of thegaining factor better with free trade.

    14

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    15/62

    this factor is expected to be labor, of course. So it may be said that an increase in the real

    wage bill could be expected for a labor abundant country, which opens up to free trade. 11

    The assumption of full employment seems crucial for getting to the point of

    maximum social welfare, whether in autarky or a with-trade situation, for any given

    country. This is so because all possible less than full employment (LFE) production points

    are inside the full employment concave transformation curve in a two-good, two-factor

    model. Of all possible LFE mixed production points, not one is Pareto-optimal by

    definition, and only one of them is the actual point for a country in an LFE situation. In

    short, within the neoclassical analysis, less than full employment is not compatible with

    general equilibrium and Pareto-optimality.

    Free trade in the two-good, two-factor general equilibrium model tends to stimulate

    production and exports of those goods, which are factor-intensive on the relatively

    abundant factor, on the condition that this factor is relatively cheap with respect to the

    other, based on its relative abundance. Now, if we are in some pre-trade equilibrium

    supply and demand balance, which happens to be an LFE position, the after-trade position

    must be on the full employment transformation curve. In other words, efficiency implies

    full employment. Greater efficiency in economics means cheaper goods, either produced at

    home or imported. This, in turn, may stimulate saving and thus investment, in a

    neoclassical equilibrium.

    In summary, free trade generates greater efficiency than autarky: higher productivity

    and lower prices, which translate into more savings and investment, as long as full

    11 This is what was expected in all Latin American countries when they adopted trade liberalization measuresin the eighties and nineties following the Washington Consensus package.

    15

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    16/62

    employment exists. Protected trade seems to be a situation that is somewhere between

    autarky and free trade, so it could be a second best according to Pareto criteria. 12

    An export expansion will clearly be brought about by free trade, but since full

    employment is assumed at the beginning, there can be no increase in overall production in

    real terms, but rather a switch from domestic importable goods production to domestic

    exportable goods production to pay for the increase in imports.

    One important aspect of the market mechanism that is sometimes overlooked in

    international trade and which is needed in order to arrive at Pareto-optimal results is the

    fact that this mechanism implies money prices not relative ones being the signals for the

    decisions of individual optimizing economic agents inside and across countries. The

    original Ricardos theory of comparative advantages, in his two-country two-commodity

    example, required that money prices showed clear advantages for either countrys

    producers and consumers, so that both groups move in the right direction. According to

    Ricardo, the most efficient country beginning with lower prices is paid for its exports with

    money. The net inflow of money makes its prices to go up until one of the two absolute

    advantages disappears. Simultaneously, the net outflow of money in the least efficient

    country makes its prices go down until one of them is relatively lower so as to make the

    good attractive for import from abroad. It is the money flow, which does a sort of

    transformation from absolute into relative advantages (Shaikh, 1980, p. 205). In

    neoclassical economics this same effect may be obtained by free exchange rate movements,

    to the point of trade balance (Ohlin, 1933; Friedman, 1973).

    12 The second best policy works when the first best is politically or institutionally impossible (seeKindleberger, 1973, p.200).

    16

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    17/62

    This, however, is different from the relative price change in the home country that

    necessarily occurs when it opens up to trade. This change favors exports rather than

    imports; that is, export prices should go up relative to import prices in money terms as

    measured in the currency in which international transactions take place. This change is

    expected from an increased total demand of exportable products (domestic plus foreign

    demand) and an increased total supply of importables.

    b) Partial Equilibrium, Free trade and Tariffs

    In partial equilibrium (one good market), free trade means to directly compare domestic

    prices to foreign prices in the same currency, thus it turns a country into either a net

    exporter or a net importer of that good, according to whether its home price is lower or

    higher than the foreign price for that particular good. In the case of a net importers

    domestic market, foreign producers may eliminate domestic producers from their own

    domestic market with lower prices. But even if they compete, home production is limited

    according to how domestic demand responds to a price reduction caused by the opening of

    that market to foreign competition.

    The microeconomic theory of demand was created with specific assumptions

    regarding consumers behavior in mind, so that the quantity demanded of a particular

    homogeneous good in the market is a well behaved decreasing function of its money price,

    that is, the demand curve . Any point along this curve is a consumers maximizing point.

    Similarly, the supply curve that was built on, among other assumptions, the law of

    diminishing factor returns, represents an increasing function of the supplied quantity of a

    particular homogeneous good with respect to its money price; any point along this supply

    curve represents for producers a profit maximizing (or cost minimizing) point. Given that

    quantities and prices of supply and demand refer to same market at the same moment in

    17

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    18/62

    time it is, therefore, possible to find a point of intersection that simultaneously satisfies

    consumers and producers, yielding maxima benefits for both groups. Still, there is a

    consumer surplus in terms of welfare, for those consumers originally willing to pay a

    higher price but who instead receive a lower one.

    Figure 3Welfare Surplus Before and After Trade

    In Figure 3 welfare consumer surplus is illustrated, assuming pre-trade equilibrium

    price P * and quantity Q *. Consumer surplus is defined as the total value to consumers of

    their consumption of a good minus the amount they have to pay for it; this is the shadowed

    area below the demand line, above the price line P * in diagram (b). If trade opening drives

    the price down to P, consumer welfare surplus is increased by areas R and T in diagram

    (c). A part of this welfare gain for consumers is taken from local producers, so the net

    welfare gain is the area T. This gain is due to the increase in total quantity supplied from Q *

    to Q and the reduction of prices from P* to P. In the case of a net importer country for a

    particular good, consumer welfare surplus increases and producer welfare surplus decreases

    in the domestic market, still there is a net welfare gain for local consumers.

    18

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    19/62

    Figure 4Welfare Producer Surplus

    Before and After Trade.

    P

    P*

    Q* Q

    S

    (a)

    P

    P*

    Q* Q

    S

    (b)

    P

    P*

    Q* Q

    S

    (c)

    R T

    Q**

    P**

    In Figure 4 welfare producer surplus is illustrated. It is defined as the surplus in

    revenue for those producers able to supply various quantities at prices lower than the

    market equilibrium price. This is the total revenue received minus the cost of production.

    This surplus is represented by the shadowed area above the supply line and below the

    equilibrium price line in diagram (b). When trade opens up and it raises the price from P * to

    P P**, welfare producer surplus is increased by areas R and T in diagram (c) as total supply

    increases from Q * to Q **. In short, for net exporting countries, welfare increases for

    producers and is reduced for consumers in the domestic market of the good it exports.

    There is a net gain for producers.

    From the diagrams in Figures 3 and 4 it is clear that a change from autarky to free

    trade produces welfare surplus gains to consumers by way of import expansion at lower

    prices and to producers by the way of export expansion at higher prices. In the first case,

    diagram (c) of Figure 3, the supply curve S moves along the demand curve D as it is

    increased by new (foreign) producers entering the domestic market. In the second case it is

    19

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    20/62

    the demand curve D that moves along the supply curve S, indicating the increase in

    (foreign) consumers.

    If, for any reason, a tariff is imposed on goods that are either i) imported by the

    home country, or ii) exported by the home country, welfare gains are reduced, as though

    there had been a shift back to autarky. However, these welfare surpluses are not entirely

    lost, but redistributed in favor of local producers and the government in the first case, and

    foreign producers and the foreign government in the second one.

    Figure 5 illustrates the general case of an import tax on a particular good market.

    Lines S and D represent domestic supply and domestic demand, respectively of good X .

    p* X is the free trade price, domestic production of good X is initially the segment 0 Q 1 ,

    and imports are represented by the segment Q 1 Q 2 ; the value of total consumption is the

    rectangle 0, p* X , B, Q 2 . The consumer surplus for good X under free trade is the area p* X

    B; correspondingly, the producer surplus is the area p* X A. If the home country imposes a

    tariff on X imports, this raises the price of X for domestic consumers from p* X to p X ,

    reduces total consumption from point B to point D, and imports are then limited to the

    segment Q 3 Q 4 , and domestic production is increased from Q 1 to Q 3 .

    The new consumer welfare surplus is reduced to the area p X D . Part of the surplus

    is transferred to local producers and the rest is transferred to the government in the form of

    taxes. There has been a transfer of welfare surplus between the local economic agents

    consumers, producers and the government with no profits or losses for the economy.

    If we start from a situation where trade is protected and tariffs are removed as a

    result of a new liberal trade policy, the graph in Figure 5 illustrates the same movements

    as before but in a reverse direction. Now the supply curve moves to the right because there

    is an increase of suppliers (local plus foreign), while the demand curve remains the same.

    20

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    21/62

    This will imply a new equilibrium point at a greater quantity Q 2 , and at a lower price per

    unit, p* X .

    Figure 5Import Tax Effects in Partial Equilibrium

    Source: Markusen, et al ., 1995, p.283.

    It also implies ipso facto a gain in welfare surpluses for consumers and a loss of

    welfare surpluses for local producers and the government. 13 One might assume that local

    producers are also consumers not only of the same goods they produce, but are also

    consumers of inputs for production, so that if there is a general removal of tariffs, local

    producers are indirectly benefited as consumers.

    The problem remains of how much losses and how much profits result from a free

    trade situation after opening up the market for foreign competition, i.e. a tariff eliminationin that market, and this depends on the elasticity of the local demand curve for goods.

    13 This means the displacement of local workers by foreign ones, not in terms of welfare but in terms of production, In other words, it means a drop in employment in all net importing local industries.

    21

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    22/62

    In the case of home country exports, there is a welfare surplus for producers as seen

    in Figure 4, when tariffs are lifted, or the foreign market opens up to free trade. The extent

    of this gain depends on the price elasticity of export supply.

    This problem is similar to that of measuring the effects of an exchange rates

    depreciation, on the trade balance, through the change in prices of imports and of exports. 14

    Since we do not know a priori the absolute values of price-elasticities of the demand for

    imports and the supply of exports, there is no basis for assuming that a free trade situation

    is, on average, better or worse than a protection situation.

    The other complication for evaluating the possible benefits of free trade as opposed

    to protectionism is related to the fact that export and import prices move not only in

    response to tariffs, whether imposed or lifted, but assuming no technical change, they vary

    directly with exchange rate movements, affecting ipso facto supply or demand curves,

    depending upon the currency used to measure exports or imports.

    For instance, if tariffs are lifted in all sectors of the home country economy, we

    expect that prices of imported goods to go down in local currency for local consumers as in

    the diagrams above, but if we assume a flexible exchange rate market and the exchange rate

    goes up because more foreign exchange is demanded to pay for the additional imports, the

    price per unit of every particular imported good will go up in local currency by the

    percentage of the depreciation, since local producers have costs that are already higher than

    foreign producers and are affected by depreciation, depending on the quantity of imported

    inputs they have in their respective production line. In the end, depreciation turns out to be

    a measure that only protects exporters, by transferring welfare benefits from local import

    substituters to exporters. However, it is of course possible that the increase in exports

    14 Formalized as the Marshall-Lerner-Robinson Condition (see Kindleberger, 1973, p. 328-9).

    22

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    23/62

    offsets this exchange rate rising tendency, if there is reciprocity in tariff reductions in the

    trading partner country.

    From the point of view of partial equilibrium, a free trade policy may, caeteris

    paribus , guarantee a welfare net gain for home country consumers of imported goods, but

    only for some , and they are those local consumers willing to pay a higher price and who

    receive a lower one in the exchange. Who are these local consumers? In the case of

    developing countries it seems they are not low-income consumers, given the

    characteristically uneven income distribution. The opportunity cost of this welfare gain is a

    welfare loss for local producers and for the government. In the case of local producers it

    means the shutdown of plants and the firing of workers. It is assumed, however, that new

    plants and jobs will be created in the exporting sectors as exports grow, and also in other

    sectors by the expanded local inputs demanded from exporting sectors. The real net gain is

    obtained only if, on average, employment increases are higher than job losses, and

    aggregate demand grows faster than imports, under the new conditions produced by free

    trade.

    In partial or general equilibrium analysis one might expect that, based on

    neoclassical orthodox theory, free trade will bring about greater efficiency in domestic

    production and lower prices for domestic consumption, but economic growth is not

    necessarily considered, and if there is full employment from the outset, there wont be any

    growth except for that created by increased productivity.

    In other words, the theory is not wrong, but stubborn reality is not adequate for the

    free trade theory implications. One other way to address this problem is to assess the

    assumption that free trade will permit the optimization of production and consumption, and

    ultimately of social welfare, if not investment and growth as well, for all trading parties. In

    23

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    24/62

    that respect, it seems that certain basic assumptions make it difficult for this theory to

    produce the expected results if they are simply not fulfilled. In a famous article regarding

    assumptions and theory, Friedman argued that it is not whether assumptions are realistic or

    unrealistic which make associated theory correct but whether its predictions are proven

    right. This is based on the idea that it is not important if economic agents follow rational

    behavior in their individual economic decisions, but rather if the overall results were as if

    these individuals had acted rationally (Friedman, 1953). If we apply this principle to free

    trade theory, we should expect welfare improvements in production and consumption, in

    both efficiency and equity, in any country engaged in free trade, regardless of whether this

    country fulfills the necessary assumptions established by the theory.

    3. New theories of trade and free trade

    As mentioned above, the Comparative Costs theory based on the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem

    has prevailed as the neoclassical theory of international trade, despite all criticisms since

    the theorems publication in 1933. However, during the last fifty years, there have been

    some departures from the traditional assumptions of neoclassical trade theory that have led

    to particular theories of trade which, together, are known as the New Theories of

    International Trade (Krugman, 1983).

    The full employment assumption has been challenged by the vent-for-surplus

    approach, which deals with the question of unused resources and trade patterns in

    underdeveloped countries (Myint, 1958). Three other necessary assumptions of perfect

    competition an essential part of the neoclassical trade theory have also been questioned:

    the equal availability of technology across countries, the existence of identical production

    functions with constant returns to scale, and the homogeneity of products. These criticisms

    gave rise to new theories, which considered the following: technology gaps (Posner, 1961;

    24

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    25/62

    Dosi et al. , 1990), the product cycle (Vernon, 1966) and increasing returns to scale

    (Krugman, 1979).

    The main implications of the comparative costs principle and the Heckscher-Ohlin

    theorem have also been questioned. One criticism is related to the trade pattern

    determination by relative factor proportions, and there are two critical aspects: the non-

    coincidence of the expected factor intensities ranking, with export and import ranking

    (Deardoff, 1979) and the absolute availability of resources as the determinant of trade

    patterns (Kravis, 1956). There is another that is related to the expected intra-industry trade

    as a result of specialization based on the Heckscher-Ohlin model, which contrasts the actual

    growing importance of intra-industry trade (Dixit and Norman, 1980; Caves, 1981;

    Krugman, 1981). However, most of these new theories have been made to fit the

    orthodox theory by using the appropriate model (Gandolfo, 1987, I Ch.8).

    In his early writings, Keynes was supportive of free trade on the grounds that

    comparative advantage would lead to optimal specialization, but by 1930 he had changed

    his views and considered the free trade doctrine no longer valid in the case of a high

    unemployment economy (Milberg, 2002). Like some other experts, Keynes was critical of

    the neoclassical assumption of full employment, which is basic to neoclassical comparative

    costs theory. The importance of the criticism of this theory is that, Under conditions of

    persistent unemployment the theory of comparative advantage is irrelevant because the

    mechanism which would otherwise transform a situation of differential comparative costs

    into one of differences in absolute money costs and prices no longer operates (Milberg,

    2002, p. 241).

    Raul Prebisch (1959), and other structuralists , questioned the neoclassical trade

    theory on its implications for a free trade policy, in the case of underdeveloped countries.

    25

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    26/62

    Besides criticizing the full employment assumption, which does not apply in most

    underdeveloped countries, Prebisch also tried to prove that free trade was not optimal in

    these countries.

    Prebisch begins by observing that underdeveloped countries produce and export

    mainly commodities and import manufactured goods. Comparative costs and free trade

    would confine these countries to this specialization and trade pattern. This situation has two

    important implications for employment and growth. In the first place, technical progress,

    recommended for increasing productivity in export activities, is a way to hasten economic

    growth. Prebisch argues that if technical progress takes place in primary activities for

    export and domestic consumption, but industry is not sufficiently developed to absorb the

    redundant work force, the result will be increased unemployment. He instead favors

    simultaneous industrialization and technical progress. The problem is then that the

    comparative costs principle rules out the production of manufactured goods in these

    countries. For Prebisch the usual neoclassical argument does not apply. Instead he argues,

    It is not really a question of comparing industrial costs with import prices but of

    comparing the increase in income obtained in the expansion of industry with that which

    could have been obtained in export activities, had the same productive resources been

    employed there (Prebisch, 1959, p.253).

    Prebisch also observed that there is a tendency for underdeveloped countries terms

    of trade to decline. He argued that this is caused by the type of products these countries

    export and the type of products they import. Primary products are said to have a declining

    income-elasticity of demand (inferior goods) while manufactured goods have rising income

    elasticity (superior goods). Therefore, as income increases, the demand for commodities

    does not rise as fast as the demand for manufactured goods. For those countries that highly

    26

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    27/62

    depend on imports for carrying out production and who export primary goods, this means a

    major constraint for economic growth. Therefore, these countries are left with two

    alternatives for their economies: to grow, running a trade deficit and thus a rising foreign

    debt, or to maintain a foreign trade balance but a stagnant economy. This situation is

    defined as the external restriction for growth. These two implications constituted

    Prebischs arguments for justifying the establishment of protectionism and import

    substitution policies in underdeveloped countries, to pursue both industrialization and

    growth.

    Joan Robinson (1973) criticized two of the main assumptions of the neoclassical

    theory of trade: full employment and perfect competition, with their implied assumptions of

    identical production functions across countries. Robinson concludes that the assumptions of

    the neoclassical theory of trade exclude the discussion of any current trade issues,

    especially those regarding free trade and investment in underdeveloped countries

    (Robinson, 1973, p.221).

    The history of international trade in capitalist economies and their trade policies

    shows that no country in the world has committed itself to free trade on a permanent basis.

    Instead, a wide variety of protectionist policies have been followed by todays developed

    countries like the US and European countries for many years as strategies for growth and

    development (Chang, 2002).

    In modern times the rationale for the second best policies as they have been

    called has been that theories on full employment, perfect competition within and among

    countries, fully developed sectors, and availability of resources, among others, simply do

    not apply to existing economies. On the contrary, market distortions like unbreakable

    oligopolies, income distribution disparities, factor prices not reflecting factor scarcities, and

    27

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    28/62

    gaps in technology prevail. (Corden, 1974), and it looks as though they will not disappear

    because of freer trade. In other cases, the theoretical first best policy is politically or

    institutionally impossible to apply (Kindleberger, 1973).

    More recently, the existence and prevalence of increasing returns to scale for firms

    and industries and of imperfect competition among firms and across countries has been

    stressed in discussions of modern global trade, as opposed to perfect competition and

    constant returns to scale. This calls for state intervention through establishing trade

    strategies for growth and development (Krugman, 1987).

    Nonetheless, in the eighties the World Bank, IMF officials and other policy advisers

    for Latin America recommended the implementation of trade liberalization policies in

    underdeveloped countries, hoping that freer trade would produce structural changes, such

    as a switch in production from inefficient sectors to productive ones; that is, where relative

    advantages are higher for the home country. These policies are synthesized in the

    Washington Consensus package which includes privatization of state owned firms and

    deregulation of economic processes in order to reduce costs for private firms and stimulate

    competition (see Moreno-Brid et al. , 2004-5). But developing countries in Latin America

    are still far away from fulfilling the necessary conditions for benefiting from free trade, like

    full employment and equilibrium. There are also great differences between developed and

    underdeveloped countries, like technology gaps, infant industries, a lack of strategic

    resources, etc. All of the aforementioned account for real asymmetries between developed

    and underdeveloped trading partners, which cannot be dealt with without the use of trade

    and industrial policy measures.

    28

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    29/62

    4. Export-led growth strategies

    To see how foreign trade though not necessarily free trade produces growth and

    increases employment, we have to use the Keynesian argument that in a model that takes

    into account price stability and fiscal and external equilibrium, a dynamic factor that does

    not create imbalance is foreign demand (export demand) (see Cornwall, 1977, ch.7;

    Davidson, 1997). The increase in exports has a direct effect on the level of production and

    employment, and it also expands the demand for intermediate goods and thereby causes an

    indirect increase in employment. On the other hand, the foreign exchange inflows generated

    by increased exports allows imports to increase by that same amount, without creating a

    deficit. There exists, at least in theory, a virtuous circle in export-led growth (Cornwall,

    1977, p.165). This kind of growth is supposed to increase productivity and, therefore,

    competitiveness, which again reinforces the export trend. It is important to note that an

    export led growth strategy is always based on manufacturing exports, because demand in

    this sector is highly elastic with respect to income and prices in the global market. 15

    Recent historical evidence shows that export-led growth strategies have been very

    successful in some Asian countries; however, none of these countries adopted full

    liberalization policies simultaneously as a strategy to promote exports. On the contrary, the

    East Asian experience shows that successful export-promoting policies have been regularly

    accompanied by import controls and rigid regulations of the movement of capital (Sachs,

    1988, p.78). And in South Korea and Taiwan, they were preceded by assorted industrial

    policies (Rodrik, 1995). It has been argued that the outward orientation of growth in these

    countries occurred as a consequence of an investment boom and not the other way around

    15 This argument is coincidental with Prebisch (1959) who argued in favor of protectionist policies forindustrialization in underdeveloped countries.

    29

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    30/62

    (Rodrik, 1995). The success of export-led growth strategies was clearly based not on free

    trade but on regulated trade and industrial policies.

    II. FREE TRADE VERSUS PROTECTION . SOME EXAMPLES FROM THE MEXICAN ECONOMY

    1. The Mexican liberal strategy

    In the early eighties, some experts in Mexico thought that manufacturing exports would

    become the engine for growth in the rest of the economy, especially for increasing

    employment. This, however, required changes in foreign exchange and foreign trade

    policies that were in line with the aforementioned mainstream neo-liberal theories (see

    Levy, 1981; Clavijo and Valdivieso, 1983). One of the main reasons for justifying the

    abandonment of protectionism was that it was producing a bias against exports (Lustig,

    1992).

    Trade policy was changed so that exporters could import low cost, high quality

    intermediate goods (inputs), in order to use the relatively cheap local labor to produce

    manufacturing goods for export at a competitive level. However, such a strategy required

    investment from abroad, and there were still obstacles to this at the end of the eighties.

    The wage differential between Mexico and the US in manufacturing, along with

    their geographical proximity, has always been an attraction for foreign firms. Nonetheless,

    foreign investment was strongly limited and regulated, up to the eighties; and this is why it

    did not represent an important share of total installed investment in Mexico.

    Therefore, the opening process could not be completed until the late eighties or the

    early nineties, when financial opening took place in Mexico, aided by a boom in capital

    investment in emerging markets around the world. In effect, the liberalization of finance

    and investment in Mexico completed the process of trade liberalization and stimulated

    export-oriented manufacturing production.

    30

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    31/62

    However, at the end of the eighties unilateral free trade was not producing the

    desired results. The clear failure of the neo-liberal economic policies led to a nationwide

    public distrust in those policies by 1988. Thus, once the ruling party managed to win the

    presidential election, thereby holding onto political power, it was a declared goal of the new

    administration to deepen liberal reforms and to politically lock up the process through a

    free trade agreement with the US. It took the form of a preferential trade agreement

    including Canada which was signed in 1993 and which took effect in 1994. It was, of

    course, the North American Free Trade Agreement, NAFTA.

    Thus, in the last 35 years Mexico has experienced three different trade policies in

    three subsequent periods: protected trade (1970-1981), unilateral free trade (1982-1993)

    and preferential trade (NAFTA) (1994-2005). The results have also been different. Observe

    the economic performance of the Mexican economy through selected economic indicators

    in Table 1.

    Table 1Selected Economic Indicators

    Average annual rates of growth in per centIndicator 1970-1981 1982-1993 1994-2005

    GDP in constant pesos 6.9 1.6 2.9Population 2.6 2.6 1.4Per capita GDP 4.1 -0.9 1.5Total Exports (US$) 29.1 4.1 9.8

    Oil Exports 103.5 -1.5 15.8Manufacturing non maq. 19.8 17.0 13.0Maquiladoras 27.2 18.2 13.6

    Gross Fixed Investment 9.3 0.2 4.6Paid Employment 4.8 1.3 1.5Consumer Prices* 196.0 710.8 163.6Terms of Trade (US$)* 28.3 -64.1 20.4Real Exchange Rate Index* 30.3 5.3 1.6Exchange Rate (Mex/US)* 78.3 696.7 155.1*Acumulated variation in the periodSources: Instituto Nacional de Estadstica Geografa e InformticaINEGI and Banco de Mxico, S. A., Mxico.

    31

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    32/62

    Looking at Table 1, it is clear that the protected trade period (1970-81), according to

    all of these indicators, was much better than the unilateral free trade period (1982-93). All

    that was expected from trade liberalization in terms of export boom, investment, growth,

    inflation reduction, and an improvement in the terms of trade, simply did not occur. The

    neo-liberal policy package applied thus far clearly failed. In contrast, economic

    performance improved during the NAFTA period. In some specific sectors, the effects of

    the change from unilateral free trade to preferential trade were rather dramatic: the

    manufacturing and maquiladora export boom (especially in the first half of the last period),

    the reduction in the inflation rate and, consequently, in the currency depreciation rate, and

    the improvement in the terms of trade. Nevertheless, the GDP growth rate, especially per

    capita GDP, during the NAFTA period is lower than in the first period, and also compared

    to what would be the growth rate needed to absorb the growing work force. Some of the

    exports boom in the second half of the last period was due to oil exports, which have

    benefited from increases in global prices. Employment also increased more in the protected

    trade period than in the free trade period and the NAFTA period.

    2. Exports and Growth

    Figure 6 shows the trend of GDP growth rates in real terms and manufacturing exports

    including maquiladoras in current US Dollars for the whole period 1970-2005. It is

    striking to observe that there seems to be no correlation between these two variables,

    during the late seventies, the eighties and part of the nineties. In fact, if we consider the

    1982 to 1997 period, there is even a negative correlation. For example, whenever there is a

    low or negative GDP growth rate, the growth rate in manufacturing exports is positive and

    high. This can be explained by the fact that reductions in GDP growth were brought about

    to a large extent by the adjustment programs put into effect by the government in 1982-83,

    32

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    33/62

    33

    1986 and 1995, which included government spending cuts, currency depreciations,

    domestic credit restrictions and real wage reductions. All of this affected domestic

    consumption and investment but not manufacturing exports. This negative relationship

    between exports and output can also be explained by the fact that, until the early 1990s,

    most production was oriented towards the domestic market; only residual production was

    exported, with the exception of oil and maquiladora products. This situation changed in the

    NAFTA period during which, with the exception of 1995, export and output growth began

    to correlate.

    The increase in exports in the first half of the last period is, undoubtedly, the result

    of an increasing US demand for imports, and also of the increased access to the US market

    as a result of NAFTA. An important factor in the liberalization process was that, since

    1992, the Mexican economy opened up its capital account, so that foreign investment of all

    types, as well as Mexican capital flights, started to flow in and out of the country without

    regulation. Some of the foreign direct investment probably matured around 1994 and some

    plants started to operate, both export oriented and assembly plants ( maquiladoras ).

    Table 2Mexican Export Structure

    Percentages1970 1981 1993 2005

    Total (FOB) 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0Oil products 2.5 62.5 4.8 14.9Manufacturing 33.0 14.4 37.1 36.4

    Maquiladoras 17.6 13.8 42.1 45.3Other Primary 46.9 9.3 6.0 3.4

    Sources: Instituto Nacional de Estadstica, Geografa e Informtica, INEGIand Banco de Mxico, S. A., Mxico.

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    34/62

    Figure 6GDP and Manufacturing Exports 71-05

    Annual Rates of Growth

    -7.0

    -5.0

    -3.0

    -1.0

    1.0

    3.0

    5.0

    7.0

    9.0

    1 9 7 1

    1 9 7 3

    1 9 7 5

    1 9 7 7

    1 9 7 9

    1 9 8 1

    1 9 8 3

    1 9 8 5

    1 9 8 7

    1 9 8 9

    1 9 9 1

    1 9 9 3

    1 9 9 5

    1 9 9 7

    1 9 9 9

    Real GDP Manufacturing Exports

    34

    Source: Own elaboration with data from INEGI and Banco de Mxico, S.A.

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    35/62

    The data in Table 2 indicate that the composition of exports has changed

    dramatically. The Mexican economy switched from commodities and oil exporting in the

    seventies to manufacture exports in the nineties. In other words, one of the aims of free

    trade policies seems to have been accomplished: structural change.

    Table 3Mexicos Structure of Final Supply and Demand

    in Mexican PesosPercentages

    1970 1981 1993 2005Aggregate Supply 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0

    GDP 91.2 87.7 83.9 70.4Imports 8.8 12.3 16.1 29.6

    Aggregate Demand 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0

    Consumption 72.2 65.2 69.6 58.0-Private 90.8 86.3 86.7 89.3-Government 9.2 13.7 13.3 10.7

    Gross Fixed Investment 18.2 23.2 15.6 14.6Change of Inventories 2.5 2.0 2.0 0.3Exports 7.1 9.6 12.8 27.1

    Sources: Instituto Nacional de Estadstica Geografa e Informtica INEGI, andBanco de Mxico, S. A.

    In Table 3, the structure of aggregate demand shows that the export boom occurred

    in the NAFTA period, in which the exports of goods and services represented 27 per cent of

    total demand, more than two times greater than its share in 1993, the final year of the

    unilateral free trade period. In contrast, consumption and investment have been declining

    their respective shares of total demand. The cost paid for the export increases during the

    free trade and NAFTA periods was the sharp increase of imports in those periods as per

    centages of aggregate supply greater than the export share of demand while Gross

    Domestic Product represented a lower percentage of total final supply. To summarize, a

    structural change in foreign trade in Mexico was the main and only real achievement of the

    free trade policy; other positive results have come from the preferential trade policy,

    NAFTA.

    35

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    36/62

    Figure 7Growth Rate and Trade Balance

    Source: Own elaboration with data from INEGI and Banco de Mxico, S.A.

    Figure 7 illustrates how trade liberalization policies and the integration process via

    NAFTA did not place Mexico on a path to real export-led growth. It shows that the

    relationship between trade performance and economic growth has been deteriorating.

    Between 1970 and 1981, Mexicos real GDP expanded at an annual average rate of 6.9 per

    cent and registered a trade deficit of 2.4 per cent of GDP. The international debt crisis and

    the collapse of the oil boom resulted in an economic slowdown starting in 1982 and was

    worsened by free trade policies; the average growth rate was 1.6 per cent in the period of

    1982-1993, accompanied by a trade surplus of 2.1 per cent of GDP. In the NAFTA period

    1994-2005 real GDP expanded at a 2.9 per cent annual average rate and registered a trade

    deficit of minus 1 per cent of GDP. Therefore, with relatively greater amounts of foreignresources as a proportion of GDP like it received in the seventies, the Mexican economy

    was now able to grow, on average, at less than a half of the annual rates it experienced

    between 1970 and 1981.

    36

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    37/62

    2. Exports and Employment

    The unemployment problem has undoubtedly been the most acute in the Mexican economy

    for many years. Migration flows of Mexicans to the US, due to the lack of jobs in Mexico,

    are by no means a new problem. During the NAFTA period these flows not only did not

    stop but actually increased, despite the relatively high growth rate of the Mexican economy

    from 1995 to 2000 (Cornelius, 2002).

    The economically active population (EAP) in Mexico represents little more than

    half of the population over12 years old and has been growing at a rate of 3.5 per cent a

    year. 16 The average number of new jobs demanded each year in the last 15 years is about

    one million. The Mexican economy has not been able to generate this number in any given

    year in this period. Hence, there is a cumulative job deficit, which is difficult to assess

    accurately. 17

    Although the lack of jobs before this 15 year period was not any better, the problem

    now is the higher amount of new labor people are looking for, and which they are not

    finding which causes all sorts of social problems in Mexico as well as in the US, regarding

    illegal migrant workers. Today the remittances of US dollars from Mexican workers (legal

    and illegal) to their families in Mexico represent the second highest source of revenues in

    the current account of Mexicos balance of payments.

    For these reasons, job creation has been a priority in the economic policy agenda of

    many administrations in the Mexican government. Thus, the main idea for opening up the

    16 In 1990 the figure of estimated EPA was about 24 million people and the number of new jobs required tokeep these people occupied was then about 900 thousand per year. In 2000 the EPA was around 34 million

    people, so the number of new jobs needed per year was about one million 200 thousand (data from Censos Nacionales de Poblacin y Vivienda , INEGI, Mxico).17 The data reported by official national surveys to the government agencies, includes the underemployed asemployed people, therefore, it is useless as an indicator of the real job deficit.

    37

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    38/62

    economy was promoting exports and thereby creating jobs in the supposed comparative

    advantage in labor-intensive sectors.

    This process, however, implied an adjustment in the labor market. Despite the

    neoclassical presumption that any job adjustment is automatic and smooth, it is widely

    recognized that, in practice, a trade opening causes short-term unemployment (Cox and

    Edwards, 1997, pp.8-9). Still, it is expected that, if free trade prevails in the medium and

    long terms, comparative advantages appear, and in the case of countries with relatively

    abundant labor like Mexico, employment will rise in labor-intensive industries and so

    growth may be based on trade expansion and comparative advantages (Dowrick, 1997).

    Thus far, the structural change in exports has not corresponded to change in the

    total employment structure: while primary activities have declined, manufacturing has not

    changed, and the only activities that have significantly increased their shares in total

    employment have been construction and trading (mostly linked to domestic activities).

    Table 4Structure of Paid Labor by Sector in Mexico

    PercentagesSector 1970-1981 1982-1993 1994-2004Agriculture, forestry, and fishing 31.9 27.0 21.9Mining and oil extraction 1.2 1.0 0.4Manufacturing 13.5 12.5 12.4Construction 8.0 9.7 12.2Electric, gas, and sanitary services 0.3 0.5 0.6Trade, hotels and restaurants 15.5 16.8 19.7Transportation and communications 4.2 5.4 6.2Financing, insurance and rentals 1.9 2.2 2.1Personal and social services 23.5 24.9 24.5Total 100.0 100.0 100.0Source: Sistema de Cuentas Nacionales , Instituto Nacional de Estadstica,Geografa e Informtica, INEGI, Mxico.

    With the aim of measuring the specific effects of dynamic export activity on

    domestic employment, we used an input-output model, which includes the technical

    38

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    39/62

    coefficients matrix, the direct employment vector, and the final demand vector (in this case,

    of exports). The basic idea was to measure the impact of final demand on gross output,

    estimate employment coefficients by industry and, using the estimated gross output,

    calculate the employment generated by the level of gross output that is required by the

    actual level of exports. Based on this method we obtained the gross output required to

    produce the actual level of exports each year, and we could calculate the level of

    employment in each industry corresponding to the level of gross output for the period of

    1978-2000 18 (see Appendix 1). As a result of applying this model, we obtained the level of

    employment associated with the gross output required to produce the actual level of exports

    each year for said period.

    The results shown in Figure 8 and Table 5 indicate that while total employment had

    been growing at an average annual rate of 2.6 per cent during the whole period, in the free

    trade and NAFTA periods, the level of employment associated with total exports has

    increased at higher rates, so that the percentage of employment generated by exports had a

    spike in 1995 and reached its highest level (15.4 per cent of the total) in 2000. Most of this

    employment is domestic production associated with exports (11.2 per cent) while the

    Maquiladora industry represents 4.2 per cent of total.

    18 We have an unwanted restriction in the availability of data for other years, especially regarding input-outputtables of the Mexican economy, which are available only for the years 1980, 1985, 1990, 1993 and 1996, andare all projections of the 1980 matrix.

    39

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    40/62

    Figure 8Total Employment and Relative Shares of Employment Generated by Exports and Maquiladoras

    0.0

    5.0

    10.0

    15.0

    20.0

    25.0

    30.0

    1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

    M i l l i o n s o f

    W o r

    k e r s

    0.0

    2.5

    5.0

    7.5

    10.0

    12.5

    15.0

    17.5

    20.0

    22.5

    25.0

    27.5

    30.0

    P e r c e n

    t a g e o f

    T o t a l

    Total Employment Generated by Exports Employment in Maquiladoras Source: Own elaboration with data from the input-output model of Appendix 1

    Table 5Mexico: Estimated Employment Structure

    Domestic Market and Exports1980 1993 2000

    Total, thousands of workers 21,356 26,040 30,613Percent structure

    Total Employment 100.0 100.0 100.0Domestic Market 95.5 91.1 84.6Exports with Maquiladoras 4.5 8.9 15.4Exports w/o Maquiladoras 4.0 6.9 11.2- Direct 2.2 3.9 5.9- Indirect 1.8 3.0 5.3

    Maquiladoras 0.6 2.1 4.2

    Source: Own elaboration based on data from Sistema de Cuentas Nacionales , INEGI, and Stata Matrix , Mxico.

    The relative share of export employment tripled from 1980 to 2000, which is by no

    means a minor achievement. However, considering that total employment has not increased

    40

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    41/62

    to a significant extent and also that in 1995, when export employment grew, the total level

    of employment diminished due to that years crisis, one can infer that export activities have

    attracted jobs from domestic market activities, especially from those which were displaced

    by imports.

    Surprisingly enough, the ratio of jobs indirectly generated by exports to export

    direct jobs a little less than one in the three periods shows that the multiplying effects of

    exports on employment remains roughly the same regardless of the rupture of domestic

    industry linkages caused by trade liberalization in the eighties. 19

    In order to see how much of this multiplying effect had actually been lost, we

    estimated the level of gross output required for exports in the 1994-2000 period (the first

    half of NAFTA) and the corresponding employment associated (directly and indirectly)

    with exports with two matrices (from 1980 and 1993), and compared the obtained results.

    The differences between the two estimates for gross output and employment generated by

    exports are all positive and favorable for the 1980 matrix. It means that, if the economic

    structure in the eighties had remained the same in the nineties, the level of employment and

    gross output associated with exports would have been higher.

    Table 6Differences of Export gross output andemployment as estimated with 1980 matrix,

    from values estimated with 1993 matrix,Year Gross Output Employment1994 6.14 2.071995 8.47 3.031996 8.52 3.461997 8.73 3.681998 10.24 4.261999 5.63 3.652000 5.62 3.69

    Source: Own elaboration with data fromINEGI, and CIESA.

    19 This is an important issue that has been widely debated (see Ruiz-Npoles, 2001 and 2004).

    41

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    42/62

    3. Exports and Imports

    Mexicos foreign trade (both exports and imports) increased notably since the trade opening

    in the eighties, but it did not diversify, as is shown in Table 7. Most exports and imports are

    concentrated in the North American market, that is, the US and Canada, even before

    NAFTA.

    From the initial period in 1970-1981, exports and imports tripled in the free trade

    period 1982-1993 and increased five times for the period 1994-2005. The trade balance

    improved in the free trade period when there was a cumulative trade surplus of eight billion

    dollars, while it deteriorated for the NAFTA period, turning into a deficit of 65 billion

    dollars.

    The actual trend of the trade balance from the period of 1970-2005 is shown in

    Figure 9. It must be observed that while there was a growing trade surplus with the North

    American market as a whole, there was a growing deficit with the rest of the world in the

    NAFTA period.

    Table 7Trade Balance of Mexico

    Millions of US Dollars1970-1981 1982-1993 1994-2005

    Total Exports 90,138.4 100.0 315,999.2 100.0 1,653,178.6 100.0 North America 54,518.5 60.5 233,417.3 73.9 1,472,096.5 89.0 Rest of the World 35,619.9 39.5 82,581.9 26.1 181,082.1 11.0Total Imports 114,293.0 100.0 307,963.1 100.0 1,718,581.6 100.0 North America 74,007.0 64.8 219,041.4 71.1 1,184,427.6 68.9 Rest of the World 40,286.1 35.2 88,921.7 28.9 534,154.1 31.1

    Balance -24,154.7 8,036.1 -65,403.1 North America -19,488.5 14,375.9 287,668.9Rest of the World -4,666.2 -6,339.8 -353,072.0

    Source: Own elaboration with data from Estadsticas de Comercio Exterior , Instituto NacionalDe Estadstica Geografa e Informtica, INEGI, Mxico.

    42

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    43/62

    Figure 9Trade Balance of Mexico

    Millions of US Dollars

    -80,000

    -60,000

    -40,000

    -20,000

    0

    20,000

    40,000

    60,000

    80,000

    1 9 7 0

    1 9 7 2

    1 9 7 4

    1 9 7 6

    1 9 7 8

    1 9 8 0

    1 9 8 2

    1 9 8 4

    1 9 8 6

    1 9 8 8

    1 9 9 0

    1 9 9 2

    1 9 9 4

    1 9 9 6

    1 9 9 8

    2 0 0 0

    2 0 0 2

    2 0 0 4

    Total Trade Balance North America Res t of the World

    It is precisely between 1994 and 2005 when the accumulated trade deficit with the

    rest of the world reached the high figure of 353 billion dollars which offset the accumulated

    trade surplus with the NAFTA area of 287 billion dollars, so there was an overall

    accumulated trade deficit of little more than 65 billion dollars.

    Most of the trade deficit in the NAFTA period comes from trading with Asian

    countries, mainly Japan, China, Hong Kong, Taiwan and South Korea. This is surprising,

    since the Mexican government has established and maintained high tariffs on the import of

    consumer goods from these countries, with which there is no free trade agreement. These

    growing Asian imports consist of growing inputs for manufacturing export industries and,

    43

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    44/62

    on the other hand, final goods imported legally or illegally as if they were coming from

    the NAFTA area. 20

    4. Free trade and equality in Mexico

    One of the desired results of free trade is an improvement in equality . As previously noted,

    this takes place in the form of a redistribution of income among the owners of factors of

    production, which, by necessity, implies a redistribution of income among population.

    To be precise, the Pareto criterion applied for income distribution among factors

    consists in improving one factor of production income without harming the other. This is

    impossible in the Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson free trade model because if there is full

    employment in both factors, the resulting (partial) specialization based on relative factor

    endowment leads to increasing the abundant factor income in real terms, while

    simultaneously reducing the scarce factors real income (Stolper and Samuelson, 1941). If

    there is no full employment in both factors, which is the case for many Latin American

    countries, we might expect that free trade would lead to an increase of both factors real

    incomes, resulting from value added real increases. Yet these increases should be

    distributed in a different way that in the pre free trade situation, the greatest increase going

    to the abundant factor, and the smallest to the scarce one. In the case of Mexico the relative

    abundant factor is, by all means, labor . This is why we expected total wages to increase

    their share in the total value added in a free trade situation as the employment of labor is

    increased.

    In Mexico the proportion of wages to GDP (the wage bill) in real terms, shown in

    Figure 9, was better in the protected trade period, 1970-81 (36.2 in average), than in the

    20 There are of course no official data on these latter imports but they are sold in formal and informal marketsin most cities around the country.

    44

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    45/62

    free trade period, 1982-93 (30.4) and in the preferential trade area period 1983-2004 (30.3).

    In fact, the wage bill declined, though it was expected to increase as a result of the

    expansion of exports and the overall increase in productivity. So we can say that free trade

    policy in the case of a non-full employment country has actually harmed the abundant

    factor of production in real terms (that is, labor).

    Figure 9Total wages as a proportion of GDP in real terms

    Percentages

    10

    15

    20

    25

    30

    35

    40

    1 9 7 0

    1 9 7 2

    1 9 7 4

    1 9 7 6

    1 9 7 8

    1 9 8 0

    1 9 8 2

    1 9 8 4

    1 9 8 6

    1 9 8 8

    1 9 9 0

    1 9 9 2

    1 9 9 4

    1 9 9 6

    1 9 9 8

    2 0 0 0

    2 0 0 2

    2 0 0 4

    P e r c e n t a g e

    Total Wages /GDP

    Source: Own elaboration based on data from Estadsticas de Cuentas Nacionales , INEGI, Mxico.

    In the same graph one can observe, however, that there was a sub-period (1988-

    1994) in which the wage bill recovered in real terms. In this sub-period there was a signed

    agreement between nationwide workers unions, chambers of commerce and trade, and the

    federal government for controlling the increase of prices and wages, thereby stopping

    inflation. It was a non-liberal policy that actually worked.

    45

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    46/62

    A measure of inequality, the Gini Coefficient, 21 shows a trend that goes exactly in

    the opposite direction of what was expected. This inequality coefficient, which fell from

    1968 to 1984, shot up in 1985 and maintained an upward trend thereafter, according to

    official data (Szkely, 2005) and the graph in Figure 10 based on it.

    Figure 10Gini Inequality Coefficient 1968-2004

    0.375

    0.400

    0.425

    0.450

    0.475

    0.500

    0.525

    0.550

    0.575

    0.600

    1 9 6 8

    1 9 7 0

    1 9 7 2

    1 9 7 4

    1 9 7 6

    1 9 7 8

    1 9 8 0

    1 9 8 2

    1 9 8 4

    1 9 8 6

    1 9 8 8

    1 9 9 0

    1 9 9 2

    1 9 9 4

    1 9 9 6

    1 9 9 8

    2 0 0 0

    2 0 0 2

    2 0 0 4

    Source: Szleky, M., 2005, p.17.

    5. Some contradictory results of the structural change

    a) Production, labor and trade

    To obtain the effects of labor and production shifts caused by free trade and NAFTA on the

    structure of the Mexican economy, we analyzed the national income accounts for the 1970-

    2004 period. We considered four variables: workers employed by industry, Gross Domestic

    Product (GDP), exports and imports at constant 1980 prices by industry. We considered 72

    industries, leaving out the federal government and military services industry. Then, we

    21 The Gini Coefficient is a measure of inequality of distribution, defined as the ratio of the area between theLorenz curve of the distribution and the curve of the uniform distribution, to the area under the uniformdistribution. It is used to measure income inequality. It is a number between 0 and 1 where 0 corresponds to

    perfect equality and 1 corresponds to perfect inequality. The data and the graph for Mexico were taken fromSzkely (2005).

    46

  • 8/12/2019 27 Protectionism, Free Trade and Preferential Trade (P. RUIZ NPOLES)

    47/62

    distinguished between tradable and non-tradable goods industries. The former were those

    that have had exports or imports in any single year during the period of analysis. We

    concentrated on these industries. Then, we calculated the number of workers per 1 million

    of GDP at constant prices and its inverse, the amount of GDP produced per worker for the

    whole period, but we chose only four years for comparison: 1970, 1980, 1990 and 2000.

    After analyzing the ratio of workers per 1 million of GDP among industries, we divided

    them in two groups: labor-intensive goods and input-intensive goods industries,

    establishing as a limit two thousand workers per 1 million of GDP at constant prices, so

    that any ratio above this limit was considered labor-intensive and below the limit, input-

    intensive. The results of these calculations are shown in Table 8.

    When the results of these four years were compared, we noticed some striking

    results that seemed to contradict in principl